Skip to main content
Log in

Salience of social security contributions and employment

  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Social security contributions in most countries are split between employers and employees. According to standard incidence analysis, social security contributions affect employment negatively, but it is irrelevant how they are divided between employers and employees. This paper considers the possibility that (i) workers perceive a linkage between current contributions and future benefits, and (ii) they value employer’s contributions less than own contributions, as the former are less “salient.” Under these assumptions, I find that employers’ contributions have a stronger (negative) effect on employment than employees’ contributions. Furthermore, a change in how contributions are divided, which reduces the share of employers, is beneficial for employment. Finally, making employers’ contributions more visible to workers also has a positive effect on employment.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Fullerton and Metcalf (2002).

  2. Statutory incidence matters for real incidence when there is a (binding) minimum price.

  3. This result does not extend to noncompetitive labor markets. See, for example, Pissarides (1998) and Koskela and Schöb (1999).

  4. See, for instance, Feldstein and Liebman (2002). Some earlier examples are Summers (1989) and Gruber (1997).

  5. In another survey conducted by the same authors in Germany and Italy, only 20 % of respondents know the overall (employer plus employee) contribution rate approximately. See Tabellini et al. (2002).

  6. See (Domínguez et al. 2011).

  7. There are countries in which workers also receive information on contributions paid by their employers. In the USA, workers get this information in their Social Security Statements. Unfortunately, the Social Security Administration has recently decided to stop mailing the statements due to budgetary restrictions.

  8. See also Mulligan and Sala-i-Martin (1999).

  9. See also Chetty (2009), Finkelstein (2009), Goldin and Homonoff (2013) and Cabral and Hoxby (2012).

  10. This model can be seen as a reduced-form of a standard intertemporal labor decision model.

  11. This is similar to Saez et al. (2012).

  12. Using my notation, (Gruber 1997) defines labor supply as:

    $$\begin{aligned} S=S((1-a\tau _{W})w+q\tau _{F}w), \end{aligned}$$

    where \(a\) and \(q\) reflect how workers discount their contributions relative to cash income and how they value employer’s contributions relative to cash income, respectively. I get my formulation by setting \(a=1-\delta ,\) and \( q=\delta \varphi .\)

  13. To check this, note that we need \(1\ge \tau _{W}(1-\delta )+\delta \varphi .\) The term on the right reaches a global maximum when \(\delta =\varphi =1,\) in which case its value is 1. In all other cases, its value is below 1.

  14. Note that Condition (7) is both necessary and sufficient. That is, if \(\varphi >\widehat{\varphi },\) we have that \(\left| \frac{d\ln L}{ d\tau _{F}}\right| <\left| \frac{d\ln L}{d\tau _{W}}\right| .\) However, in this case the difference between both terms is approximately zero as long as both \(\tau _{W}\) and \(\tau _{F}\) are small. In fact, the difference at the minimum (\(\delta =0)\) is:

    $$\begin{aligned} \left| \frac{d\ln L}{d\tau _{F}}\right| -\left| \frac{d\ln L}{ d\tau _{W}}\right| =\frac{-\tau \varepsilon _{D}\varepsilon _{S}}{ (1-\tau _{W})\varepsilon _{S}+(1+\tau _{F})\varepsilon _{D}}, \end{aligned}$$

    which is close to zero when \(\tau \) is small. This is the standard result saying that the effect of an increase in \(\tau _{F}\) is equal to the effect of an increase in \(\tau _{W}\), since economic incidence is determined only by the elasticities of supply and demand.

  15. If \(\delta <\frac{\tau }{1+\tau },\) then \(\widehat{\varphi }<0.\)

  16. We can compute easily:

    $$\begin{aligned} \left. \frac{d(w_{F}L)}{d\tau _{F}}\right| _{\overline{T}}=w_{F}L\left( \frac{\varepsilon _{S}\delta (1-\varphi )}{\alpha \varepsilon _{S}+(1+\tau _{F})\varepsilon _{D}}\frac{1}{1+\tau _{F}}\right) (1-\varepsilon _{D}). \end{aligned}$$
  17. If \(\delta =0,\) the term \(\left. \frac{d\ln w}{d\tau _{F}}\right| _{ \overline{\tau }}\) is approximately -1, as long as \(\tau _{W}\) and \(\tau _{F} \) are not very large. This is the classical result of full shifting where the equilibrium wage depends only on the value of \(\tau ,\) and not on how this tax is split between employers and employees. Additionally, when \( \delta =0\) both \(\left. \frac{d\ln w_{F}}{d\tau _{F}}\right| _{\overline{ \tau }}\) and \(\left. \frac{d\ln L}{d\tau _{F}}\right| _{\overline{\tau } } \) are approximately zero as long as \(\tau \) is small. As long as total tax \(\tau \) does not change, labor costs \(w_{F}\) and employment \(L\) are not affected by how contributions are split between worker and firm. It does not matter who bears the statutory burden of the tax.

  18. See Mastrobuoni (2011).

  19. In the context of the MP model of Sect. 3, this policy change has always the effect of reducing the equilibrium level of unemployment. The reason is that it only affects the wage curve, shifting it to the right, while it does not affect the job creation curve.

References

  • Boeri, T., Börsch-Supan, A., & Tabellini, G. (2001). Would you like to shrink the welfare state? A survey of European citizens. Economic Policy, 16(32), 7–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J., & Wagner, R. (1977). Democracy in deficit. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cabral, M. & Hoxby C. (2012). The hated property tax: salience, tax rates, and tax revolts, NBER Working Paper 18514.

  • Chetty, R. (2009). The simple economics of salience and taxation, NBER Working Papers No. 15246.

  • Chetty, R., Looney, A., & Kroft, K. (2009). Salience and taxation: Theory and evidence. American Economic Review, 99(4), 1145–1177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Domínguez, I., Devesa, E., Devesa, M., Encinas, B., Meneu, R., & Nagore, A. (2011). Encuesta para determinar el impacto de las reformas necesarias del sistema de pensiones español. In Necesitan los futuros jubilados españoles complementar su pensión? Análisis de las reformas necesarias y sus efectos sobre la decisión de los ciudadanos (Part III). Fundación Edad y Vida. http://www.edad-vida.org/fitxers/publicacions/Necesitan%20Jubilados.pdf

  • Dušek, L. (2002). Visibility of Taxes and the Size of Government, Working Paper.

  • Feldstein, M., & Liebman, J. B. (2002). Social security. In A. J. Auerbach & M. Feldstein (Eds.), Handbook of public economics (Vol. IV, pp. 2245–2324). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Finkelstein, A. (2009). E-Z tax: Tax salience and tax rates. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(3), 969–1010.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fullerton, D., & Metcalf, G. (2002). Tax incidence. In A. J. Auerbach & M. Feldstein (Eds.), Handbook of public economics (Vol. IV, pp. 1787–1872). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldin, J., & Homonoff, T. (2013). Smoke gets in your eyes: Cigarette tax salience and regressivity. American Economic Journal, 5(1), 302–306.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldin, J. (2013). Optimal tax salience. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gruber, J. (1997). The incidence of payroll taxation: Evidence from Chile. Journal of Labor Economics, 15(3), s72–s101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamermesh, D. S. (1993). Labour demand elasticity. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koskela, E., & Schöb, R. (1999). Does the composition of wage and payroll taxes matter under nash bargaining? Economics Letters, 64, 343–349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck, A., Molander, P., Persson, T., Petersson, O., Sandmo, A., Swedenborg, B., et al. (1994). Turning Sweden around. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mastrobuoni, G. (2011). The role of information for retirement behavior: Evidence based on the stepwise introduction of the social security statement. Journal of Public Economics, 95, 913–925.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mortensen, D. T., & Pissarides, C. A. (1994). Job creation and job destruction in the theory of unemployment. Review of Economic Studies, 61, 397–415.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mulligan, C., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (1999). Gerontocracy, Retirement, and Social Security, NBER Working Papers No. 7117.

  • Mulligan, C., Gil, R., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (2010). Social security and democracy. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy, 10(1), 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pissarides, C. (1998). The impact of employment tax cuts on unemployment and wages: The role of unemployment benefits and tax structure. European Economic Review, 42(1), 155–183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pissarides, C. (2000). Equilibrium unemployment theory. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saez, E., Matsaganis, M., & Tsakloglou, P. (2012). Earnings determination and taxes: Evidence from a cohort based payroll tax reform in Greece. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127(1), 493–533.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salanié, B. (2003). The economics of taxation. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Summers, L. (1989). Some simple economics of mandated benefits. American Economic Review, 79(2), 177–183.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tabellini, G., Boeri, T., & Börsch-Supan, A. (2002). Pension reforms and the opinions of European citizens. American Economic Review, 92(2), 396–401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I would like to thank Juan José Dolado, Miguel-Angel López García, Adam Sanjurjo, the editor Eckhard Janeba and two anonymous referees for their helpful comments and suggestions. Financial support from Instituto Valenciano de Investigaciones Económicas, Generalitat Valenciana (Prometeo/2013/037) and Ministerio de Economía y Competitividad (ECO2012-34928) are gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Iñigo Iturbe-Ormaetxe.

Appendix

Appendix

See Fig. 3.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Average rate of social security contributions, in %, OECD countries 2013. Data retrieved from the OECD database, December 2013 (http://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx). Data correspond to the average contributions for a two-earner couple, one at 100 % of average earnings and the other at 67 %, with two children

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Iturbe-Ormaetxe, I. Salience of social security contributions and employment. Int Tax Public Finance 22, 741–759 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-014-9322-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-014-9322-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation