Skip to main content
Log in

Divorce and the duality of marital payoff

  • Published:
Review of Economics of the Household Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Empirical studies on the determinants of divorce are scarce in economics. The literature has focused on the impact of income differentials between partners. We extend the model of marital dissolution to integrate time-varying non-pecuniary quality of the match. We use a unique Russian dataset to measure shocks to the non-economic components of the value of marriage. Our estimates suggest that the monetary and non-monetary components enter additively into marriage surplus, but with gender-specific marginal rates of substitution: divorce hazard is more sensitive to the non-pecuniary dissatisfaction of the wife than to that of the husband; impacts of the monetary components are also gender-specific and highly non-linear. We link these findings to remarriage prospects and partial risk sharing.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The selection hypothesis implies that happier people are more outgoing and are more successful in finding a good match, while unhappy people are more likely to have trouble finding a stable mate. The social role hypothesis implies that divorced individuals are less likely to have social networks and more likely to have financial difficulties. Both hypotheses were rejected based on the instability in the differences in spouses’ happiness levels and short-term correlations in levels of happiness and marriage or divorce occurrences.

  2. See Becker (1991) for an early survey, and Browning et al. (2014) for a more recent presentation.

  3. See Chiappori and Mazzocco (forthcoming) for a survey.

  4. There are also child and community-level questionnaires. The latter provides information on region-specific prices and community infrastructure.

  5. Individual evaluations are again given on a scale ranging from 1, the highest level of satisfaction, to 5.

  6. Unfortunately, this is the only round of the survey designed to report these aspects.

  7. We attempted to estimate more complex wage equations with highly persistent shock (modeled by a random walk) or serially correlated temporary shocks. Unfortunately, the panel dimension does not seem to be strong enough to identify such structures.

  8. They can affect the divorce hazard via the probability of singlehood. However, the wage rate increased over the whole period, and the time dummies are likely to also reflect the effects of inflation despite the CPI used to adjust the nominal wages.

  9. The within transformation implied by the fixed effect approach would yield demeaned match quality which would distort between and overall variation of the match quality variable because the panel data in hand are strongly unbalanced. It would therefore mislead the estimates of the divorce model described below.

  10. Unfortunately, most rounds of the survey do not provide data on marriage duration. This makes it impossible to use a duration model of the divorce hazard. However, the duration of marriage is highly correlated with age, which we include in X ti (estimation based on the few rounds that have information on marriage duration show that the correlation with age is 0.9).

  11. The specification using the tail terms is motivated by our analysis of the distributions of the wage components obtained from (1), which we discuss in section 6.

  12. The 10th and 90th percentiles of the log-wage shock distributions are roughly −0.5 and 0.5 for both gender groups, so that our “strong shocks” are larger than approximately 50% in absolute value.

  13. The equations are estimated using a sample of working individuals which is considerably larger than our main sample based on a selection of the rounds providing the necessary information. Using this extended sample allows us to obtain precise and efficient estimates of wage determinants while including a rich set of fixed effects.

  14. The return to human capital is stable over the observational window. The parsimonious model reported excludes interactions between human capital variables and time. A weak association between wages and education in Russia is quite a stylized fact (Cheidvasser and Benítez-Silva, 2007), it relates to (1) oversupply of highly educated workers in Russia since the transition period and (2) USSR inheritance of wage equalization with no or very slight differentiation based on education.

  15. The corresponding specification is not reported but is available on request.

  16. For the sake of estimation efficiency, we also excluded housing price changes from the baseline model. The housing prices are frequently associated with the cost of divorce. However, the coefficients associated have been found statistically insignificant. On the one hand, it is likely to be a statistical result: house prices are self-reported starting with round 9 (2004) implying more than 30% loss of observations. The sample reduction concerns in particular transitions from marital to divorce status and leads to high efficiency loss of the estimation. On the other hand, the insignificance is consistent with housing markets failures in Russia documented by Zavisca (2012) who qualifies the Russian housing regime as “property without markets, in which housing is privately owned but not fully commodified”. Housing ownership relates to privatization process of 1990–2000 s; exchange institutions and mortgage markets fail due to very high interest rates and housing prices relative to earnings, high level of economic instability and uncertainty, and strong population distrust in regards to financial institutions. Housing wealth remains a “frozen asset” for majority of the population; housing mobility is very limited in the 2000s and is mainly driven by inheritances and infra-family wealth transfers (Zavisca 2012). In this context, changes of housing economic value, prices, do not yet immediately translate into the cost of divorce unlike economies where housing mobility is driven by housing market conditions.

  17. Excluded from the parsimonious estimation reported in Table 4.

  18. Recall that as defined in (5), our shock variables are algebraic: a large negative value denotes a large negative shock rather than its absolute value.

  19. We should note here that Weiss and Willis measure “predicted earnings” somewhat differently.

References

  • Battu H., Brown H. & M. Costa-Gomes (2013). Not always for richer or poorer: The effects of income shocks and house price changes on marital dissolution, ERSA conference papers ersa13p250.

  • Becker, G., Landes, E., & Michael, R. (1977). An economic analysis of marital instability. Journal of Political Economy, 85(6), 1141–1188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1973). A theory of marriage: Part I. Journal of Political Economy, 81, 813–846.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1974). A theory of marriage: Part II. Journal of Political Economy, 82(2), S11–S26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1991). Treatise on the family. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand, M., Kamenica, E., & Pan, J. (2015). Gender Identity and Relative Income within households. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 130(2), 571–614.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blum, A., Lefevre, C., Sebille, P., Badurashvili, I., Régnier-Loilier, A., Stankuniene, V., & Sinyavskaya, O. (2009). The family anyway: France, Georgia, Lithuania, Russia. Revue d'études comparatives Est-Ouest, 40, 5–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning M., Chiappori P. A. & Weiss Y. (2014). Economics of the Family. Cambridge Surveys of Economic Literature. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

  • Bruze, G., Svarer, M., & Weiss, Y. (2015). The dynamics of marriage and divorce. Journal of Labor Economics, 33(1), 123–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Böheim, R., & Ermisch, J. (2001). Partnership dissolution in the UK— the role of economic circumstances. Oxford Bulletin of Economic Statistics, 63, 197–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chapman, B., & Guven, C. (2016). Revisiting the relationship between marriage and wellbeing: Does marriage quality matter? Journal of Happiness Studies, 17, 533–551.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charles, K. K., & Stephens, M. (2004). Job displacement, disability, and divorce. Journal of Labor Economics, 22(2), 489–522.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheidvasser, S., & Benítez-Silva, H. (2007). The educated Russian’ s curse: Returns to education in the Russian federation during the 1990s. Labour, 21(1), 1–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori, P. A. & Mazzocco, M. Static and intertemporal household decisions, Journal of Economic Literature, forthcoming. http://www.econ.ucla.edu/mazzocco/doc/HouseholdSurvey.pdf

  • Chiappori, P. A., Iyigun, M., & Weiss, Y. (2015). The Becker–Coase theorem reconsidered. Journal of Demographic Economics, 81(2), 157–177.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori, P.-A., Oreffice, S., & Quintana-Domeque, C. (2012). Fatter attraction: Anthropometric and socioeconomic matching on the marriage market. Journal of Political Economy, 120(4), 659–695.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori, P.-A., Oreffice, S. & Quintana-Domeque C. (2017). Bidimensional matching with heterogeneous preferences: Education and smoking in the marriage market, Journal of the European EconomicAssociation, forthcoming. doi:10.1093/jeea/jvx012

  • Chiappori, P. A., & Weiss, Y. (2006). Divorce, remarriage and welfare: A general equilibrium approach. Journal of the European Economic Association, Papers and Proceedings, 4(2–3), 415–426.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori, P. A., & Weiss, Y. (2007). Divorce, remarriage, and child support. Journal of Labor Economics, 25(1), 37–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, A. E., Frijters, P., & Shields, M. A. (2008). Relative income, happiness, and utility: An explanation for the easterlin paradox and other puzzles. Journal of Economic Literature, 46(1), 95–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dolan, P., Peasgood, T., & White, M. (2008). Do we really know what makes us happy? A review of the economic literature on the factors associated with subjective well-being. Journal of Economic Psychology, 29(1), 94–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farnham, M., Schmidt, L., & Sevak, P. (2011). House prices and marital stability. American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings, 101(3), 615–619.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farzanegan, M. R., & Gholipour, H. F. (2016). Divorce and the cost of housing: Evidence from Iran. the Review of Economics of the Household, 14, 1029–1054.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gardner, J., & Oswald, A. J. (2006). Do divorcing couples become happier by breaking up? Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 169(2), 319–336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • González-Val, R., & Marcén, M. (2017). Divorce and the business cycle: A cross-country analysis. Review of Economics of the Household, 15(3), 879–904.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guven, C., Senik, C., & Stichnoth, H. (2012). You can’t be happier than your wife. Happiness gaps and divorce. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 82(1), 110–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hess, G. D. (2004). Marriage and consumption insurance: What’s love got to do with it? Journal of Political Economy, 112(2), 290–318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman, S. D., & Duncan, G. J. (1995). The effect of incomes, wages, and AFDC benefits on marital disruption. Journal of Human Resources, 30(1), 19–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jalovaara, M. (2003). The joint effects of marriage partners’ socioeconomic positions on the risk of divorce. Demography, 40(1), 67–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, D. R., & Wu, J. (2002). An Empirical Test of Crisis, Social Selection, and Role Explanations of the Relationship between Marital Disruption and Psychological Distress: A Pooled Time-Series Analysis of Four-Wave Panel Data. Journal of Marriage and Family, 64(1), 211–224.

  • Kalugina, E., Radchenko, N., & Sofer, C. (2009a). How do spouses share their full income? Identification of the sharing rule using self-reported income. Review of Income and Wealth, 55, 360–391.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalugina, E., Radchenko, N., & Sofer, C. (2009b). Intrahousehold inequality in transitional Russia. Review of Economics of the Household, 7(4), 447–471.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lacroix, G., & Radchenko, N. (2011). The changing intra-household resource allocation in Russia. Journal of Population Economics, 24, 85–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, G., & Vikat, A. (2007). Does divorce risk in Sweden depend on spouses’ Relative income? A study of marriage from 1981 to 1998. Canadian Studies in Population, 34(2), 217–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Low C. (2014). Pricing the Biological Clock: Reproductive Capital on the US Marriage Market, mimeo.

  • Lucas, R. E., Clark, A. E., Georgellis, Y., & Diener, E. (2003). Reexamining adaptation and the set point model of happiness: Reactions to changes in marital status. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 84(3), 527–539.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundberg, S. (2012). Personality and marital surplus. IZA Journal of Labor Economics, 1(1), 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nunley, J. M., & Seals, A. (2010). The effects of household income volatility on divorce. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Wiley Blackwell, 69(3), 983–1010.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Population of Russia (2014). Higher school of economics & demography institute. Annual report, in Russian.

  • Radchenko, N. (2015). Welfare sharing within households: Identification from subjective well-being data and the collective model of labor supply. Journal of Family and Economic Issues, 37(2), 254–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rainer, H., & Smith, I. (2010). Staying together for the sake of the home?: House price shocks and partnership dissolution in the UK. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 173(3), 557–574.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Routon, P. W. (2017). Military servuce and marital dissolution: a trajectory analysis. The Review of Economics of the Households, 15, 335–355.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stevenson, B., & Wolfers, L. (2007). Marriage and divorce: Changes and their driving forces. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21(2), 27–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Der Klaauw, W. (1996). Female labor supply and marital status decisions: A life-cycle model. Review of Economic Studies, 63(2), 199–235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Praag, B. M. S. (2007). Perspectives from the happiness literature and the role of new instruments for policy analysis, IZA Discussion Paper, N 2568.

  • Waite, L., & Gallagher, M. (2000). The case for marriage. New York, NY: Doubleday.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weiss, Y., & Willis, R. J. (1997). Match quality, new information, and marital dissolution. Journal of Labor Economics, 15(2), 293–312.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zavisca, J. (2012). Housing the New Russia. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. http://www.jstor.org/stable/10.7591/j.ctt7zd38

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Natalia Radchenko.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

Appendix

Appendix

Table 5

Table 5 Descriptive statistics on the key variables

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Chiappori, P., Radchenko, N. & Salanié, B. Divorce and the duality of marital payoff. Rev Econ Household 16, 833–858 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-017-9382-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-017-9382-0

Keywords

JEL codes

Navigation