Skip to main content
Log in

Collective and Unitary Models: A Clarification

  • Household Decision-making
  • Published:
Review of Economics of the Household Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this note we identify and clarify a confusion that has arisen in the literature about the exact relationship between unitary and collective models and what enters the Pareto weight and the sharing function. We suggest that we should denote as ‘unitary’ any model that leads to outcomes that satisfy the Slutsky conditions whether or not these outcomes depend on distribution factors. In particular, income pooling is neither necessary nor sufficient for a unitary model. We also show that the presence of prices or total expenditure in the sharing rule cannot be used as a test for a unitary model.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Becker (1965), Mincer (1963).

  2. This is conceptual in the sense that we doubt that any household uses this for all private goods (the latter including much food that is consumed within the household). On the other hand, the concept may be used for some goods in the form of an ‘allowance’ or ‘pocket money’.

  3. If we do have public goods and preferences over private goods are not separable from them, we can decentralise any allocation by giving each agent money to spend on both types of goods and then using Lindahl prices for the public goods (see Donni, 2002).

  4. In this note we shall always assume adding up and homogeneity so these conditions are symmetry and negative semidefiniteness of the Slutsky matrix.

  5. Browning and Chiappori (1998) show that in general the demands from a non-trivial collective model will fail the Slutsky conditions and are hence non-unitary, by this definition. In a two person household, collective demands will satisfy the condition that the Slutsky matrix is the sum of a symmetric and negative semidefinite matrix and a rank one matrix.

  6. The decision about how much to spend may itself be non-unitary in the sense that the two partners may have different preferences over intertemporal allocation; see Browning (2000) for such a model. An unexplored area is the interactions between intertemporal and intratemporal allocations within the household. For example, it might be that one partner agrees to extra total expenditure if the extra is spent in a particular way.

  7. To ease notation we assume that preference factors are disjoint from distribution factors, but we can easily accommodate the case in which they overlap.

  8. By definition, any unitary model is also a collective model but we shall implicitly exclude the latter when we talk of a collective model.

  9. ‘For most’, but not for all. For example, household income or gender specific windfall incomes would not usually be considered preference factors and hence their significant presence in an empirical demand equation would signal a failure of DFI.

References

  • Basu, K. (2001). Gender and say: a model of household behavior with endogenously determined balance of power. Mimeo: Department of Economics, Cornell University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1965). A theory of the allocation of time. Economic Journal, 75, 493–515.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1973). A theory of marriage: Part I. Journal of Political Economy, 81, 813–846.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourguignon, F. (1984). Rationalité individuelle ou rationalité strategique: le cas de l’offre familiale de travail. Revue Economique, 35(1), 147–162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown, D. J., & Matzkin, R. L. (1995). Estimation of non-parametric functions in simultaneous models with an application to consumer demand. Mimeo, Northwestern University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown, B. W., & Walker, M. B. (1989). The random utility hypothesis and inference in demand systems. Econometrica, 57, 815–829.

    Google Scholar 

  • Browning, M. (2000). The saving behaviour of a two person household. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 102(2), 235–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning, M., Bourguignon F., Chiappori P.-A., & Lechene V. (1994). Incomes and outcomes: a structural model of intrahousehold allocation. Journal of Political Economy, 102(6), 1067–1096.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning, M., & Chiappori, P.-A. (1998). Efficient intra-household allocation: a characterisation and tests. Econometrica, 66(6), 1241–1278.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Z., & Woolley, F. (2001). A Cournot-Nash Model of family decision making. Economic Journal, 111(474), 722–748.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori, P.-A. (1988). Rational household labor supply. Econometrica, 56(1), 63–90.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori, P.-A. (1992). Collective labor supply and welfare. Journal of Political Economy, 100(3), 437–467.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Donni, O. (2002). A simple model of collective consumption, manuscript, UQAM.

  • Grossbard-Shechtman, A. (1984). A theory of allocation of time in markets for labour and marriage. Economic Journal, 94, 863–882.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hurwicz, L., & Uzawa (1971). On the integrability of demand functions, 1971, in Chipman et al., (Eds.), Preferences, utility and demand.

  • Konrad, K. A., & Lommerud, K. E. (2000). The bargaining family revisited. Canadian Journal of Economics, 33(2), 471–487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leuthold, J. (1968). An empirical study of formula transfers and the work decision of the poor. Journal of Human Resources, 1, 312–323.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lundberg, S., & Pollak, R. A. (1993). Separate spheres bargaining and the marriage market. Journal of Political Economy, 101, 988–1010.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundberg, S., & Pollak, R. A. (2003). Efficiency in marriage Review of Economics of the Household.

  • McElroy, M., & Horney M. (1981). Nash-bargained decisions: Towards a generalization of the theory of demand. International Economic Review, 22, 333–349.

    Google Scholar 

  • McElroy, M. B. (1990). The empirical content of Nash bargained household behavior. Journal of Human Resources, 25(4), 559–583.

    Google Scholar 

  • Manser, M., & Brown, M. (1980). Marriage and household decision making: A bargaining analysis. International Economic Review, 21(1), 31–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mazzocco, M. (2003). Household intertemporal behavior: A collective characterization and empirical tests, Manuscript, University of Wisconsin.

  • Mincer, J. (1963). Market prices, opportunity costs, and income effects. In: Christ, C. (ed.) Measurement in Economics. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ulph, D. (1988). A general non-cooperative Nash model of household consumption behaviour, Working paper 88-205, Department of Economics, University of Bristol.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Valérie Lechene.

Additional information

We thank the Danish National Research Foundation for support through its grant to the Centre for Applied Microeconometrics. We thank three referees for comments and suggestions.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Browning, M., Chiappori, PA. & Lechene, V. Collective and Unitary Models: A Clarification. Rev Econ Household 4, 5–14 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-005-6694-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-005-6694-2

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation