Skip to main content
Log in

Collective Models of Labor Supply with Nonconvex Budget Sets and Nonparticipation: A Calibration Approach

  • Published:
Review of Economics of the Household Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We suggest a methodology to calibrate a collective model with household-specific bargaining rules and marriage-specific preferences that incorporate leisure externalities. The empirical identification relies on the assumption that some aspects of individual preferences remain the same after marriage, so that estimation on single individuals can be used. The procedure maps the complete Pareto frontier of each household in the dataset and we define alternative measures of a power index. The latter is then regressed on relevant bargaining factors, including a set of variables retracing the potential relative contributions of the spouses to household disposable income. In its capacity to handle complex budget sets and labor force participation decisions of both spouses, this framework allows the comparison of unitary and collective predictions of labor supply reactions and welfare changes entailed by fiscal reforms in a realistic setting (see Michal Myck et al., 2006; Denis Beninger et al., 2006).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Within the collective approach, Beninger (2000) and Donni (2003) provide theoretical results for the case of convex budget sets. Moreau and Donni (2002) estimate a household labor supply model for France accordingly, by convexifying the budget sets and selecting participating couples. On the other hand, Blundell, Chiappori, Magnac and Meghir (2001) tackle nonparticipation with linear budget constraints. But the general case has not yet received proper treatment.

  2. Dauphin, El Laga, Fortin, and Lacroix (2006) test for the number of decision makers in a study on consumption within the setting of Browning and Chiappori (1998).

  3. Examples of collective models with more general preferences can be found in Browning and Chiappori (1998) and Chiappori, Fortin, and Lacroix (2002).

  4. An alternative approach can be found in Browning, Chiappori, and Lewbel (2004), who assume that singles and individuals in couples have the same preferences over a bundle of private good equivalents. For singles, private good equivalents equal observed quantities. For couples, a household consumption technology transforms observed quantities into private good equivalents.

  5. Browning and Chiappori (1998) is an exception, but their paper is not primarily concerned with labor supply and focuses on linear budget constraits. See also Chiappori et al. (2002).

  6. Apps and Rees (2001) present a model with household production that also includes a calibration step. The theoretical distinction between individual and shared leisure in a collective framework is investigated by Fong and Zhang (2001). Apps (2003) discusses the limitations of time use surveys in this context.

  7. See Browning and Gørtz (2005) for an empirical study taking advantage of such data.

  8. This is also what Barmby and Smith (2001) do.

  9. In a full estimation approach, λ would be estimated in a two stage procedure like feasible generalized least squares. Here it is only roughly calibrated ex ante, with the main aim of taking into account different discretizations of labor supplies of men and women, as well as different hours distributions.

  10. For instance, using the PSID, Chiappori et al. (2002) find a significant impact on the sharing rule of the sex ratio and the divorce laws across states for US households.

  11. Indeed, the hypothesis of income pooling specific to the unitary model, but relaxed by the collective model, is rejected by most tests in the empirical literature on collective models already quoted.

  12. Clearly, a more reliable identification could be obtained by using data covering a tax reform along the lines of Blundell, Duncan, and Meghir (1998).

  13. Recall the definition of μ f in equation (8).

  14. One could think of iterating the procedure further, by re-calibrating the bargaining power position given the estimated δm(d) and δf(d) until convergence, but this would be costly in terms of computer time.

  15. Although we proceed in a fairly naive way by treating the collective model as deterministic in Beninger et al., there is scope for full-scale simulation taking into account all types of unobserved heterogeneity considered in the estimation/calibration approach, as well as the uncertainty embodied in the estimated parameters. This concerns the estimation of wages for the nonparticipants, the estimation of preference parameters for singles, and the estimation/calibration of ω f (e, d), δm(d) and δf(d).

  16. We would like to thank Costas Meghir for pointing this out.

  17. We also estimated random parameter logit models (RPL, see, e.g., McFadden and Train, 2000) with a normal distribution of the constant terms in β i c and β i l . For several countries we obtained significant dispersion for the consumption term, but not for the leisure term, both for men and women. The specification with mass points on β i c alone strongly dominated the RPL specification on most cases, both in terms of likelihood and in terms of accuracy of predictions.

References

  • Apps, P. (2003). Gender, time use and models of the household. IZA Discussion Paper 796. Bonn: IZA.

  • Apps, P., & Rees, R. (1988). Taxation and the household. Journal of Public Economics, 35, 355–369.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Apps, P., & Rees, R. (2001). Household production, full consumption and the costs of children. Labour Economics, 8, 621–648.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bargain, O., Beninger, D., Laisney, F., & Moreau, N. (2002). Positive and normative analysis of tax policy: Does the representation of the household decision process matter? Evidence for France. Paper presented at the EEA’02 meeting in Venice.

  • Barmby, T., & Smith, N. (2001). Household labour supply in Britain and Denmark: Some interpretation using a model of Pareto optimal behavior. Applied Economics, 33, 1109–1116.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beblo, M. (2001). Die Freizeitlücke zwischen erwerbstätigen Müttern und Vätern - Ein ö konomischer Erklärungsversuch mit Daten der deutschen Zeitbudgeterhebung 1991/92. In M. Ehling, J. Merz et al. (Eds.), Zeitbudget in Deutschland – Erfahrungsberichte der Wissenschaft. Wiesbaden: Statistisches Bundesamt.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beninger, D. (2000). Collective models: Introduction of the taxation. Mimeo, Mannheim: ZEW.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beninger, D., Laisney, F., & Beblo, M. (2002). Welfare analysis of fiscal reforms: Does the representation of the family decision process matter? Evidence for Germany. Mimeo, Mannheim: ZEW.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beninger, D., Bargain, O., Beblo, M., Blundell, R., Carrasco, R., Chiuri, M.-C., Laisney, F., Lechene, V., Longobardi, E., Myck, M., Moreau, N., Ruiz-Castillo, J., & Vermeulen, F. (2006). Evaluating the move to a linear tax system in Germany and other European countries: The choice of the representation of household decision processes does matter.Review of Economics of the Household, 4, 159–180.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhattarai, K., & Whalley, J. (1997). Discreteness and the welfare cost of labor supply tax distortions. NBER Working Paper 6280. Cambridge Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Bingley, P., & Walker, I. (1997). The labour supply, unemployment, and participation of lone mothers in in-work transfer programs. Economic Journal, 107, 1375–1390.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., Duncan, A., & Meghir, C. (1998). Estimating labour supply responses using tax reforms. Econometrica, 66, 827–861.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., Lechene, V., & Myck, M. (2002). Does the representation of family decision processes matter? Collective decisions and fiscal reforms in the UK. Mimeo, London: IFS.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., Chiappori, P.-A., Magnac, T., & Meghir, C. (2001). Collective labour supply: Heterogeneity and non-participation. IFS Working Paper WP01/19. London: IFS.

  • Browning, M., & Chiappori, P.-A. (1998). Efficient intra-household allocations: A general characterization and empirical tests. Econometrica, 66, 1241–1278.

    Google Scholar 

  • Browning, M., & Gørtz, M. (2005). Spending time and money within the household. Mimeo, Copenhagen: CAM.

    Google Scholar 

  • Browning, M.,& Lechene, V. (2001). Caring and sharing: Tests between alternative models of intra-household allocation. Oxford Economics Discussion Paper Series 70. Oxford: University of Oxford.

  • Browning, M., Chiappori, P.-A., & Lechene, V. (2006). Collective and unitary models: A clarification. Review of Economics of the Household, 4, 5–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning, M., Chiappori, P.-A., & Lewbel, A. (2004). Estimating consumption economies of scale, adult equivalence scales, and household bargaining power. Mimeo, Boston: Boston College.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carrasco, R., & Ruiz-Castillo, J. (2002). Does the representation of the family decision process matter? A collective model of household labor supply for the evaluation of a personal tax reform in Spain. Mimeo, Madrid: Universidad Carlos III.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori, P.-A. (1988). Rational household labor supply. Econometrica, 56, 63–89.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori, P.-A. (1992). Collective labor supply and welfare. Journal of Political Economy, 100, 437–467.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori, P.-A., Fortin, B., & Lacroix, G. (2002). Marriage market, divorce legislation and household labor supply. Journal of Political Economy, 110, 37–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiuri, M.-C., & Longobardi, E. (2002). Welfare analysis of fiscal reforms in Europe: Does the representation of family decision processes matter? Evidence from Italy. Mimeo, Bari: University of Bari.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dauphin, A., El Lahga, A.R., Fortin, B., & Lacroix, G. (2006). Choix de Consommation des Ménages en Pr ésence de Plusieurs Décideurs. Forthcoming in L’Actualité Économique.

  • Donni, O. (2003). Collective household labor supply: Non-participation and income taxation. Journal of Public Economics, 87, 1179–1198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Donni, O. (2004). A note on the collective model of labor supply with domestic production. Mimeo, Cergy-Pontoise: Université de Cergy-Pontoise.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fong, Y., & Zhang, J. (2001). The identication of unobservable independent and spousal leisure. Journal of Political Economy, 109, 191–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fortin, B., & Lacroix, G. (1997). A test of the neo-classical and collective models of household labour supply. Economic Journal, 107, 933–955.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J., & Singer, B. (1984). A method for minimizing the impact of distributional assumptions in econometric models of duration data. Econometrica, 52, 271–320.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoynes, H. (1996). Welfare transfers in two-parent families: Labor supply and welfare participation under AFDC-UP. Econometrica, 64, 295–332.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewbel, A. (2000). Two stage least squares estimation of endogeneous sample selection models. Mimeo, Boston: Boston College.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lundberg, S., Pollak, R., Wales, T. (1997). Do husbands and wives pool their resources? Evidence from the UK child benefit. Journal of Human Resources, 32, 463–480.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manser, M., & Brown, M. (1980). Marriage and household decision making: A bargaining analysis. International Economic Review, 21, 31–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mas-Colell, A., Whinston, M., & Green, J. (1995). Microeconomic theory. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McFadden, D., & Train, K. (2000). Mixed MNL models of discrete response. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 15, 447–470.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moreau, N., & Donni, O. (2002). Une Estimation d’un Modèle Collectif d’Offre de Travail avec Taxation. Annales d’Économie et de Statistique, 65, 55–83.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myck, M., Bargain, O., Beblo, M., Beninger, D., Blundell, R., Carrasco, R., Chiuri, M.C., Laisney, F., Lechene, V., Longobardi, E., Moreau, N., Ruiz-Castillo, J., & Vermeulen, F. (2006). Who receives the money matters: Simulating the working families’ tax credit in the UK and some European tax reforms. Review of Economics of the Household, 4, 129–158.

    Google Scholar 

  • Small, K., & Rosen, S. (1981). Applied welfare economics with discrete choice models. Econometrica, 49, 105–130.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Soest, A. (1995). Structural models of family labor supply: A discrete choice approach. Journal of Human Resources, 30, 63–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vermeulen, F. (2002). Where does the unitary model go wrong? Simulating tax reforms by means of unitary and collective labour supply models. The case for Belgium. Mimeo, Leuven: University of Leuven.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vermeulen, F. (2005). And the winner is ... an empirical evaluation of unitary and collective labour supply models. Empirical Economics, 30, 711–734.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This paper exploits work done in the one-year project “Welfare analysis of fiscal and social security reforms in Europe: does the representation of family decision processes matter?”, partly financed by the EU, General Directorate Employment and Social Affairs, under Grant VS/2000/0778. We are grateful for comments and advice from the Editors, anonymous referees, François Bourguignon, Martin Browning, Pierre-André Chiappori, Olivier Donni, Andreas Krüpe, Jason Lee, Ernesto Longobardi, Isabelle Maret, Costas Meghir, Nathalie Picard, Hubert Stahn, Ian Walker and Bernarda Zamora, as well as participants in conferences and seminars too numerous to be quoted here. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Frederic Vermeulen.

Appendices

Appendix

For the sake of completeness we give here some details on the estimation procedures used.

A.1 Wage equations

In order to obtain wage rates for the whole population, including those not working, we estimate wage equations.

For singles we posit a linear normal selection model and use either the maximum likelihood method or the two-steps Heckman procedure. We tried a number of different estimation methods, including also two step methods with other regressors than the predicted normal hazard used in the Heckman approach, but the choices mentioned above gave the most accurate predictions for working singles.

For couples we also estimate wage equations separately for wives and husbands. The following conceptual difficulty arises here due to selectivity: a participation model would need to be based on the collective framework, which is difficult. However, Lewbel (2000) proposes an estimation method for the selection model which does not require the specification of the selection mechanism. Footnote 16 The method relies on the existence of a variable which is monotonically related to the selection variable: in the case of participation, household unearned income is a plausible candidate—though admittedly less so in the collective than in the unitary approach, because of the effect of household unearned income on intrahousehold allocation. We use the simplest of the estimators proposed by Lewbel for wives. For men we apply OLS, as the selectivity problem is much less severe for them, and the OLS predictions are more accurate than those based on the Lewbel estimator.

A.2 Preferences of single women and men

We estimate preferences separately for women and men, assuming LES-type preferences:

$$v_{i}\left(c_{i},l_{i}\right) = \beta_{c}^{i}\ln\left(c_{i} - \overline{c}_{i}\right) + \beta_{l}^{i}\ln\left(l_{i} - \overline{l}_{i}\right)\quad i=f,m,$$
(17)

where c i represents consumption (i.e., disposable income in this static model) and l i demand for leisure. \(\bar{c}_{i}\) and \(\overline{l}_{i}\) are, respectively the “minimum” requirements in consumption and leisure. Instead of estimating these, which proved difficult, we chose to calibrate them.

The budget constraint is defined as:

$$c_{i} = g\left(l_{i},w_{i},y_{i},\phi_{i}\right)\quad i=f,m,$$
(18)

where w i and y i are, respectively i’s gross wage rate and i’s unearned income, ϕ i represents a vector of characteristics relevant to the tax system, and the function g expresses the tax-benefit schedule.

For the estimation, we use a mixed multinomial logit model (MMNL) with mass points on the consumption and leisure coefficients in order to account for unobserved heterogeneity (see Heckman and Singer, 1984; Hoynes, 1996). Footnote 17 We suppose that each person has J alternative values ℓj for his/her weekly labor supply, leading to leisure choices lj=T−ℓj, where T is the total time available in a week: 168 h a week. The contribution to the likelihood for person i choosing combination (c j i , lj) is:

$$L =\sum_{r=1}^{R}p_{r}\frac{\exp\left[\beta_{cr}^{i}\ln\left(c_{i}^{j}- \overline{c}_{i}\right) + \beta_{lr}^{i}\ln\left(l^{j} - \overline{l}_{i}\right)\right]}{\sum_{j{\prime} = 1}^{J}\exp\left[\beta_{cr}^{i}\ln\left(c_{i}^{j^{\prime}} - \overline{c}_{i}\right) + \beta_{lr}^{i}\log\left(l^{j^{\prime}} - \overline{l}_{i}\right)\right]}$$
(19)

where R denotes the number of mass points (or regimes), and p r the probability associated with mass point r in the mixture. Three mass points appear sufficient, given the heavy dominance of one of the regimes for both preference estimations, single women as well as single men. We do not impose the constraint β i c i l =1 in the estimation, but check that the estimates are positive, which allows to rescale the utility function by β i c i l afterwards. An alternative specification with β i c =F(z i γ), where F denotes the logistic cumulative distribution function, and z i γ a linear index depending on characteristics for individual i, used for instance by Hoynes (1996), led to much lower likelihood values. The reason for the superiority of not imposing the restriction β i cr i lr =1 is that it amounts to fixing the scale of utility. The MMNL model results from adding iid-error terms to (17) for each possible choice, with an extreme value distribution. This entails a fixed variance, which in turns identifies the scale of utility (and thus the sum of the marginal valuations of leisure and consumption).

In order to ensure that the probabilities p r do lie between 0 and 1, we adopt the following logit parameterization:

$$\begin{array}{ll} p_{r} = & \exp(e_{r})/\left[1 + \sum \limits_{s=1}^{R-1}\exp(e_{s})\right]; \quad r = 1,\ldots,R-1, \\ & p_{R} = 1-\sum \limits_{s=1}^{R-1}p_{s}. \end{array}$$
(20)

After estimation, we allocate each observation to the regime yielding the best hours prediction.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Vermeulen, F., Bargain, O., Beblo, M. et al. Collective Models of Labor Supply with Nonconvex Budget Sets and Nonparticipation: A Calibration Approach. Rev Econ Household 4, 113–127 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-006-0002-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-006-0002-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation