Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Commitment to local autonomy in non-democracies: Russia and China compared

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Constitutional Political Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The aim of this paper is to investigate under which conditions non-democratic political regimes are capable of making credible commitments to maintain a certain level of local autonomy and to incentivize local bureaucrats. For this purpose, we compare two big non-democratic countries—Russia and China. While China has managed to establish a relatively stable system, with substantial decision-making rights resting with sub-national governments, in Russia relations between the center and the regions have been highly unstable and driven primarily by the extent to which central elites consolidated their power. We argue that China has been able to make credible commitments because its non-democratic rule is based on competition between vertical elite networks that span regional and central political arenas, and because the country has limited access to natural resources: these two characteristics explain the difference between the two cases we investigate.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Generally speaking, for non-democratic regimes providing any form of credible policy commitments is a very difficult task. The search for conditions under which non-democracies can make credible commitments has recently attracted substantial scholarly attention (Brennan 1990; Olson 1993; North 1993; Bueno de Mesquita et al. 2003; Haber et al. 2003; Acemoglu and Robinson 2006; Gandhi and Przeworski 2006; Desai et al. 2009; Besley and Kudamatsu 2008; Wright 2008; Magaloni 2008; Fang and Owen 2011; Congleton 2011; Gehlbach and Keefer 2011; Boix and Svolik 2013; Pepinsky 2014). Our paper can be seen as a further contribution to these studies. .

  2. For the case there is a single group controlling the highest political office, Congleton (2012) shows that this group may be interested in minimizing rent extraction at lower levels of government, but would not impose any restrictions on predation of the high-level officials themselves.

  3. Resource control is not linked to a specific level of administration. It can be transferred and re-transferred from central to local levels, that is, to any of the following agencies: the province, district, county or villages and townships. It is for this reason the literature speaks about central-local relations rather than being specific about national—sub-national levels (Wong 2002).

  4. As best described in the novels by Qiu Xiaolong, for example in The Mandarin Dress (Qiu 2007).

  5. As a caveat, our observations for Russia apply primarily to the vertical mobility of the highest-level regional and federal officials—the governors and the ministers. An interesting research question would be to look at vertical mobility of lower-level regional officials to lower-level federal positions within more ‘technical’ segments of the bureaucratic hierarchy, and its ability to contribute to the formation of vertical elite networks. Unfortunately, there is no empirical evidence in this respect.

  6. For China one has to distinguish between local identities within the Han Chinese, which are very strong and form the basis of Chinese politics, and ethnic identities of groups different from Han Chinese. In Russia local identities of ethnic Russians are almost absent, but ethnic identities resulted in the formation of ethnic elites.

  7. The allocation of rents employs the following three means: state monopolies (Du and Wang 2013), procurement contracts handed to SOEs and the ‘national champion’ firms (Laffont 2004), and the allocation of ‘cheap’ credits and loans (Lin 1995).

  8. Even if capital and labor mobility increased, the result would be the outflow of capital to the relatively rich resource regions (which, in turn, would also create disincentives for resource-poor regions to engage in predatory policies, see Cai and Treisman 2005).

  9. The Tuimen oblast, which officially also includes two subordinate regions—Khanty-Mansi and Yamalo-Nenets autonomous okrugs.

  10. This is an option unfeasible for Russia due to the bad demographic situation in ethnic Russian regions (e.g. Heard and Aldis 2003).

  11. A striking difference to Russia, where the threat of secessionism was discussed even for ethnic Russian regions (Furman 2010).

  12. For the Soviet period, Qian et al. (2006) explain it also by the organization of the Soviet planned economy as opposed to the Chinese one.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., Egorov, G., & Sonin, K. (2009). Do juntas lead to personal rule? American Economic Review, 99, 298–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. (2006). Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berkowitz, D., & Li, W. (2000). Tax rights in transition economies: A tragedy of the commons? Journal of Public Economics, 76, 369–397.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berkowtitz, D., & DeJong, D. N. (1999). Russia’s internal borders. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 29, 633–649.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., & Kudamatsu, M. (2008). Making Autocracy Work. In E. Helpman (Ed.), Institutions and economic performance. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blackwell, R. E., & Hulbary, W. E. (1973). Political mobility among Soviet Obkom Elites. American Journal of Political Science, 17, 721–743.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blakkisrud, H. (2011). Medvedev’s new governors. Europe-Asia Studies, 63, 367–395.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, O., & Shleifer, A. (2001). Federalism with and without political decentralization: China versus Russia. IMF Staff Papers, 48, 171–179.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bo, Z. (2002). Chinese provincial leaders: Economic performance and political mobility since 1949. Armonk: M.E. Sharpe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bockman, H. (1996). Informal Chinese politics: Society in the state. Forum for Development Studies, 23, 307–323.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boix, C., & Svolik, M. W. (2013). The foundations of limited authoritarian government: Institutions, commitment, and power-sharing in dictatorships. Journal of Politics, 75, 300–316.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brandt, L., van Biesebroeck, J., & Zhang, Y. (2012). Creative accounting or creative destruction? Firm-level productivity growth in Chinese manufacturing. Journal of Development Economics, 97, 339–351.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G. (1990). The tale of the slave–owner: Reflections on the political economy of communist reform. Fairfax: Center for the Study of Public Choice.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brodsgaard, K. E. (2012). Politics and business group formation in China: The party in control? China Quarterly, 211, 624–648.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buck, T., Filatochev, I., Nolan, P., & Wright, M. (2000). Different paths to economic reform in Russia and China: Causes and consequences. Journal of World Business, 35, 379–400.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buckley, N., Frye, T., Garifullina, G., & Reuter, O. J. (2014). The political economy of Russian gubernatorial election and appointment. Europe-Asia Studies, 66, 1213–1233.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bueno de Mesquita, B., Smith, A., Siverson, R. M., & Morrow, J. D. (2003). The logic of political survival. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burawoy, M. (1996). The state and economic involution: Russia through a China lens. World Development, 24, 1105–1117.

    Google Scholar 

  • Busygina, I. (2002). Russia’s regions in search of identity. Acta Slavonica Iaponica, 19, 296–312.

    Google Scholar 

  • Busygina, I. (2012). Threats to critical infrastructure and state responses: The case of 2010 forest fires in Russia. In K. Pynnoniemi (Ed.), Russian critical infrastructures: Vulnerabilities and policies. Helsinki: Finnish Institute of International Affairs.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cai, H., & Treisman, D. (2004). State corroding federalism. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 819–843.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cai, H., & Treisman, D. (2005). Does competition for capital discipline governments? Decentralization, globalization and public policy. American Economic Review, 95, 816–830.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cai, H., & Treisman, D. (2006). Did government decentralization cause China’s economic miracle? World Politics, 58, 505–536.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chebankova, E. (2006). The unintended consequences of gubernatorial appointments in Russia, 2005–06. Journal of Communist Studies and Transition Politics, 22, 457–484.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Y., Li, H., & Zhou, L. (2005). Relative performance evaluation and the turnover of provincial leaders in China. Economics Letters, 88, 421–425.

    Google Scholar 

  • Choi, E. K. (2012). Patronage and performance: Factors in the political mobility of provincial leaders in post-Deng China. China Quarterly, 2012, 956–981.

    Google Scholar 

  • Choi, Y. S., & Wright, D. S. (2004). Intergovernmental relations in Korea and Japan: Phases, patterns, and progress toward decentralization (local autonomy) in a trans-Pacific context. International Review of Public Administration, 9, 1–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chung, C.-P. (2008). Separatism in modern China: An analytical framework. Issues and Studies, 44, 169–203.

    Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. (2011). Perfecting parliament: Constitutional reform, liberalism, and the rise of western democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. (2012). Rent-extraction, liberalism and economic development. In Y. B. Choi (Ed.), Institutional economics and national competitiveness. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R., Kyriacou, A., & Bacaria, J. (2003). A theory of the menu federalism: decentralization by political agreement. Constitutional Political Economy, 14, 167–190.

    Google Scholar 

  • Corina, G. A., & Popov, V. (Eds.). (2001). Transition and institutions. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Creel, H. G. (1964). The beginnings of bureaucracy in China: The origin of the Hsien. Journal of Asian Studies, 23, 155–184.

    Google Scholar 

  • Creel, H. G. (1970). The origins of statecraft in China (Vol. I). Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Desai, R. M., Freinkman, L., & Goldberg, I. (2005). Fiscal federalism in rentier regions: Evidence from Russia. Journal of Comparative Economics, 33, 814–834.

    Google Scholar 

  • Desai, R. M., Olofsgard, A., & Yousef, T. (2009). The logic of authoritarian bargains. Economics and Politics, 21, 93–125.

    Google Scholar 

  • Djankov, S., Roland, G., Qian, Y., & Zhuravskaya, E. (2006). Entrepreneurship in China and Russia compared. Journal of the European Economic Association, 4, 352–365.

    Google Scholar 

  • Du, J., & Wang, Y. (2013). Reforming SOEs under China’s State Capitalism. In J. Zhang (Ed.), Unfinished reforms in the Chinese economy. London: World Scientific Publishing Company.

  • Estrin, S., & Prevezer, M. (2011). The role of informal institutions in corporate governance: Brazil, Russia, India and China compared. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 28, 41–67.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fang, S., & Owen, E. (2011). International institutions and credible commitments of non-democracies. Review of International Organizations, 6, 141–162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Filippov, M., Ordershook, P., & Shvetsova, O. (2004). Designing federalism: A theory of sel-sustainable federal institutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • FOM. (2005). Ugroza Raspada Rossii: Real’naya ili Mnimaya. http://bd.fom.ru/report/cat/reg_suv/dd051623. Accessed January 9, 2014

  • Furman, D. (2010). Dvizhenie po Spirali: Politicheskaya Sistema Rossii v Ryadu Drugikh Sistem. Moscow: Ves Mir.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gallyamnov, R. (1998). Politicheskie Elity Postsovetskikh Respublik. POLIS, 2, 108–115.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gandhi, J., & Przeworski, A. (2006). Cooperation, cooptation, and rebellion under dictatorships. Economics and Politics, 18, 1–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gehlbach, S., & Keefer, P. (2011). Investment without democracy: Ruling-party institutionalization and credible commitment in autocracies. Journal of Comparative Economics, 39, 123–139.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gevorkyan, N., Timakova, N., & Kolesnikov, A. (2000). Ot Pervogo Litsa: Razgovory s Vladimirom Putinym. Moscow: Vagrius.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giuliano, E. (2006). Secessionism from the bottom up: Decentralization, nationalism and local accountability in the Russian transition. World Politics, 58, 276–310.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goode, J. P. (2007). The puzzle of Putin’s gubernatorial appointments. Europe-Asia Studies, 59, 365–399.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodman, D. S. G. (Ed.). (2004). The campaign to ‘open up the west’: National, provincial-level and local perspectives. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greif, A., & Laitin, D. (2004). A theory of endogenous institutional change. American Political Science Review, 98, 633–652.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guo, G. (2007). Retrospective economic accountability under authoritarianism: evidence from China. Political Research Quarterly, 60, 378–390.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guo, G. (2009). China’s local political budget cycle. American Journal of Political Science, 53, 621–632.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haber, S., Razo, A., & Maurer, N. (2003). The politics of property rights: Political instability, credible commitments, and economic growth in Mexico, 1876–1929. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hale, H. E. (2009). The foundations of ethnic politics: Separatism of states and nations in Eurasia and the world. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heard, G. P., & Aldis, A. (2003). Russian regions and regionalism. Abingdon: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heilmann, S. (2008). From local experiments to national policy: The origins of China’s distinctive policy process. China Journal, 59, 1–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herrmann-Pillath, C. (2009). An evolutionary approach to endogenous political constraints of transition in China. In T. Heberer & G. Schubert (Eds.), Regime legitimacy in contemporary China. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, Ben. (2010). Factions and spoils: Examining political behavior within the local state in China. China Journal, 64, 1–18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang, Y. (1994). Information, bureaucracy, and economic reforms in China and the Soviet Union. World Politics, 47, 102–134.

    Google Scholar 

  • Intriligator, M. D. (1997). What Russia could learn from China in the transition to a Market Economy. Los Angeles: John E. Anderson Graduate School of Management at UCLA, Center for International Business Education and Research (CIBER).

  • Jefferson, G. H., Rawski, T. G., & Zhang, Y. (2008). Productivity growth and convergence across China’s Industrial economy. Journal of Chinese Economic and Business Studies, 6, 121–140.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jia, R., Kudamatsu, M., & Seim, D. (2013). Complementary roles of connections and performance in political selection in China. Centre for Economic Policy Research.

  • Jin, H., Qian, Y., & Weingast, B. (2005). Regional decentralization and fiscal incentives: Federalism, Chinese style. Journal of Public Economics, 89, 1719–1742.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalinin, K., & Mebane, W. R. (2011). Understanding electoral frauds through evolution of Russian Federalism: From “Bargaining Loyalty” to “Signaling Loyalty”. In Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, DC (pp. 2-5).

  • Kazakevitch, G., & Smyth, R. (2005). Gradualism versus shock therapy: (Re)Interpreting the Chinese and Russian experiences. Asia Pacific Business Review, 11, 69–81.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight, J. (1992). Institutions and social conflict. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krug, B., & Hendrischke, H. (2013). Market design in Chinese market places. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 29, 525–546.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kryukov, V., Tokarev, A., & Yenikeyeff, S. (2011). The contest for oil: Oil and gas management in Russia. In P. Collier & A. Venables (Eds.), Plundered nations? Successes and failures in natural resource extraction. Basingstoke: Palgrave MacMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kusznir, J. (2008). Der politische Einfluss von Wirtschaftseliten in russischen Regionen: Eine Analyse am Beispiel der Erdoel- und Erdgasindustrie 1992-2005. Stuttgart: Ibidem-Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laffont, J.-J. (2004). Management of public utilities in China. Annals of Economic and Finance, 5, 185–210.

    Google Scholar 

  • Landry, P. F. (2008). Decentralized authoritarianism in China. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ledeneva, A. (2008). Blat and guanxi: Informal practices in Russia and China. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 50, 118–144.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, C. (2008). Ethnic minority elites in China’s party-state leadership: An empirical assessment. China Leadership Monitor, 25, 1–13.

  • Li, C. (2012). The battle for China’s Top nine leadership posts. Washington Quarterly, 35, 131–145.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, C. (2013). The transition of political selection in China. Mimeo.

  • Li, S., & Lian, P. (1999). Decentralization and coordination: China’s credible commitment to preserve the market under authoritarianism. China Economic Review, 10, 161–190.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, H., & Zhou, L.-A. (2005). Political turnover and economic performance: The incentive role of personnel control in China. Journal of Public Economics, 89, 1743–1762.

    Google Scholar 

  • Libman, A., Schultz, A., & Kozlov, V. (2012). Roving bandits in action: Outside option and governmental predation in autocracies. Kyklos, 65, 526–562.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lin, N. (1995). Market socialism and local corporatism in action in rural China. Theory and Society, 24, 301–354.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lin, N. (2011). Capitalism in China: A centrally managed capitalism and its future. Management and Organization Review, 7, 63–96.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu, Y., & Chen, D. (2012). Why China will democratize? Washington Quarterly, 35, 41–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Magaloni, B. (2008). Credible power-sharing and the longevity of authoritarian rule. Comparative Political Studies, 41, 715–741.

    Google Scholar 

  • Magaloni, B., & Kricheli, R. (2010). Political order and one-party rule. Annual Review of Political Science, 13, 123–143.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maskin, E., Qian, Y., & Xu, C. (2000). Incentives, Information, and Organizational Form. Review of Economic Studies, 67, 359–378.

    Google Scholar 

  • Michailova, S., & Worm, V. (2003). Personal networking in Russia and China: Blat and Guanxi. European Management Journal, 21, 509–519.

    Google Scholar 

  • Montinola, G., Qian, Y., & Weingast, B. R. (1995). Federalism, Chinese style: The political basis for economic success in China. World Politics, 48, 50–81.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myagkov, M., Ordeshook, P. C., & Shakin, D. (2009). The forensics of electoral fraud. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nee, V., & Opper, S. (2012). Capitalism from below. Markets and institutional change in China. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (1993). Institutions and credible commitment. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 149, 11–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oakes, T. (2000). China’s provincial identities: Reviving regionalism and reinventing “Chineseness”. Journal of Asian Studies, 59, 667–692.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oi, J. (1992). Fiscal reform and the economic foundations of local state corporatism in China. World Politics, 45, 99–126.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oi, J. (1995). The role of local state in China’s transitional economy. China Quarterly, 144, 1132–1149.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oksenberg, M. (1968). The institutionalization of the Chinese communist revolution: The ladder of success on the eve of the cultural revolution. China Quarterly, 36, 61–92.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1993). Dictatorship, democracy and development. American Political Science Review, 87, 567–576.

    Google Scholar 

  • Opper, S., & Brehm, S. (2007). Networks versus performance: Political leadership promotion in China. Lund University.

  • Park, S. H., & Luo, Y. (2001). Guanxi and organizational dynamics: Organizational networking in Chinese firms. Strategic Management Journal, 22, 455–477.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parker, E., & Thornton, J. A. (2007). Fiscal centralization and decentralization in Russia and China. Comparative Political Studies, 49, 514–542.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pepinsky, T. (2014). The institutional turn in comparative authoritarianism. British Journal of Political Science, 44, 631–653.

    Google Scholar 

  • Popov, V. (2007). Shock therapy versus gradualism reconsidered: Lessons from Transition economies after 15 years of reforms. Comparative Economic Studies, 49, 1–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Puffer, S. M., McCarthy, D. J., & Boisot, M. (2010). Entrepreneurship in Russia and China: The impact of formal institutional voids. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 34, 441–467.

    Google Scholar 

  • Qian, Y., Roland, G., & Xu, C. (2006). Coordination and experimentation in M-form and U-form organizations. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 366–402.

    Google Scholar 

  • Qian, Y., & Xu, C. (1993). Why China’s economic reforms differ: The M-form hierarchy and entry/expansion of the non-state sector. Economics of Transition, 1, 135–170.

    Google Scholar 

  • Qiu, X. (2007). The mandarin dress. New York: Minotaur Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reisinger, W. M., & Moraski, B. J. (2012). Governance or deference? A survival analysis of Russia’s governors under presidential control. In William Reisinger (Ed.), Russia beyond the Kremlin: Comparative subnational politics. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reuter, O. J., & Robertson, G. (2012). Sub-national appointments in authoritarian regimes: Evidence from Russian gubernatorial appointments. Journal of Politics, 74, 1023–1037.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. (1964). Federalism: Origin, operations, significance. Boston: Little, Brown and Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rochlitz, M. (2013). Elections vs. appointments: Comparing incentive pattern for Russian Governors under Putin. Mimeo.

  • Rutland, P. (1993). The politics of economic stagnation in the Soviet Union. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rutland, P. (2011). The business sector in post-Soviet Russia. In Graeme Gill & James Young (Eds.), Routledge handbook of Russian politics and society. Abingdon: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sachs, J., Woo, W. T., Fisher, S., & Hughes, G. (1994). Structural factors in the economic reforms of China, Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union. Economic Policy, 9, 101–145.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schultz, A., & Libman, A. (2013). Is there a local knowledge advantage in federations? Evidence from a natural experiment. Forthcoming in Public Choice.

  • Sevortian, A. (2009). Xenophobia in post-Soviet Russia. Equal Rights Review, 3, 19–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shambaugh, D. (2008). China’s communist party: Atrophy and adaptation. Ewing: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sharafutdinova, G. (2010). Subnational governance in Russia: How Putin changed the contract with his agents and the problems it created for Medvedev. Publius: The Journal of Federalism, 40, 672–696.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sharafutdinova, G. (2013). Gestalt switch in Russian Federalism: The decline in regional power under Putin. Comparative Politics, 45, 357–376.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sheinis, V. L. (2005). Vzlet i Padenie Parlamenta: Perelomnye Gody v Rossiyskoy Politike. Two Volumes. Moscow: Carnegie Center.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shih, V., Adolph, C., & Liu, M. (2012). Getting ahead in the communist party: Explaining the advancement of central committee members in China. American Political Science Review, 106, 166–187.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer, A. (1997). Government in transition. European Economic Review, 41, 385–410.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stevens, C. E., & Cooper, J. T. (2010). A behavioral theory of government’s ability to make credible commitments to firms: The case of the East Asian paradox. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 27, 587–610.

    Google Scholar 

  • Treisman, D. S. (1997). Russia’s ‘ethnic revival’: The separatist activism of regional leaders in a post-communist order. World Politics, 49, 212–249.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1987). Autocracy. Dorderecht: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turovskii, R. (2010). How Russian governors are appointed: Inertia and radicalism in central policy. Russian Politics and Law, 48, 58–79.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walder, A. (1995). Local governments as industrial firms: An organizational analysis of China’s transitional economy. American Journal of Sociology, 101(2), 263–301.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang, Y.-K. (2001). Towards a synthesis of the theories of peripheral nationalism. Asian Ethnicity, 2, 177–195.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang, J., Guthrie, D., & Xiao, Z. (2012). The rise of SASAC: Asset management, ownership concentration, and firm performance in China’s capital markets. Management and Organization Review, 8, 253–281.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wedel, J. R. (2003). Clans, cliques and captured states: Rethinking ‘transition’ in central and Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union. Journal of International Development, 15, 427–440.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. R. (2009). Second generation fiscal federalism: The implications of fiscal incentives. Journal of Urban Economics, 65, 279–293.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. R. (2014). Second generation fiscal federalism: Political aspects of decentralization and economic development. World Development, 53, 14–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wong, C. (2002). China: National development and sub-national finance—A review of provincial expenditures. Washington: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woo, W. T. (1994). The art of reforming centrally planned economies: Comparing China, Poland and Russia. Journal of Comparative Economics, 18, 276–308.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woo, W. T. (1999). The real reasons for China’s growth. China Journal, 41, 115–137.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wright, J. (2008). Do authoritarian institutions constrain? How legislatures affect economic growth and investment. American Journal of Political Science, 52, 322–343.

    Google Scholar 

  • Xu, C. (2011). The fundamental institutions of China’s reforms and development. Journal of Economic Literature, 49, 1076–1151.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yao, S., & Zhang, Z. (2001). On regional inequality and diverging clubs: A case study of contemporary China. Journal of Comparative Economics, 29, 466–484.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yenikeyeff, S. (2014). The battle for Russian oil: Corporations, regions, and the state. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zang, X. (1991). Provincial elites in post-Mao China. Asian Survey, 31, 512–525.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhan, J. V., Duan, H., & Zeng, M. (2014). Resource dependence and human capital investment in China. Forthcoming in China Quarterly.

  • Zhuravskaya, E. (2000). Incentives to provide local public goods: Fiscal federalism, Russian style. Journal of Public Economics, 76, 337–368.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhuravskaya, E. (2010). Federalism in Russia. In Aslund, A., Guriev, S., & A. Kuchins (Eds.), Russia after the global economic crisis. Institute for International Economics.

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors are very grateful to the participants of the ECSPC conference in Freiburg (May 2013), to the Editor and to the anonymous referees for their helpful comments, which were crucial for us in terms of advancing and sharpening our argument, as well as to Jo Chipperfield and Marlene Hiller for editing our text.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alexander Libman.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Krug, B., Libman, A. Commitment to local autonomy in non-democracies: Russia and China compared. Const Polit Econ 26, 221–245 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-014-9181-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10602-014-9181-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation