Skip to main content

Abstract

The author distinguishes between normative and positive constitutional economics. Taking the observation that the normative branch of the new discipline is much better developed than its positive counterpart as a starting point, the available positive literature is surveyed nevertheless. The available evidence is arranged into four categories: (1) Constitutional rules and the procedures bringing them about, (2) constitutional rules as the result of preferences and restrictions, (3) constitutional rules channeling constitutional change, and (4) the economic effects of constitutional rules. Additionally, various concepts of the constitution are presented, the tools suited for a positive theory of constitutional economics discussed, and precursors as well as related research programs shortly described.

The author would like to thank Dennis C. Mueller and Manfred E. Streit for helpful comments and suggestions and Antje Hagen for improving his English.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  • Ackerman, B. (1984). The Storrs Lectures: Discovering the constitution. Yale Law Journal 93: 1013–1072.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ackerman, B. (1988). Neo-federalism? In J. Elster and R. Slagstad (Eds.), Constitutionalism and democracy, 153–193. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Alessi, L. de (1980). The economics of property rights: A review of the evidence. Research in Law and Economics 2: 1–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, T. and Hill, P. (1986). Constraining the transfer society: Constitutional and moral dimensions. Cato Journal 6(1): 317–339.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, G., Shugart II, W. and Tollison, R. (1989). On the incentives of judges to enforce legislative wealth transfers. Journal of Law & Economics 32: 215–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, G., Martin, D., Shugart II, W. and Tollison, R. (1990). Behind the veil: The political economy of constitutional change. In W. Crain and R. Tollison (Eds.), Predicting politics-Essays in empirical public choice, 89–100. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1951). Social choice and individual values. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beard, C. (1913/1986). An economic interpretation of the Constitution of the United States: with a new introduction by F. McDonald. New York: The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. (1976). The economic approach to human behavior. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernholz, P. (1991). Institutional aspects of the European integration. In S. Borner and H. Grubel (Eds.), The EC after 1992 — Perspectives from the outside. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhalla, S. (1994). Freedom and economic growth: A virtuous cycle? Nobel Symposium. Uppsala University. August.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blankart, C. (1985). Where are we in the economic theory of constitutions? Economia delle Scelte pubbliche 3: 147–158.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boudreaux, D. and Pritchard, A. (1993). Rewriting the constitution: An economic analysis of the constitutional amendment process. Fordham Law Review 62: 111–162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boudreaux, D. and Pritchard, A. (1994). Reassessing the role of the independent judiciary in enforcing interest-group bargains. Constitutional Political Economy 5(1): 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G. and Buchanan, J. (1980). The power to tax. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G. and Buchanan, J. (1985). The reason of rules. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G. and Lomasky, L. (1993). Democracy and decision — The pure theory of electoral preference. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G. and Pardo, J. (1991). A reading of the Spanish Constitution. Constitutional Political Economy 2(1): 53–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breton, A. (1987). Towards a theory of competitive federalism. European Journal of Political Economy. Special Issue 3(1+2): 263–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brooks, M. (1994). The cost of being too cynical. Paper presented at the Public Choice Society-Meeting in Austin, Texas. April.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1965). An economic theory of clubs. Economica 32: 1–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1975). The limits of liberty — Between anarchy and Leviathan. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1984). Sources of opposition to constitutional reform. In R.B. McKenzie (Ed.), Constitutional economics — Containing the economic powers of government, 21–34. Lexington: Lexington Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1987). Constitutional economics. Entry in The New Palgrave, Vol. 1: 588–595. London/Basingstoke: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1990a). The domain of constitutional economics. Constitutional Political Economy 1(1): 1–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1990b). Europe’s constitutional opportunity. In Europe’s constitutional future. IEA: Readings/London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1991). The domain of constitutional political economy. In J. Buchanan, The economics and the ethics of constitutional order, 3–18. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1994). Choosing what to choose. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 150(1): 123–135.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. and Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent: Logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michgian Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burnham, W. (1982). The constitution — Capitalism and the need for rationalized regulation. In R. Goldwin and W. Schambra (Eds.), How capitalistic is the Constitution?, 75–105. Washington DC: American Enterprise Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cain, B. and Jones, W. (1989). Madison’s theory of representation. In B. Grofman and D. Wittman (Eds.), The Federalist Papers and the new institutionalism, 11–30. New York: Agathon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Y. and Ordeshook, P. (1994). Constitutional secession clauses. Constitutional Political Economy 5(1): 45–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J.L. (1988a). The foundations of constitutional economics. In J.L. Coleman, Markets, morals and the law, 133–152. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J.L. (1988b). Market contractarianism. In J.L. Coleman, Markets, morals and the law, 243–276. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooter, R. (in print). Constitutional law and economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooter, R. and Ulen, T. (1988). Law and economics. New York: Harper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crain, W.M. and Tollison, R. (1979a). Constitutional change in an interest-group perspective. Journal of Legal Studies 8: 165–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davidson, J. (1984). The limits of constitutional determinism. In R.B. McKenzie (Ed.), Constitutional economics — Containing the economic power of government, 61–87. Lexington: Lexington Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Denzau, A. (1985). Constitutional change and agenda control. Public Choice 47: 183–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dorn, J. (1988). Public choice and the constitution: A Madisonian perspective. In J.D. Gwartney and R.E. Wagner (Eds.), Publich choice and constitutional economics, 57–102. London: JAI.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eggertsson, T. (1990). Economic behavior and institutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Elster, J. (1984). Ulysses and the Sirens. Rev. ed. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elster, J. (1991). Arguing and bargaining in two constituent assemblies. The Storrs Lectures.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elster, J. (1993). Constitution-making in Eastern Europe: Rebuilding the boat in the open sea. Public Administration 71(1/2): 169–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elster, J. (1994). The impact of constitutions on economic performance. Paper presented to the Annual Bank Conference on Development Economics of the World Bank. April.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eucken, W. (1952/1990). Grundsätze der Wirtschaftspolitik. Tübingen: Mohr (Siebeck).

    Google Scholar 

  • Foyer, J. (1988). The drafting of the French Constitution of 1958. In R. Goldwin and A. Kaufman (Eds.), Constitution-makers on constitution-making, 7–46. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. (1979). Economic policy by constitutional contract. Kyklos 32(1/2): 307–319.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. (1990). Institutions matter. European Economic Review 34: 443–449.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. (1994a). Moral and institutional constraints. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 150(1): 136–141.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. (1994b). Direct democracy: Politico-economic lessons from Swiss experience. American Economic Review 84(2): 338–332.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1962). Capitalism and freedom. Chicago and London: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frohlich, N., Oppenheimer, J. and Eavey, C. (1987). Laboratory results on Rawls’s distributive justice. British Journal of Political Science 17: 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Furubotn, E. and Pejovich, S. (1972). Property rights and economic theory: A survey of recent literature. Journal of Economic Literature 10: 1137–1162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Furubotn, E. and Richter, R. (1991). The new institutional economics: An assessment. In Furubotn and Richter (Eds.), The new institutional economics —A collection of articles from the Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 1–32. Tübingen: Mohr (Siebeck).

    Google Scholar 

  • Gifford, A. (1991). A constitutional interpretation of the firm. Public Choice 68: 91–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldwin, R. and Kaufman, A. (Eds.) (1988). Constitution-makers on constitution-making. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, R. (1983). An optimal taxation approach to fiscal federalism. Quarterly Journal of Economics 98: 567–586.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gwartney, J., Lawson, R. and Block, W. (1996). Economic freedom of the world: 1975–1995. Vancouver et al.: The Fraser Institute et al.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, A., Madison, J. and Jay, J. (1788/1961). the Federalist Papers — With an introduction, table of contents, and index of ideas by C. Rossiter. New York: Mentor.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hardin, R. (1989). Why a constitution? In B. Grofman and D. Wittman (Eds.), The Federalist Papers and the new institutionalism, 100–120. New York: Agathon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hardin, R. (1990). Contractarianism: Wistful thinking. Constitutional Political Economy 1(2): 35–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. (1944). The road to serfdom. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. (1960). The constitution of liberty. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. (1973). Law, legislation and liberty, Vol. 1: Rules and order. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. (1976). Law, legislation and liberty, Vol. 2: The mirage of social justice. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. (1979). Law, legislation and liberty, Vol. 3: The political order of a free people. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. (1988). The fatal conceit — The errors of socialism. W.W. Bartley III (Ed.). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hechter, M. (1992). The dynamics of secession. Acta Sociologica 35: 267–283.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heiner, R. (1983). The origin of predictable behavior. American Economic Review 73:560–595.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmes, S. (1988). Precommitment and the paradox of democracy. In J. Elster and R. Slagstad (Eds.), Constitutionalism and democracy, 195–240. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • International Review of Law and Economics (1992). Special Issue on Constitutional Law and Economics 12(2): 123–288.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J.N. (1955). The scope and method of political economy. New York: Kelley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirchgässner, G. and Frey, B. (1990). Volksabstimmung und direkte Demokratie: Ein Beitrag zur Verfassungsdiskussion. In H.D. Klingmann and M. Kaase (Eds.), Wahlen und Wähler — Analysen aus Anlaβ der Bundestagswahl, 42–69. Opladen: Westdeutscher Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kiwit, D. and Voigt, S. (1995). Ãœberlegungen zum institutionellen Wandel unter Berücksichtigung des Verhältnisses interner und externer Institutionen. ORDO 46: 117–147.

    Google Scholar 

  • La Manna, M. and Slomp, G. (1994). Leviathan: Revenue-maximizer or glory-seeker? Constitutional Political Economy 5(2): 159–171.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landes, W. and Posner, R. (1975). The independent judiciary in an interest-group perspective. The Journal of Law and Economics 18(3): 875–911.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leipold, H. (1990). Neoliberal Ordnungstheorie and constitutional economics — A comparison between Eucken and Buchanan. Constitutional Political Economy 1(1): 47–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leschke, M. (1993). Ökonomische Verfassungstheorie und Demokratie. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levmore, S. (1992). Bicameralism: When are two decisions better than one? International Review of Law and Economics 12: 145–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Macey, J. (1986). Promoting public-regarding legislation through statutory interpretation: An interest-group model. Columbia Law Review 86: 223–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Macey, J. (1988). Transaction costs and the normative elements of the public choice model:An application to constitutional theory. Virginia Law Review 74(1): 471–518.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCormick, R. and Tollison, R. (1981). Politicians, legislation, and the economy-An inquiry into the interest-group theory of government. Boston: Nijhoff.

    Google Scholar 

  • McDonald, F. (1986). A new introduction, to Charles A. Beard: An economic interpretation of the Constitution of the United States, vii–liii. New York: The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McGuire, R. and Ohsfeldt, R. (1986). An economic model of voting behavior over specific issues at the Constitutional Convention of 1787. Journal of Economic History 46(1): 79–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGuire, R. and Ohsfeldt, R. (1989a). Self-interest, agency theory, and political voting behavior: The ratification of the United States Constitution. American Economic Review 79(1): 219–234.

    Google Scholar 

  • McGuire, R. and Ohsfeldt, R. (1989b). Public choice analysis and the ratification of the Constitution. In B. Grofman and D. Wittman (Eds.), The Federalist Papers and the new institutionalism, 175–204. New York: Agathon.

    Google Scholar 

  • McKenzie, R. (1984). Introduction. In R.B. McKenzie (Ed.), Constitutional economics — Containing the economic powers of government, 1–18. Lexington: Lexington Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • McKenzie, R. and Tullock, G. (1975). The new world of economics. Homewood, IL: Irwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merville, L. and Osborne, D. (1990). Constitutional democracy and the theory of agency. Constitutional Political Economy 1: 21–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P., North, D. and Weingast, B. (1990). The role of institutions in the revival of trade: The law merchant, private judges, and the champagne fairs. Economics and Politics 2: 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, G. and Hammond, T. (1989). Stability and efficiency in a separation-of-powers constitutional system. In B. Grofman and D. Wittman (Eds.), The Federalist Papers and the new institutionalism, 85–99., New York: Agathon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. (1989). Public choice II. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. (1991). Constitutional rights. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organisation 7(2): 313–333.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, W. (1990). Conditions affecting the survival of constitutional rules. Constitutional Political Economy 1(2): 53–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1981). Structure and change in economic history. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Nozick, R. (1973). Anarchy, state, and utopia. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oates, W. (1972). Fiscal federalism. New York: Harcourt.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1984). Comment. In R.B. McKenzie (Ed.), Constitutional Economics — Containing the economic powers of government, 89–94. Lexington: Lexington Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1991). Autocracy, democracy, and prosperity. In R.J. Zeckhauser (Ed.), Strategy and choice, 131–157. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ordeshook, P. (1992). Constitutional stability. Constitutional Political Economy 3(2): 137–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pejovich, S. (1990). The economics of property rights: Towards a theory of comparative systems. Dordrecht: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pommerehne, W. (1978). Institutional approaches to public expenditure. Journal of Public Economics 9: 255–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pommerehne, W. (1990). The empirical relevance of comparative institutional analysis. European Economic Review 34: 458–468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pommerehne, W. and Frey, B. (1992). The effects of tax administration on tax morale. Paper presented at the Conference on Tax Administration and Tax Evasion of the International Seminar in Public Economics (ISPE). El Escoriai, June.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R. (1987). The constitution as an economic document. George Washington Law Review 56(1): 4–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Priddat, B. (1993). Constitutional economics — einige Fragen an die constitutional economics. Diskussionspapiere der Wirtschaftswissenschaftlichen Fakultät der Universität Witten/Herdecke.

    Google Scholar 

  • Przeworski, A. (1991). Democracy and the market — Political and economic reforms in Eastern Europe and Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Przeworski, A. and Limongi, F. (1993). Political regimes and economic growth. Journal of Economic Perspectives 7(3): 51–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Radnitzky, G. and Bernholz, P. (Eds.). (1987). Economic imperialism. New York: Paragon House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rawls, J. (1971). A theory of justice. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. (1983). Political theory and the art of heresthetics. In A. Finifter (Ed.), Political science: The state of the discipline, 47–67. Washington, DC: American Political Science Association.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. (1984). The heresthetics of constitution-making: The Presidency in 1787, with comments on determinism and rational choice. American Political Science Review 78: 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scharpf, F. (1991). Kann es in Europa eine stabile föderale Balance geben? In R. Wildenmann (Ed.), Staatswerdung Europas: Optionen für eine Europäische Union, 415–428. Baden-Baden: Nomos.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, T. (1984). Self-command in practice, in policy, and in a theory of rational choice. American Economic Review 74(2): 1–11.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, T. (1989). Publius and public choice. In B. Grofman and D. Wittman (Eds.), The Federalist Papers and the new institutionalism, 11–30. New York: Agathon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sinn, H. (1990). The limits to competition between economic regions. Empirica 17(1): 3–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steunenberg, B. (1992). Referendum, initiative, and veto power: Budgetary decision-making in local government. Kyklos 45(4): 501–529.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Streit, M. (1992). The Freiburg School of Law and Economics. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 148: 675–704.

    Google Scholar 

  • Streit, M. (1995). Ordnungsökonomik — Versuch einer Standortbestimmung. Discussion paper 04/95 of the Max-Planck-Institute for Research Into Economic Systems, Jena.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sunstein, C. (1987). The Beard thesis and Franklin Roosevelt. George Washington Law Review 56(1): 114–143.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sunstein, C. (1991). Constitutionalism and secession. University of Chicago Law Review 58(2): 633–670.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. and Shefrin, H. (1981). An economic theory of self-control. Journal of Political Economy 89(2): 392–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tocqueville, A. de (1840/1945). Democracy in America. New York: Knopf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1987). The calculus after 25 years. Cato Journal 7(2): 313–321.

    Google Scholar 

  • Twight, C. (1992). Constitutional renegotiation: Impediments to consensual revision. Constitutional Political Economy 3(1): 89–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Twight, C. (1994). Political transaction-cost manipulation — An integrating theory. Journal of Theoretical Politics 6(2): 189–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ulen, T. (1992). An economic interpretation of the Bill of Rights. The limits and potential of law and economics in discussing constitutional issues. University of Illinois Law Review 1: 189–212.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vanberg, V. (1988). ‘Ordnungstheorie’ as constitutional economics — The German conception of a’ social market economy.’ ORDO 39: 17–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vanberg, V. (1992). Organizations as constitutional systems. Constitutional Political Economy 3(2): 223–253.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Voigt, S. (1992). On the internal consistency of Hayek’s evolutionary-oriented constitutional economics — Some general remarks. Journal des Economistes et des Etudes Humaines 3(4): 461–476.

    Google Scholar 

  • Voigt, S. (1994). Die kontraktorientierte Theorie der Verfassung — Anmerkungen zum Ansatz Buchanans. Homo Oeconomicus 11(2): 173–209.

    Google Scholar 

  • Voigt, S. (1996). Pure eclecticism — On the tool kit of the constitutional economist. To appear in Constitutional Political Economy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. (1993). Constitutions as governance structures: The political foundations of secure markets. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 149: 286–311.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. (1995). The economic role of political institutions: Market-preserving federalism and economic development. Journal of Law, Economics & Organization 11(1): 1–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wicksell, K. (1896). Finanztheoretische Untersuchungen. Jena: Fischer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, R. (1994). The political economy of secession: The case of Quebec. Constitutional Political Economy 5(2): 221–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wohlgemuth, M. (1995). Economic and political competition in neoclassical and evolutionary perspective. Constitutional Political Economy 6: 71–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 1997 Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Voigt, S. (1997). Positive constitutional economics: A survey. In: Rowley, C.K. (eds) Constitutional Political Economy in a Public Choice Perspective. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-011-5728-5_2

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-011-5728-5_2

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Dordrecht

  • Print ISBN: 978-94-010-6416-3

  • Online ISBN: 978-94-011-5728-5

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics