Skip to main content
Log in

Building fresh product supply chain cooperation in a typical wholesale market

  • Published:
Journal of the Operational Research Society

Abstract

In China, the fresh product supply chain is usually connected by a wholesale market. This feature, as well as the product’s perishability, has a great influence on the chain. The market price is exogenous and stochastic because it is actually determined by the uncontrollable supply and demand in the market. The wholesaler reacts to the stochastic price, and based on his experience, he may refuse to sell and may retain fresh products with relatively long lifetime when the price is low. When purchasing at the market, the retailer is incapable of distinguishing the quality change during the delay caused by the wholesaler. However, the difference in quality becomes obvious with faster deterioration in the retail store, and the retailer’s sales are influenced accordingly. The ’market’ works well in pricing the products and matching supply and demand, but it cannot prevent the wholesaler delaying the sales due to the retailer’s incapability. We explain this situation as a result of quality information asymmetry and fix it by coordinating the supply chain; we expect a cooperation mechanism in which the wholesaler cannot improve his profit by delaying the sales even when he has access to the market. The wholesaler’s behavior under market price uncertainty is simplified and described. With the wholesaler’s behavior taken into account, the average quality distribution in the market is approximately estimated. With the approximated description, we construct the model and design the mechanism to coordinate the wholesaler and retailer. A numerical experiment based on an actual market situation is developed and analyzed; the reason why most existing contracts fail is discussed, and managerial suggestions are provided for the practitioners.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1
Figure 2

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Boyabatli O, Kleindorfer PR and Koontz SR (2011). Integrating long-term and short-term contracting in beef supply chains. Management Science 57(10):1771–1787.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cai X, Chen J, Xiao Y and Xu X (2010). Optimization and coordination of fresh product supply chains with freshness-keeping effort. Production and Operations Management 19(3):261–278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cai X, Chen J, Xiao Y, Xu X and Yu G (2013). Fresh-product supply chain management with logistics outsourcing. Omega 41(4):752–765.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chung YT, and Erhun F (2012). Designing supply contracts for perishable goods with two periods of shelf life. IIE Transactions 45(1):53–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duan Y, Huo J, Zhang Y, and Zhang J (2012). Two level supply chain coordination with delay in payments for fixed lifetime products. Computers & Industrial Engineering 63(2):456–463.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goyal SK and Giri BC (2001). Recent trends in modeling of deteriorating inventory. European Journal of Operational Research 134(1):1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hahn KH, Hwang H and Shinn SW (2004). A returns policy for distribution channel coordination of perishable items. European Journal of Operational Research 152(3):770–780.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karaesmen IZ, SchellerCWolf A and Deniz B (2011). Managing Perishable and Aging Inventories: Review and Future Research Directions. Planning production and inventories in the extended enterprise Springer US. pp. 393–436.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kleindorfer PR and Wu DJ (2003). Integrating long- and short-term contracting via business-to-business exchanges for capital-intensive industries. Management Science 49(11):1597–1615.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nahmias S (1982). Perishable inventory theory: A review. Operations Research 30(4):680–708.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pahl J and VoßS (2014). Integrating deterioration and lifetime constraints in production and supply chain planning: A survey. European Journal of Operational Research 238(3):654–674.

  • Pasternack BA (1985). Optimal pricing and return policies for perishable commodities. Marketing Science 4(2):166–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raafat F (1991). Survey of literature on continuously deteriorating inventory models. The Journal of the Operational Research Society 42(1):27–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang CX and Webster S (2009). Markdown money contracts for perishable goods with clearance pricing. European Journal of Operational Research 196(3):1113–1122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Webster S and Weng Z K (2000). A risk-free perishable item returns policy. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 2(1):100–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xiao Y, Chen J and Xu X (2008). Fresh product supply chain coordination under CIF business model with long distance transportation. Systems Engineering - Theory & Practice 28(2):19–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors express their sincere appreciation to two anonymous reviewers for their helpful suggestions to improve the manuscript. The authors also thank Louis Biaggi for improving the language.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Dacheng Liu.

Appendices

Appendix A

Lemma

Equations about \(P_0\):

$$\begin{aligned} P_0=& \sum _{x=0}^{\overline{t}-n_{\text{s}}}\frac{Pr\{w<g(\theta (0))\}+Pr\{w<g(\theta (1))\}+\cdots +Pr\{w<g(\theta (x+n_s-1))\}}{x+n_{\text{s}}} \nonumber \\&\times\, f(x;n_{\text{s}},1-P_0) \end{aligned}$$
(13)

and

$$\begin{aligned} f(x;n_{\text{s}},1-P_0)= {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \left( {\begin{array}{c}x+n_{\text{s}}-1\\ n_{\text{s}}-1\end{array}}\right) P_0^x (1-P_0)^{n_{\text{s}}}&{}x=0,1, \ldots ,\overline{t}-n_{\text{s}}-1\\ 1-\sum _{y=0}^{\overline{t}-n_{\text{s}}-1}f(y;n_{\text{s}},1-P_0)&{}x=\overline{t}-n_{\text{s}} \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$

have a unique solution.

Proof

Assume \(\lambda (p)=\sum _{x=0}^{\overline{t}-n_{\text{s}}} \frac{Pr\{w<g(\theta (0))\}+ \cdots +Pr\{w<g(\theta (x+n_{\text{s}}-1))\}}{x+n_{\text{s}}}\) \(x+n_{\text{s}}-1\atopwithdelims ()n_{\text{s}}-1\) \(p^x(1-p)^{n_{\text{s}}},\) where \(p\in [0,1]\). \(\frac{Pr\{w<g(\theta (0))\}+\cdots+Pr\{w<g(\theta (x+n_{\text{s}}-1))\} }{x+n_{\text{s}}}\) is the expectation of the probability that a wholesaler does not sell products to the retailer with a total delay of x days. So \(\lambda (p)\) is also a conditional probability and we have \(\lambda (p)\in [0,1]\). We also know that \(\lambda (p)\) is continuous over \(p\in [0,1]\) and derivable on \(p\in (0,1)\).

Under this space, with Lagrange’s theorem, \(d(\lambda (p_1),\lambda (p_2))=|\lambda (p_1)-\lambda (p_2)|=|\lambda ^{\prime }(\xi )||p_2-p_1|,\) where \(|\lambda ^\prime (\xi )|=|\lambda (1)-\lambda (0)|=\frac{Pr\{w<g(\theta (0))\}+ \cdots +Pr\{w<g(\theta (n))\}}{n+1}\in (0,1)\) and \(p_1,p_2\) can be any value in the interval [0,1]. Thus, \(\lambda\) is a contraction mapping on [0, 1]. According to Banach’s fixed point theorem, \(P_0=\lambda (P_0)\) has a unique solution and can be solved iteratively with an arbitrary start point in the interval [0, 1].

Appendix B

Proposition

The optimal supply chain profit in the centralized scenario is higher than the optimal profit in the decentralized virtual supply chain.

Proof

After the other virtual wholesaler is considered, the total profit of the virtual chain is

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi ^{\text{d}}=\, & \Pi _{\text{r}}(q_{\text{r}},p_{\text{r}})+\Pi _{\text{s}}(n_{\text{s}})+\Pi _{{\text{s}}^{\prime }}\nonumber \\=\, & p_r\int _{\underline{w}}^{\overline{w}}\int _{\underline{\epsilon }}^{\overline{\epsilon }}\sum _{\theta \in \Theta _y}P_y(\theta )\min \{A\theta p_{\text{r}}^{-k}\epsilon ,q_{\text{r}}\}f_{\epsilon }(x)f_w(y){\mathrm {d}}x{\mathrm {d}}y-E_w\left[wq_{\text{r}}\right]\nonumber \\ +&\quad \sum _{\theta \in \Theta _{\text{m}}}P_{\text{m}}(\theta )\int _{\underline{w}}^{\overline{w}}\left[q_{\text{r}}(y-c_0)-\frac{K}{n_{\text{s}}}\right]f_w(y){\mathrm {d}}y-\frac{c_{\text{h}}n_{\text{s}}q_{\text{r}}}{2}-HC \nonumber \\=\, & p_{\text{r}}\int _{\underline{w}}^{\overline{w}}\int _{\underline{\epsilon }}^{\overline{\epsilon }}\sum _{\theta \in \Theta _y}P_y(\theta )\min \{A\theta p_{\text{r}}^{-k}\epsilon ,q_{\text{r}}\}f_{\epsilon }(x)f_w(y){\mathrm {d}}x{\mathrm {d}}y-q_{\text{r}}c-\frac{K}{n_{\text{s}}}-\frac{c_{\text{h}}n_{\text{s}}q_{\text{r}}}{2}-HC \end{aligned},$$
(14)

while for the centralized scenario, profit \(\Pi _c\) is shown in (9).

For any given \((n_{\text{s}},q_{\text{r}},p_{\text{r}})\),

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi ^{\text{c}}-\Pi ^{\text{d}}=\, & {} p_{\text{r}}\int _{\underline{\epsilon }}^{\overline{\epsilon }}\sum _{\theta \in \Theta _{\text{c}}}P_{\text{c}}(\theta )\min \{A\theta p_{\text{r}}^{-k}\epsilon ,q_{\text{r}}\}f_{\epsilon }(x){\mathrm {d}}x\nonumber \\&-\,p_{\text{r}}\int _{\underline{w}}^{\overline{w}}\int _{\underline{\epsilon }}^{\overline{\epsilon }}\sum _{\theta \in \Theta _y}P_y(\theta )\min \{A\theta p_{\text{r}}^{-k}\epsilon ,q_{\text{r}}\}f_{\epsilon }(x)f_w(y){\mathrm {d}}x{\mathrm {d}}y+HC\nonumber \\\ge & {} p_{\text{r}}\int _{\underline{\epsilon }}^{\overline{\epsilon }}\sum _{\theta \in \Theta _{\text{c}}}P_{\text{c}}(\theta )\min \{A\theta p_{\text{r}}^{-k}\epsilon ,q_{\text{r}}\}f_{\epsilon }(x){\mathrm {d}}x\nonumber \\&-p_{\text{r}}\int _{\underline{\epsilon }}^{\overline{\epsilon }}\sum _{\theta \in \Theta _{{\text{m}}}}P_{{\text{m}}}(\theta )\min \{A\theta p_{\text{r}}^{-k}\epsilon ,q_{\text{r}}\}f_{\epsilon }(x){\mathrm {d}}x+HC \nonumber \\ \ge&HC>0. \end{aligned}$$
(15)

We obtain the first inequality by assuming a best case of the decentralized system in which the market price is fixed to its maximal value \(\overline{w}\). Then \(P_y(\theta )\) becomes \(P_{\overline{w}}(\theta )\) and equals \(P_{\text{m}}(\theta )\) according to the definition of \(P_y(\theta )\).

Then, we have the second inequality by comparing the two probability mass functions \(P_{\text{c}}(\theta )\) and \(P_{\text{m}}(\theta )\). The result is obvious because we consider the influence of delay in \(P_{\text{m}}(\theta )\); therefore, \(\Theta _{\text{c}}\subset \Theta _{\text{m}}\) and the quality distribution in the market is approached from the ideal quality distribution by reducing the probability of high quality and increasing the probability of that extended part in \(\Theta _{\text{m}}\). This step shows the difference of quality distributions with/without cooperation.

The third inequality \(HC>0\) is from our judgment that the virtual wholesaler’s holding cost should be shared by the decentralized system because transactions with the virtual wholesaler exist.

Then, we have \(\Pi ^{\text{c}}-\Pi ^{\text{d}}>0\), that is to say, for the optimal setting \((n_{\text{s}}^{\text{d}},q_{\text{r}}^{\text{d}},p_{\text{r}}^{\text{d}})\) in the decentralized scenario, and we also have the same result \(\Pi ^{\text{c}}(n_{\text{s}}^{\text{d}},q_{\text{r}}^{\text{d}},p_{\text{r}}^{\text{d}})>\Pi ^{\text{d}}(n_{\text{s}}^{\text{d}},q_{\text{r}}^{\text{d}},p_{\text{r}}^{\text{d}})=\Pi ^{{\text{d}}*}\).

For the centralized scenario, the optimal solution cannot be worse than any other solutions; therefore, it is better for that optimal setting in the decentralized scenario, \(\Pi ^{{\text{c}}*}=\Pi ^{\text{c}}(n_{\text{s}}^{\text{c}},q_{\text{r}}^{\text{c}},p_{\text{r}}^{\text{c}})\ge \Pi ^{\text{c}}(n_{\text{s}}^{\text{d}},q_{\text{r}}^{\text{d}},p_{\text{r}}^{\text{d}})\).

Finally, we can obtain the result \(\Pi ^{{\text{c}}*}>\Pi ^{{\text{d}}*}\) with the inequalities above.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hou, X., Liu, D. Building fresh product supply chain cooperation in a typical wholesale market. J Oper Res Soc 68, 566–576 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41274-016-0025-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41274-016-0025-2

Keywords

Navigation