Skip to main content
Log in

Reassessing the role of the independent judiciary in enforcing interest-group bargains

  • Published:
Constitutional Political Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

William Landes and Richard Posner contend that judicial independence maximizes the value of legislative deals with interest groups by enhancing the durability of those deals. Despite its acceptance among economics-minded scholars, we argue that this theory is seriously deficient. The ‘strong’ positive version of this theory fails as an attempt to explain the origin and maintenance of judicial independence because it ignores collective-action problems plaguing both the legislature and the judiciary in fostering judicial independence. The ‘weak’ descriptive version inadequately describes the full historical record. We re-interpret some empirical findings—previously thought to support the Landes-Posner theory—in light of our analysis. We conclude that the United States federal judiciary is truly independent of Congress and the President, and that this independence was designed by the Constitution's framers as a means of furthering sound government.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Anderson, G.M.; Shughart, W.F.; and Tollison, R.D. (1989) “On the Incentives of Judges to Enforce Legislative Wealth Transfers.”Journal of Law and Economics 32: 215–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aranson, P.H. (1984) “Judicial Control of the Political Branches: Public Purpose and Public Law.”Cato Journal 4: 719–82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod, R. (1984)The Evolution of Cooperation. New York, NY.

  • Boudreaux, D.J., and Pritchard, A.C. (1993) “Rewriting the Constitution: An Economic Analysis of the Constitutional Amendment Process.”Fordham Law Review 62: 111–62.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J.M. (1987) “Constitutional Economics.”The New Palgrave. London.

  • Calabresi, G. (1982)A Common Law for the Age of Statutes. Cambridge, MA.

  • Crain, W.M., and Tollison, R.D. (1979) “Constitutional Change in an Interest-Group Perspective.”Journal of Legal Studies 8: 165–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeBow, M.E., and Lee, D.R. (1988) “Understanding (and Misunderstanding) Public Choice: A Response to Farber and Frickey.”Texas Law Review 66: 993–1012.

    Google Scholar 

  • Declaration of Independence (1776).

  • Dworkin, R (1982) “Law as Interpretation.”Texas Law Review 60: 527–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterbrook, F.H. (1983) “Statutes' Domain.”University of Chicago Law Review 50: 533–52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eskridge, W.N. (1987) “Dynamic Statutory Interpretation.”University of Pennsylvania Law Review 135: 1479–1555.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eskridge, W.N. (1991) “Overriding Supreme Court Statutory Interpretation Decisions.”Yale Law Journal 101: 331–455.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenberg, P.E., and Haley, J.A. (1986) “The Role of the Compensation Structure in Enhancing Judicial Quality.”Journal of Legal Studies 15: 417–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, A. (1788a) “Federalist No. 78.” In: Alexander Hamilton, John Jay, James Madison.The Federalist. Edited by Michael L. Chadwick. Washington, D.C.

  • Hamilton, A. (1788b) “Federalist No. 81.” In: Alexander Hamilton, John Jay, James Madison.The Federalist. Edited by Michael L. Chadwick. Washington, D.C.

  • Hart, H.M., and Sacks, A. (1958)The Legal Process: Basic Problems in the Making and Application of Law. Cambridge, Mass.

  • Landes, W.M., and Posner, R.A. (1975) “The Independent Judiciary from an Interest Group Perspective.”Journal of Law and Economics 18: 875–901.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landes, W.M., and Posner, R.A. (1976) “Legal Precedent: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis.”Journal of Law and Economics 19: 249–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, D.R. (1988) “Politics, Ideology and Power of Public Choice.”Virginia Law Review 74: 191–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leuchtenburg, W.E. (1966) “The Origins of Franklin D. Roosevelt's ‘Court-Packing’ Plan.”Supreme Court Review 1966: 347–400.

    Google Scholar 

  • Low, P.W., and Jeffries, J.C. (1989)Federal Courts and the Law of Federal-State Relations. 2nd ed. Westbury, N.Y.

  • N.A.A.C.P. v. Button, 341 U.S. 415 (1963).

  • Macey, J.R. (1986) “Promoting Public-Regarding Legislation Through Statutory Interpretation.”Columbia Law Review 86: 223–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Macey, J.R. (1988) “Transaction Costs and the Normative Elements of the Public Choice Model: An Application to Constitutional Theory.”Virginia Law Review 74: 471–518.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Madison, J. (1788) “Federalist No. 10.” In: Alexander Hamilton, John Jay, James Madison,The Federalist. Edited by Michael L. Chadwick. Washington, D.C.

  • McCormick, R.E., and Tollison, R.D. (1981)Politicians, Legislation, and the Economy. Boston, Mass.

  • Mendelson, W. (1992) “The Judiciary Act of 1789: the formal origin of federal judicial review.”Judicature 76: 133–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, W.L. (1992)The Business of May Next. Charlottesville, Va.

  • National Law Journal (August 1992).

  • Perry, M.J. (1982)The Constitution, the Courts, and Human Rights: An Inquiry into the Legitimacy of Constitutional Policy Making by the Judiciary. New Haven, Conn.

  • Posner, R.A. (1985)The Federal Courts: Crisis and Reform. Cambridge, Mass.

  • Posner, R.A. (1987) “The Constitution as an Economic Document.”George Washington Law Review 56: 4–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R.A. (1990)The Problems of Jurisprudence. Cambridge, Mass.

  • Posner, R.A. (1992a)Economic Analysis of Law. 4th ed. Boston, Mass.

  • Posner, R.A. (1992b) “Legal Reasoning from the Top Down and from the Bottom Up: The Question of Unenumerated Constitutional Rights.”University of Chicago Law Review 59: 433–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pound, R. (1908) “Common Law and Legislation.”Harvard Law Review 21: 383–407.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. (1937 [1776])An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. New York, N.Y.

  • Sunstein, C.R. (1990)After the Rights Revolution: Constitutional Government and the Regulatory State. Cambridge, Mass.

  • Toma, E.F. (1991) “Congressional Influence and the Supreme Court: The Budget as a Signalling Device.”Journal of Legal Studies 20: 131–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tyler, T.R. (1990) “Justice, Self-Interest, and the Legitimacy of Legal and Political Authority.” In: Mansbridge, J.J. (ed)Beyond Self-Interest. Chicago, Ill.

  • Wagner, R.E. (1984) “Boom and Bust: The Political Economy of Economic Disorder.” In: Buchanan, J.M., and Tollison, R.D. (eds)The Theory of Public Choice II. Ann Arbor, Mich.

  • United States Constitution.

  • Wall Street Journal “The Federal Reserve: A Very Easy Target.” 8 February 1993.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Boudreaux, D.J., Pritchard, A.C. Reassessing the role of the independent judiciary in enforcing interest-group bargains. Constit Polit Econ 5, 1–21 (1994). https://doi.org/10.1007/BF02393253

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/BF02393253

JEL classification

Navigation