Skip to main content
Log in

A Bioeconomic Model of a Multi-site Fishery with Nonlinear Demand Function: Number of Sites Optimizing the Total Catch

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Acta Biotheoretica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We present a mathematical model of a fishery on several sites with a variable price. The model takes into account the evolution during the time of the resource, fish and boat movement between the different sites, fishing effort and price that varies with respect to supply and demand. We suppose that the movements of the boats and resource as well as the variation of the price go on at a fast time scale. We use methods of aggregation of variables in order to reduce the number of variables and we derive a reduced model governing two global variables, respectively the biomass of the resource and the fishing effort of the whole fishery. We look for the existence of equilibria of the aggregated model and perform local stability analysis. Two main cases can occur. The first one corresponds to over-exploitation leading to fish extinction. At extinction, the fishing effort tends to a positive value. The second case corresponds to a durable fishery equilibrium which is globally asymptotically stable. In the later case, we show that there exists a number of fishing sites that optimizes the total catch of the fishery.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Auger P, Mchich R, Raissi N, Kooi B (2010a) Effects of market price on the dynamics of a spatial fishery model: over-exploited fishery/traditional fishery. Ecol Complex 7:13–20

  • Auger P, Lett C, Moussaoui A, Pioch S (2010b) Optimal number of sites in artificial pelagic multi-site fisheries. Can J Fish Aquat Sci 67:296–303

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Auger P, Moussaoui A, Sallet G (2012) Basic reproduction ratio for a fishery model in a patchy environment. Acta Biotheor 60:167–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barbier EB, Strand I, Sathirathai S (2002) Do open access conditions affect the valuation of an externality? Estimating the welfare effects of mangrove-fishery linkages. Env Resour Econ 21:343–367

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark CW (1990) Mathematical. Bioeconomics: the optimal management of renewable resources, 2nd edn. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • de Lara M, Doyen L (2008) Sustainable management of renewable resources: mathematical models and methods. Springer, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Dagorn L, Holland KN, Itano DG (2007) Behavior of yellowfin (Thunnus albacares) and bigeye (T. obesus) tuna in a network of fish aggregating devices (FADs). Mar Biol 151(2):595–606

  • Fonteneau A, Ariz J, Gaertner D, Nordstrom T, Pallares P (2000) Observed changes in the species composition of tuna schools in the Gulf of Guinea between 1981 and 1999, in relation with the fish aggregrating device fishery. Aquat Living Resour 13(4):253–257

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Girard C, Benhamou S, Dagorn L (2004) FAD: fish aggregating device or fish attracting device? A new analysis of yellowfin tuna movements around floating objects. Anim Behav 67(2):319–326

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moreno G, Dagorn L, Sancho G, Itano D (2007) Fish behaviour from fisher’s knowledge: the case study of tropical tuna around drifting fish aggregating devices (DFADs). Can J Fish Aquat Sci 64(11):1517–1528

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moussaoui A, Auger P, Lett C (2011) Optimal number of sites in multi-site fisheries with fish stock dependent migrations. Math Biosci Eng 8:769–783

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ohta I, Kakuma S (2005) Periodic behavior and residence time of yellowfin and bigeye tuna associated with fish aggregating devices around Okinawa Islands, as identified with automated listening stations. Mar Biol 146(3):581–594

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schaefer MB (1957) Some considerations of population dynamics and economics in relation to the management of the commercial marine fisheries. J Fish Res Board Canada 14:669

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith VL (1968) Economics of production from natural resources. Am Econ Rev 58(3):409–431

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith VL (1969) On models of commercial fishing. J Political Econ 77(2):181–198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thiao D, Chaboud C, Samba A, Lalo F, Cury P (2012) Economic dimension of the collapse of the ‘false cod’. Epinephelus aeneus in a context of ineffective management of the small-scale fisheries in Senegal. Afr J Mar Sci 34(3):305–311

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sidy Ly.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Calculation of the Fast Equilibria

We notice that \(n(t)\) and \(E(t)\), the global variables, are constants of motion of the fast process: migration and price variation. Fast equilibria are the solutions of the following system:

$$\begin{aligned} \displaystyle \sum _{i=1}^{\text {L}}m_{si}n_{i}- \sum _{i=1}^{\text {L}}m_{is}n_{s}&= 0\end{aligned}$$
(15)
$$\begin{aligned} m_{is}n_{s}- m_{si}n_{i}&= 0\end{aligned}$$
(16)
$$\begin{aligned} \beta _{i,i-1}E_{i-1}+\beta _{i,i+1}E_{i+1}-\left( \beta _{i-1,i}+ \beta _{i+1,i}\right) E_i&= 0\end{aligned}$$
(17)
$$\begin{aligned} D(p)-q\displaystyle \sum _{i=1}^{\text {L}}n_{i}^{*}E_{i}^{*}&= 0 \end{aligned}$$
(18)

Since \(m_{is}=\frac{m_{0}}{k_{s}}\) and \(m_{si}=\frac{m_{0}}{k_{i}}\) substituting \(m_{is}\) and \(m_{si}\) into the Eq. (16) leads to

$$\begin{aligned} n_{i}^{*} = \frac{k_i}{k_s}n_{s}^{*} \end{aligned}$$
(19)

Since \(n=\displaystyle \sum _{i=1}^{\text {L}}n_{i}^{*}+n_{s}^{*}\) \(\Rightarrow\) \(n=\displaystyle \sum\nolimits _{i=1}^{\text {L}}\frac{k_i}{k_s}n_{s}^{*}+n_{s}^{*}\) \(\Rightarrow\) \(n=n_{s}^{*}\frac{\sum\nolimits _{i=1}^{\text {L}}k_{i}+k_{s}}{k_s}\) leads to:

$$\begin{aligned} n_{s}^{*} = \frac{k_s}{K}n \quad \text{ and } \quad n_{i}^{*} = \frac{k_i}{K}n \qquad \text{ for }\qquad i=1\ldots \text {L} \end{aligned}$$

Equation (17) states that \(\beta _{1,2}E_{2}=\beta _{2,1}E_{1}\). As symmetric movement rates for boats were assumed, \(\beta _{1,2}=\beta _{2,1}\) and therefore, \(E_1 = E_2\) at equilibrium. Then a simple recurrence shows that \(\forall i, E_i=E_{i+1}\). As a consequence, we obtain \(\forall i \in \{1,\ldots ,\text {L}\}\) \(E_{i}^{*}=E_{1}^{*}\). So, with \(E=\displaystyle \sum _{i=1}^{\text {L}}E_{i}^{*}\) we obtain the following result

$$\begin{aligned} E_{i}^{*}=\frac{E}{\text {L}} \end{aligned}$$

From Eq. (18), we deduce that

$$\begin{aligned} D(p)&= q\displaystyle \sum _{i=1}^{\text {L}}\frac{k_{i}}{K}n \frac{E}{\text {L}}\end{aligned}$$
(20)
$$\begin{aligned}&= q(1-\alpha )n\frac{E}{\text {L}}\end{aligned}$$
(21)
$$\begin{aligned}&= QnE \end{aligned}$$
(22)

where \(Q = q(1-\alpha )/\text {L}\). Because \(D(p) = \frac{A}{p}\), at fast equilibrium, we have

$$\begin{aligned} p^* = p^*(n,E) = \frac{A}{QnE} \end{aligned}$$
(23)

Appendix 2: Derivation of the Aggregated Model

We substitute the fast equilibria computed in previous section and we obtain the following system:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dn_s}{d\tau }&= \varepsilon r_{s}n_{s}^{*}\left( 1-\frac{n_{s}^{*}}{k_s}\right) \\ \frac{dn_i}{d\tau }&= \varepsilon \left( r_{1}n_{i}^{*}\left( 1-\frac{n_{i}^{*}}{k_i} \right) -qn_{i}^{*}E_{i}^{*}\right) \\ \frac{dE_i}{d\tau }&= \varepsilon \left( -{\text {c}} + p^*qn_i^*\right) E_{i}^{*} \end{aligned}$$

Since \(n=\sum _{i=1}^{\text {L}}n_{i}+ n_{s}\) we have \(\frac{dn}{d\tau }=\sum _{i=1}^{\text {L}}\frac{dn_i}{d\tau }+\frac{dn_s}{d\tau }\). We perform a change of timescale \(t=\varepsilon \tau\). At slow time scale, the equation governing total fish stock reads:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dn}{dt}&= r_{s}n_{s}^{*}\left( 1-\frac{n_{s}^{*}}{k_s} \right) +r_{1}\displaystyle \sum _{i=1}^{\text {L}}n_{i}^{*} \left( 1-\frac{n_{i}^{*}}{k_i}\right) -q\displaystyle \sum _{i=1}^{\text {L}}n_{i}^{*}E_{i}^{*} \\&= r_{s}\alpha n\left( 1-\frac{n}{K}\right) +r_{1}(1-\alpha )n \left( 1-\frac{n}{K}\right) -\frac{q(1-\alpha )}{\text {L}}nE \\&= n\left( 1-\frac{n}{K}\right) \left( \alpha r_{s}+ (1-\alpha )r_{1} \right) -\frac{q(1-\alpha )}{\text {L}}nE \end{aligned}$$

We denote \(r= \alpha r_{s}+ (1-\alpha )r_{1}\) and \(Q=\frac{q(1-\alpha )}{\text {L}}\). At slow time scale, the equation for fish stock finally reads:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dn}{dt}=rn\left( 1-\frac{n}{K}\right) -QnE. \end{aligned}$$

Equation governing total fishing efforts \(E\) at slow time scale reads

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dE}{dt}=\displaystyle \sum _{i=1}^{\text {L}} \frac{dE_i}{dt}&= \displaystyle \sum _{i=1}^{\text {L}}(-{ \text {c}}E_{i}^{*}+p^*qn_{i}^{*}E_{i}^{*}) \\&= -{\text {c}}\displaystyle \sum _{i=1}^{\text {L}}E_{i}^{*} +p^*q\displaystyle \sum _{i=1}^{\text {L}}n_{i}^{*}E_{i}^{*} \\&= \left( -{\text {c}}+p^*\frac{q(1-\alpha )}{\text {L}}n \right) E \\&= (-{\text {c}}+p^*Qn)E \end{aligned}$$

At slow scale time we finally have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dE}{dt}=(-{\text {c}}+p^*Qn)E \end{aligned}$$

where \(p^*\) depends on \(n\) and \(E\) and is given by Eq. (23).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ly, S., Auger, P. & Balde, M. A Bioeconomic Model of a Multi-site Fishery with Nonlinear Demand Function: Number of Sites Optimizing the Total Catch. Acta Biotheor 62, 371–384 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10441-014-9222-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10441-014-9222-z

Keywords

Navigation