1 Introduction

In the late 1960 s, one of every two watches in the world was made in Switzerland - almost all mechanical. Ten years later, by the end of the 1970 s, the Swiss share of the world market has plummeted to 15%. US watchmakers like Timex, and Japanese companies like Citizen and Hattori-Seiko, took advantage of the new quartz and LED technologies to offer watches at considerably lower prices. Still, Swiss watchmakers continued to dominate the upper end of the watch market with brands like Omega, Longines, or Tissot. To protect these highly valuable premium brands from encroachment by its competitors, the SMH Group, formed by a merger of the two largest watchmaking groups in the country, launched the Swatch brand in 1983 as a low-cost, high-tech line plastic-cased watches. This launch was so successful that not only did the Swatch sales and exports grow at double-digit rates through the 1980 s, but also its premium brands could maintain a stronghold in the higher end market, see Mudambi (2005) and Barrett (2000).

Swatch is a typical example of a so-called fighter brand that a brand manufacturer under competitive pressure can use to respond to potential entry. Positioning a second product lower in quality than the existing premium brand targets directly against low-price competitors. Many brand manufacturers have used such fighter brands against low-cost entrantsFootnote 1: Qantas, for example, dominating the Australian airspace, launched JetStar to attack Virgin Blu; British Airways launched GO to take on Ryanair and EasyJet in the UK; General Motors launched Saturn to fight against Japanese imports into America; Nestle created a fighter brand called Khrutka to compete in the Russian market directly with the local corn flakes producers; or Philip Morris has used L &M, Basic and Chesterfield as fighter brands to flank its brand Marlboro. In some cases, fighter brands might even open up a new lower-end market segment for the brand manufacturer. For example, 3 M created a low-price version called Highland of its Post-it Notes to compete with its cheaper rivals. And, Anheuser-Busch promoted Busch Bavarian against regional breweries to protect its premium brands Budweiser and Michelob, see Ritson (2009). In both cases, it turned out that these fighter brands were so profitable that 3 M, as well as Anheuser-Busch, left them in their portfolio long after their cheaper rivals had left the market.

However, positioning a fighter brand confronts a brand manufacturer with a dual challenge: On the one hand, this second brand should weaken the market position of potential entrants, should drive them out of the market, or, ideally, prevent their entry at all. On the other hand, introducing a fighter brand should not end up competing with the manufacturer’s premium brand. Such cannibalization would imply that current premium brand customers switch to buy the new fighter brand, although they would have never switched to the rival’s low-price product. To cope with this dual challenge, the incumbent has two different strategies to position a fighter brand successfullyFootnote 2:

  • The firewall strategy is the most common response to launch a fighter brand. The idea is to position the second product below the quality of the top product but without moving below the expected quality of the low-price competitor. In this sense, the fighter brand should fend off rival firms to directly compete with the premium brand. As a response to private labels, Procter & Gamble, for example, repositioned some well-known products as higher-grade alternatives, such as Luvs disposable diapers or Camay beauty soap. In the U.S. airspace, the established airlines countered Southwest Airlines’ no-frills concept with low-frills sub-airlines such as Shuttle by United Airlines, Delta Express by Delta Airlines, or Continental Lite by Continental Airlines.

  • The sandwich strategy is another way to position a fighter brand. Instead of launching the second product in the middle market segment to fight low-price competitors, the manufacturer differentiates the offerings by launching the fighter brand as a low-price, low-quality product. By doing so, the rival’s positioning is sandwiched and locked into the middle market segment. After the patent expiry of its blockbuster proton pump inhibitor drug Prilosec and the entry of several generics, AstraZeneca, for example, introduced a non-prescription, over-the-counter offering Prilosec OTC and sandwiched the generics on price and quality. Or, in the parcel delivery market in the U.S., market leader FedEx launched a second brand called FedEx standard delivery to sandwich United States Postal Service (USPS), which introduced an air courier service with a price significantly below the rate of its brand service called FedEx Priority.

The purpose of the present paper is to analyze the strategic role of a fighter brand to accommodate entry in a vertically differentiated market. In our setup, we consider an incumbent firm that already produces a product of high quality. The incumbent, foreseeing market entry, positions a fighter brand before the entrant’s product launch. Then both firms set prices, and customers decide which product to buy. Two aspects of this modeling are essential to note: First, in the absence of market entry, the incumbent never finds it optimal to have a second product. This one-product strategy follows because customers are uniformly distributed according to their willingness to pay for quality which implies that marginal revenues are decreasing.Footnote 3 However, in the presence of market entry, introducing a fighter brand might be beneficial because it allows the incumbent to influence the positioning of the entrant’s product and protect the high-quality product. And second, note that the timing of the launch of the fighter brand is essential for its strategic role: By launching the fighter brand before the competitor entered, the incumbent tries to influence the quality positioning of the entrant. If the launch would be simultaneously or after the entrant’s product launch, it would never be optimal for the incumbent to offer a second product because this would not influence the quality decision of the entrant.Footnote 4

Not in all the examples mentioned above does the incumbent use the launch of a fighter brand for such preemptive reasons. Take, for example, the fighter brands of the SMH Group, 3 M, or Anheuser-Busch. They launched their fighter brands after the entrant’s product choice. Hence, introducing a second, lower-positioned product to the brand product was not to influence the entrant’s quality choice but to weaken the entrant’s market position or drive them out of the market.

There are, however, examples in which firms launch their fighter brands for preemption, either to influence the quality decision of the entrant or even to prevent them from entering into existing home markets.Footnote 5 In the example above on the U.S. airline industry, the established airlines introduced low-fare sub-airlines not only to fight back for market share ex-post after the entry of Southwest Airlines but also to prevent Southwest Airlines from entering into other existing home markets. These fighter brands flew on routes with head-to-head competition with no-frills carriers like Southwest Airlines but also on routes where low-price competitors were not yet offering services. A brand manufacturer of electronic goods used a similar two-product strategy to counter and prevent the entry of Chinese manufacturers which low-quality products. By launching a fighter brand, the brand manufacturer stopped the decrease of profits in already entered markets and used this strategy worldwide in countries where the low-priced competitors have not yet tried to enter the market.

As a first result, we show that the launch of a fighter brand is ineffective without any commitment by the incumbent. Two commitment problems might arise: First, the incumbent might have an incentive to withdraw the fighter brand after the entrant chose a quality level. In our model, two reasons might induce this temptation. First, introducing a second product does not open up new market segments with high growth potential, as in the examples mentioned above of 3 M and Anheuser-Busch. This possibility is excluded since we consider a market with one homogeneous market segment only. Second, we do not consider exit costs for the incumbent in our model. As first discussed by Judd (1985), preempting new entrants by product proliferation then is not credible because the incumbent can always withdraw the new product. Such a behavior happened, for example, in the match industry in both Canada and the United Kingdom.Footnote 6 Here, the monopolist introduced a locally marketed brand of lower quality as a fighter brand to deter or limit new entry and withdrew the brand as soon as the entrant left the market or was sold out to the monopolist. In our model, the entrant would foresee such behavior by the incumbent and then launch a higher quality product.

The second commitment problem, however, is more severe. Even if the incumbent has no incentive to withdraw the fighter brand, it always has an incentive to price the fighter brand out of the market to increase the profits with the premium product. Such behavior can occur independently of whether the incumbent positions the fighter brand using the firewall or the sandwich strategy:

  • When using the firewall strategy, the incumbent can set the price for the fighter brand so high that the price-quality ratios of the premium and fighter brand are identical. No customer would buy the second new product, and the resulting market demand is zero. By doing so, the incumbent avoids any cannibalization with the premium product.

  • When using the sandwich strategy, the incumbent can set the price for the fighter brand so high that the resulting market demand is zero. Although this reduces the incumbent’s profits with the fighter brand, it relaxes price competition with the entrant’s product. Such behavior is beneficial for the incumbent because it also relaxes price competition with the premium product with higher profit margins than those with the fighter brand.

Of course, in both cases the entrant anticipates the incumbent’s pricing behavior and is better off by launching a product directly in the higher market segment. Hence, the strategic role assigned to the fighter brand is lost without any commitment by the incumbent to the pricing strategy for the fighter brand.

To resolve both commitment problems, we consider two commitment devices, endogenous price leadership with a price announcement and dual channeling with price delegation, and analyze their trade-offs:

  • Under endogenous price leadership, the incumbent can send out a catalog or leaflet to consumers or use TV or Internet to advertise the price for the new product. In principle, such an advertisement is possible in two ways. The incumbent can announce to offer the fighter brand either for a specific fixed price or for a particular list price with the possibility to sell the fighter brand for a discounted price that is less than or equal to the announced list price.Footnote 7 The incumbent’s investment in advertisement indicates the degree of commitment not to price the fighter brand higher than announced. Deviating from this announcement implies a loss in the incumbent’s reputation in the entire market and influences the premium product sales. The extent of this reputation loss thereby depends on customers’ reaction in case of a deviation and the incumbent’s advertising investments for the new product. If these investments are sufficiently high, the incumbent credibly commits to its price announcement and has no incentive to withdraw the fighter brand ex-post.

  • Under dual channeling, the incumbent uses an intermediary retailer to distribute the fighter brand. By offering a franchise contract to the retailer, the incumbent delegates the sales of the fighter brand to a third party. Dual channeling, therefore, solves both commitment problems of the incumbent. However, since cannibalization concerns do not influence the retailer’s pricing decision, the retailer intensifies competition with the entrant. Hence, using a dual-channel as a commitment device comes with some costs for the incumbent.

We then show the following four results: First, although both commitment devices entail costs, it is always beneficial for the incumbent to use one of them. Second, independent of the commitment device used, the incumbent always positions the fighter brand to defend the premium product strategically. That is, a firewall strategy is always better than a sandwich strategy. The reason is as follows: When using the firewall strategy, the incumbent will optimally choose prices to cover the upper half of the entire market by the premium product. To reduce the negative effect of cannibalization, the incumbent tries to position the quality level of the fighter brand as low as possible. Of course, if this quality level is too low, the fighter brand loses its purpose as a firewall, and the competitor launches the product in the middle market segment. Although this eliminates any cannibalization, the sandwich strategy leads to more price competition, which reduces the demand for the fighter brand and the premium product. Third, we show that a list price leads to higher profits than a fixed price announcement. Under the fixed price commitment, the entrant introduces a product identical to the quality of the fighter brand but priced slightly below its fixed price. Consequently, the incumbent makes no profits with the fighter brand, and the entrant’s product competes directly with the premium product. Although the incumbent can strategically use the entrant’s reaction to position the fighter brand even lower in the market and for a higher price than the list price, this does not compensate for the loss of profits with the fighter brand. Note that such an imitation of the fighter brand is not beneficial for the entrant under a list price commitment because the incumbent can react to the entrant’s price cut with a discount. Price competition then sparks a continuous undercutting mechanism that leads to zero profits for the entrant. And fourth, the optimal commitment device depends on the reputation elasticity and the attractiveness of the market. Suppose customers’ sensitivity to a deviation from the incumbent’s price announcement is low or the market is very attractive. In that case, dual channeling is the only commitment device for the incumbent because the necessary advertising investments for an endogenous price leadership would be too high. Suppose customers’ sensitivity increases or the market attractiveness is in an intermediate range. In that case, advertising in a fixed price commitment becomes possible and optimal. In contrast, an endogenous price commitment with a list price becomes optimal if the reputation elasticity is sufficiently high or the market is relatively unattractive.

The paper proceeds as follows: Sect. 2 reviews the related literature. Section 3 introduces the basic model of a vertically differentiated market in which an incumbent can use a fighter brand as a response to entry and solves for the optimal behavior. Section 4 extends the basic model to analyze two commitment devices; endogenous price leadership and dual channeling. We conclude with some final remarks in Sect. 5. Proofs of the results are presented in the Appendix.

2 Related literature

This paper mainly contributes to the economic literature on strategic entry deterrence with product proliferation.Footnote 8 The idea that incumbent firms can deter entry by product proliferation goes back to Hay (1976), Prescott and Visscher (1977), Schmalensee (1978), Eaton and Lipsey (1979), and Omori and Yarrow (1982). They argue that launching additional products and thereby crowding the product spectrum, incumbents leave potential entrants no niche for entry. Such a product proliferation strategy is beneficial for the incumbent even though it leads to inefficiencies in the absence of possible entry.Footnote 9

Judd (1985) emphasized the importance of commitment in determining whether product proliferation can serve as a credible entry deterrent. He argued that an incumbent might have an incentive to withdraw some products once the entrant entered the market to prevent competition.Footnote 10 In the context of a multi-market model, he then showed that crowding the product spectrum will not credibly deter entry when goods are substitutes, exit costs are low, or competition for the same good is intense. This result is different in a market with horizontal product differentiation. Depending on the costs for launching an additional product, an incumbent always has an incentive to crowd the product spectrum to increase profits even in the absence of potential entry. Indeed, suppose the incumbent faces the threat of entry. In that case, Bonanno (1987) shows that the incumbent better uses an entry-deterring strategy by changing the specification of its products instead of increasing the number of products.

In a market with vertical product differentiation, however, the problem of commitment becomes even more severe than in the multi-market model as in Judd (1985), for the following reasonFootnote 11: An incumbent protected by market entry would, as a monopolist, only offer one product, namely the one with the highest quality. Hence, in the presence of potential entry, an incumbent launches a second product only for strategic reasons like entry deterrence. Therefore, the incumbent’s incentives to withdraw the second product after successful entry deterrence are high. This temptation is independent of whether the market is covered or uncovered. Suppose the market is covered because all customers have an income such that they are willing to buy always one product. Then Donnenfield and Weber (1992) show that the incumbent chooses the highest quality and the entrant offers the lowest quality if both firms apply a one-product strategy. If, in addition, the incumbent can launch a second product, Bonnisseau and Lahmandi-Ayed (2006) show that the incumbent has no incentive to do so to prevent entry in the low-quality segment. Müller and Götz (2017) show that if there are two incumbents in the market as in Donnenfield and Weber (1992) and the high-quality incumbent can launch a second product to prevent entry, launching a fighter brand as a firewall is always optimal. However, they neglect the commitment problem in their analysis and discuss only interior solutions. Suppose the market is uncovered because some customers do not buy. Then the model of Choi and Shin (1992) shows that quality differentiation between the incumbent and an entrant is not maximal if both can offer only one product. Hence, price competition is fiercer than in a market that is covered. If the incumbent applies a multi-product strategy, Jost (2014) shows that the high-quality incumbent also positions a second product as a firewall. However, he circumvents the commitment problem by assuming that the incumbent can credibly introduce a second product quality. In the model by Li (2019), which also studies vertical line extension in the context of preemption, the problem of commitment does not arise due to status preferences of customers. She considers an incumbent selling a premium good to customers with an additional status utility derived from the average status (willingness to pay) of all buyers when buying this product. Launching a fighter brand might be profitable for the incumbent if customers exhibit such preferences. The status preferences increase the differentiation between the premium product and the fighter brand because it alleviates cannibalization.

The basic model of our analysis then is similar to Jost (2014) and Müller and Götz (2017) with the following modifications. Unlike Jost (2014), we do not consider a two-period setup where customers make purchases from the incumbent in both periods while purchasing from the entrant only in the second period. Instead, we follow Müller and Götz (2017), assuming that the incumbent’s highest quality product is exogenously given. Unlike Müller and Götz (2017), we do not consider two incumbents offering products when entry occurs, and the market is not covered. Instead, we follow Jost (2014) in assuming that only one incumbent is active in the market and that customers have the option not to buy a product.

The contribution of the present paper is to solve the incumbent’s commitment problems when launching a fighter brand for strategic reasons. Our paper contributes to the literature on endogenous price leadership concerning the first commitment device where the incumbent announces a fixed or list price. This stream of literature investigates under which conditions it is optimal for a dominant or more efficient firm to act as a price leader in an oligopolistic market. See, for example, Deneckere and Kovenock (1992), Deneckere et al. (1992), Tasnádi (2004), or Pastine and Pastine (2004) for models where the timing of moves is endogenously derived. Li (2014) analyzes the case in which two firms already offer a product, one firm a high-quality product, and its competitor a low-quality product. The competitive setup is different in our model since the entrant endogenously chooses the quality level of its product before price competition takes place. Consequently, the entrant would have a second-mover advantage in his quality and price-setting behavior if the incumbent announces a specific fixed price when launching the fighter brand. For this reason, we also consider endogenous price leadership, where the incumbent offers a special list price for selling its second product.Footnote 12 Concerning the second commitment device, the idea to use a retailer as a commitment device for launching and pricing a fighter brand goes back to Hadfield (1991). He shows that the delegation of pricing authority to an independent third party through a franchise contract can deter entry. However, his analysis is not in a framework of vertical but horizontal differentiation.

3 The commitment problem when launching a fighter brand

This section first introduces the basic model of vertical differentiation with entry. We then show that if the incumbent cannot credibly commit to launching the fighter brand, product proliferation has no strategic role for entry deterrence.

3.1 The basic model

Consider a vertically differentiated market where products can be produced in different qualities \(q\in \left[ 0,\overline{q}\right] \) where \(\overline{q}>0\) is the highest possible quality level. We assume that a customer buys no more than one unit of the product from the qualities available in the marketplace. Customers’ preferences are described by a parameter \(\theta \) which is uniformly distributed on the interval \(\left[ 0,\overline{\theta }\right] \) with unit density, where \(\overline{\theta }\ge 1.\) The parameter \(\theta \) of a customer can be interpreted as the willingness to pay for a product. The net surplus when buying a product with quality q for price p then is

$$\begin{aligned} u\left( q,p\right) =q\theta -p. \end{aligned}$$

Customers who do not purchase receive zero utility.

On the supply side, we presume that an incumbent - henceforth, she - already developed and produces one product of highest quality \(q_{H}=\overline{q}\). This product is the incumbent’s premium product.Footnote 13 Before a competitor enters the market, the incumbent can launch a second product as fighter brand with lower quality. Let \(q_{L}>0\) be the quality of this fighter brand, with \(q_{L}<\overline{q}\). To focus on the incumbent’s commitment problem, we assume that she has no further development costs and can costlessly develop a lower quality product. Being aware of both product qualities \(q_{L},~q_{H}\), the entrant - henceforth, he - enters the market. The basic model assumes that the entrant has free access to the incumbent’s technology and no development costs for a lower quality level. Since market entry is without costs, the market becomes a duopoly.Footnote 14 The entrant then competes for customers by offering a product with quality \(q_{E}\) with \(q_{E}>0\). We assume in the basic model that introducing or withdrawing a fighter brand is without costs for the incumbent. As it is standard in literature on vertical differentiation, marginal costs of production are normalized to zero for both firms.Footnote 15

The incumbent observes the entrant’s quality choice \(q_{E}\) and both firms then set prices \(p_{H},~p_{L}\) and \(p_{E}\) conditional on the qualities offered in the market. This choice then determines firms’ demands \(x_{H},~x_{L}\) and \(x_{E}\). Since production is without costs, the entrant’s profits are

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{E}\left( q_{H},q_{L};q_{E}\right) =p_{E}x_{E}, \end{aligned}$$

and the total profits of the incumbent are

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{I}\left( q_{H},q_{L};q_{E}\right) =p_{H}x_{H}+p_{L}x_{L}. \end{aligned}$$

In sum, we consider the following sequence of eventsFootnote 16:

Stage 1:

The incumbent, already producing a product with quality level \(q_{H}=\overline{q}\), can introduce a second product quality \(q_{L}\) with \(q_{L}\in \left( 0,\overline{q}\right) \).

Stage 2:

The entrant enters the market and offers a product of quality \(q_{E}>0\).

Stage 3:

Having observed the product qualities offered in the market, the two firms compete by simultaneously choosing prices \(p_{H},~p_{L}\) respectively, \(p_{E},\) in the product market.

Stage 4:

Customers decide whether to buy from the firm that offers the best price-quality combination or whether not to buy at all.

3.2 The incumbent’s commitment problem

Before we solve the basic model, note that the incumbent would never introduce a second quality into the market without the threat of entry, see, e.g., Mussa and Rosen (1978), Moorthy (1984), or Tirole (1988, pp. 296–297). In fact, for a given quality level \(q_{H}\) of her product, the incumbent always uses a one-product strategy which leads to monopoly profits \(\pi _{I}=\overline{\theta }^{2}q_{H}/4\) and a monopoly price \(p=\overline{\theta }q_{H}/2\).Footnote 17 As noted before, the incumbent would then prefer the highest possible quality level, \(q_{H}=\overline{q}\), if she could also choose the quality level \(q_{H}\) of her product.

To solve the basic model of Sect. 3.1, we use backward induction. Suppose that the incumbent has launched the second product of quality \(q_{L}\) in Stage 1 and that the entrant entered by offering a product of quality \(q_{E}\) in Stage 2. Market competition in Stage 3 then depends on where the entrant located his product quality. Two product quality orderings can be distinguished. In the firewall scenario, the entrant positions his product \(q_{E}\) in the low quality area and \(q_{E}<q_{L}<q_{H}\). In the sandwich scenario, the entrant offers a new product \(q_{E}\) in an intermediate quality range between the incumbent’s two products and \(q_{L}<q_{E}<q_{H}\). Customers in Stage 4 can choose between three different products in both cases.

To discuss the incumbent’s commitment problem, suppose that the incumbent offers the high-quality product for a price \(p_{H}\) and that the entrant offers his product for a price \(p_{E}\). The consumption decisions in Stage 4 then depend on the price \(p_{L}\) for the fighter brand, which determines whether the fighter brand is active in the market with positive demand. To see this in more detail, consider first the firewall scenario, then the sandwich scenario.

Stage 4 - Firewall scenario

Suppose that the fighter brand has positive demand such that three indifferent customers exist in the market. One type of customer \(\theta _{1}\) is indifferent between buying the product with the highest quality \(q_{H}\) or the fighter brand with quality \(q_{L}\), that is, \(\theta _{1}q_{H}-p_{H}=\theta _{1}q_{L}-p_{L}\). One type of customer \(\theta _{2}\) is indifferent between buying the fighter brand from the incumbent or the entrant’s product with quality \(q_{E}\), that is, \(\theta _{2}q_{L}-p_{L}=\theta _{2}q_{E}-p_{E}\). And one type of customer \(\theta _{3}\) is indifferent between buying the lowest quality product \(q_{E}\) or nothing at all, that is, \(\theta _{3}q_{E}-p_{E}=0\). Hence, any customer with \(\theta \ge \theta _{1}\) will prefer to buy product \(q_{H}\), any customer with intermediate parameter \(\theta \in \left( \theta _{2},\theta _{1}\right) \) will buy product \(q_{L}\), any customer with intermediate parameter \(\theta \in \left( \theta _{3},\theta _{2}\right) \) will buy product \(q_{E}\), and any consumer \(\theta \le \theta _{3}\) will not buy at all. This consumption behavior results in market demands,

$$\begin{aligned} x_{H}=\overline{\theta }-\frac{p_{H}-p_{L}}{q_{H}-q_{L}},~x_{L}=\frac{p_{H}-p_{L}}{q_{H}-q_{L}}-\frac{p_{L}-p_{E}}{q_{L}-q_{E}},~x_{E}=\frac{p_{L}-p_{E}}{q_{L}-q_{E}}-\frac{p_{E}}{q_{E}}, \end{aligned}$$

and the incumbent’s profits \(p_{H}x_{H}+p_{L}x_{L}\) are

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{IF}\left( q_{H},q_{L};q_{E}\right) =p_{H}\left( \overline{\theta }-\frac{p_{H}-p_{L}}{q_{H}-q_{L}}\right) +p_{L}\left( \frac{p_{H}-p_{L}}{q_{H}-q_{L}}-\frac{p_{L}-p_{E}}{q_{L}-q_{E}}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Note that the demand \(x_{L}\) for the fighter brand is strictly positive, \(\theta _{2}<\theta _{1}\), only if \(p_{L}\) is sufficiently low, that is, lower than the weighted average of \(p_{H}\) and \(p_{E}\),

$$\begin{aligned} p_{L}<p_{H}\frac{\left( q_{L}-q_{E}\right) }{\left( q_{H}-q_{E}\right) }+p_{E}\left( 1-\frac{\left( q_{L}-q_{E}\right) }{\left( q_{H}-q_{E}\right) }\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(PC$_{F}$)

This price constraint \(\left( \text {PC}_{F}\right) \) has to be fulfilled for a fighter brand to be active in the market. If the constraint holds in equilibrium, price competition in Stage 3 leads to optimal prices \(p_{H}^{*},p_{L}^{*}\) and \(p_{E}^{*}\) and implies profits \(\pi _{IF}^{*}\left( q_{H},q_{L};q_{E}\right) \) for the incumbent.

Alternatively, the incumbent also can price the fighter brand out of the market; that is, the fighter brand is not active, and the price constraint \(\left( \text {PC}_{F}\right) \) is violated. In this case, only two indifferent customers exist in the market: One type of customer \(\theta _{1}\) is indifferent between buying the product \(q_{H}\) or the entrant’s product with quality \(q_{E}\), that is, \(\theta _{1}q_{H}-p_{H}=\theta _{1}q_{E}-p_{E} \). And, as before, type \(\theta _{3}\) customer is indifferent between buying the lowest quality product \(q_{E}\) or nothing at all, that is, \(\theta _{3}q_{E}-p_{E}=0\). The market demands in this case then are

$$\begin{aligned} x_{H}=\overline{\theta }-\frac{p_{H}-p_{E}}{q_{H}-q_{E}},~x_{E}=\frac{p_{H}-p_{E}}{q_{H}-q_{E}}-\frac{p_{E}}{q_{E}}, \end{aligned}$$

and the incumbent’s profits are

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{I}\left( q_{H};q_{E}\right) =p_{H}\left( \overline{\theta }-\frac{p_{H}-p_{E}}{q_{H}-q_{E}}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Price competition between the incumbent and the entrant then leads to optimal prices \(p_{H}^{*}\) and \(p_{E}^{*}\) in Stage 3, which results in profits \(\pi _{I}^{*}\left( q_{H};q_{E}\right) \) for the incumbent.

If we now compare the incumbent’s optimal profits in these two cases, a simple calculation shows that the incumbent is always better off when pricing the fighter brand out of the market, that is,

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{I}^{*}\left( q_{H};q_{E}\right) >\pi _{IF}^{*}\left( q_{H},q_{L};q_{E}\right) \end{aligned}$$

for all quality combinations \(\left( q_{H},q_{L};q_{E}\right) \).

Stage 4 - Sandwich scenario

Like the firewall scenario, suppose first that the incumbent prices the fighter brand to have a positive demand. Then there exist three indifferent customers in the market: The customer indexed by \(\theta _{1}\) is now given by \(\theta _{1}q_{H}-p_{H}=\theta _{1}q_{E}-p_{E},\) customer \(\theta _{2}\) is indifferent between buying the entrant’s product with quality \(q_{E}\) or the fighter brand from the incumbent, that is, \(\theta _{2}q_{E}-p_{E}=\theta _{2}q_{L}-p_{L}\) and the customer indexed by \(\theta _{3}\) is given by \(\theta _{3}q_{1\,L}-p_{L}=0\). Market demands then are

$$\begin{aligned} x_{H}=\overline{\theta }-\frac{p_{H}-p_{E}}{q_{H}-q_{E}},~x_{E}=\frac{p_{H}-p_{E}}{q_{H}-q_{E}}-\frac{p_{E}-p_{L}}{q_{E}-q_{L}},~x_{L}=\frac{p_{E}-p_{L}}{q_{E}-q_{L}}-\frac{p_{L}}{q_{L}}. \end{aligned}$$

The demand \(x_{L}\) for the fighter brand is strictly positive, \(\theta _{3}<\theta _{2}\), only if the price-quality ratio of the fighter brand is lower than the one of the entrant’s product,

$$\begin{aligned} p_{L}<p_{E}\frac{q_{L}}{q_{E}}. \end{aligned}$$
(PC$_{S}$)

This price constraint \(\left( \text {PC}_{S}\right) \) is necessary for a fighter brand to be active in the market. If it is satisfied in equilibrium, the corresponding optimal prices leads to equilibrium profits \(\pi _{IS}^{*}\left( q_{H},q_{L};q_{E}\right) \) for given product qualities \(\left( q_{H},q_{L};q_{E}\right) \).

As in the firewall scenario, the incumbent can also price the fighter brand out of the market. In this case, the price constraint \(\left( \text {PC}_{S}\right) \) is violated, and \(p_{L}\) is sufficiently high. Of course, the incumbent’s optimal profits are identical to those in the firewall scenario.

If we then compare the incumbent’s profits in both cases, note that her profits when the fighter brand is active in market are identical to the ones when she prices the fighter brand out of the market, if she sets \(q_{L}=0\). Moreover, the higher the quality of the fighter brand, the higher the quality of the entrant’s product in the sandwich scenario, which implies that price competition between the entrant’s and the incumbent’s products becomes fiercer. Hence, the incumbent’s profits decrease in the quality level of the fighter brand. In sum, for every quality level \(q_{L}>0\),

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{I}^{*}\left( q_{H},q_{E}\right) >\pi _{IS}^{*}\left( q_{H},q_{E};q_{L}\right) , \end{aligned}$$

and the incumbent is always better off when pricing the fighter brand sufficiently high such that its demand is zero.

Proposition 1

In the basic model, the incumbent cannot credibly launch a fighter brand. Instead, she offers the premium product \(q_{H}=\overline{q}\) for an equilibrium price \(p_{H}^{*}=\overline{\theta }\overline{q}/4\). The entrant chooses an equilibrium quality \(q_{E}^{*}=4\overline{q}/7\) and a price \(p_{E}^{*}=\overline{\theta }\overline{q}/14\). The resulting equilibrium profits are

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{I}^{*}\left( \overline{q};\frac{4}{7}\overline{q}\right) =\frac{7}{48}\overline{\theta }^{2}\overline{q},\ \pi _{E}^{*}\left( \overline{q};\frac{4}{7}\overline{q}\right) =\frac{1}{48}\overline{\theta }^{2}\overline{q}. \end{aligned}$$

Proof

See Appendix 1. \(\square \)

The proposition shows that the incumbent has a commitment problem when launching a fighter brand, independent of whether she uses a firewall or sandwich strategy. In both cases, after introducing the second product into the market to thwart the entrant, she always has an incentive to price the product out of the market in the subsequent price competition stage. Of course, the entrant will forego such a pricing behavior so that the quality decision when introducing his product will not be affected by the incumbent’s fighter brand. As a result, the entrant enters the market with a product whose quality level is identical to one without a fighter brand.

4 The optimal commitment to launch a fighter brand

In the following, we will show how the incumbent can credibly launch her fighter brand into the market. In particular, we extend the basic model of Sect. 3 to analyze two different commitment devices: Endogenous price leadership, where the incumbent has the possibility to announce a certain price behavior when introducing the fighter brand.Footnote 18 And dual channeling, where the incumbent has the possibility to delegate the pricing decision for the fighter brand to a third party. In the third subsection, we then compare these commitment devices.

4.1 Endogenous price leadership

Suppose the incumbent can introduce a second product before the entrant enters the market and, simultaneously, announces a price for which the fighter brand is active in the market. Our discussion in the last section then implies that the incumbent has to announce a price for the fighter brand that either satisfies the price constraint \(\left( \text {PC}_{F}\right) \) or the price constraint \(\left( \text {PC}_{S}\right) \), depending on whether the subsequent quality choices lead to a firewall or sandwich scenario.

Of course, without any commitment device to follow such a price strategy in the subsequent price competition stage, the incumbent’s announcement would be useless since she would price the fighter brand out of the market after known qualities. We, therefore, assume that the incumbent can advertise her price strategy when launching the fighter brand. In practice, such an advertisement is usually in the form of a catalog or a leaflet sent to consumers or by TV or Internet ads. The advertised price then serves as a commitment by the incumbent not to price the fighter brand higher than announced.

Whether the incumbent’s commitment to the advertised price is binding in the price competition stage depends on the number of consumers reached by the advertisement and her loss in reputation in the market when charging a higher price for her fighter brand than announced. This reputation loss might, for example, occur because customers retract their decision to buy the incumbent’s premium product.Footnote 19 To model this endogenous degree of commitment, we assume that the incumbent can choose an investment \(i\ge 0\) in advertising her price strategy. This advertising investment implicitly determines the incumbent’s loss in reputation R(i) when pricing the fighter brand higher than announced. In this sense, R(i) serves as deviation costs the incumbent has to pay if she deviates from her announcement. It constitutes her degree of commitment. We assume that the reputation loss R(i) increases in the advertising investment i, but with decreasing marginal reputation loss, that is \(R^{\prime }>0\) and \(R^{\prime \prime }<0\).

Our discussion in the last section then implies that the incumbent can credibly commit to the pricing of the fighter brand if the loss R(i) is sufficiently high such that she has no incentive to deviate from her announcement. Depending on the quality ordering, such a credible commitment requires sufficiently high advertising investment. In case of a firewall scenario, the advertising investment \(i_{F}\) has to ensure the following commitment constraint \(\left( \text {CC}_{F}\right) \):

$$\begin{aligned} R\left( i_{F}\right) \ge \pi _{I}^{*}\left( q_{H};q_{E}\right) -\pi _{IF}^{*}\left( q_{H},q_{L};q_{E}\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(CC$_{F}$)

And in the case of a sandwich scenario, the advertising investment \(i_{S}\) has to be sufficiently high such that the following commitment constraint \(\left( \text {CC}_{S}\right) \),

$$\begin{aligned} R\left( i_{S}\right) \ge \pi _{I}^{*}\left( q_{H};q_{E}\right) -\pi _{IS}^{*}\left( q_{H},q_{L};q_{E}\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(CC$_{S}$)

is satisfied.

Similar to Diaz et al. (2009), we assume that the incumbent has two possibilities when advertising her price strategy for the following analysis. She announces either to offer the fighter brand for a specific list price which she can lower by offering discounts in the price competition stage. Or, she announces to offer the fighter brand for a fixed price without any discounts. In the following, we analyze the incumbent’s commitment to a list price and delegate the discussion on how to commit to a fixed price to Appendix 2.

To analyze the list price commitment game, we modify the basic model from Sect. 3 as followsFootnote 20:

Stage 1:

The incumbent, already producing her premium product with quality level \(q_{H}=\overline{q}\), introduces a fighter brand of quality \(q_{L}\) and simultaneously chooses an advertising investment i\(i\ge 0,\) to announce that she will offer the fighter brand for a list price \(\bar{p}_{L}\), with \(\bar{p}_{L}>0\).

Stage 2:

The entrant enters the market and offers a product of quality \(q_{E}\).

Stage 3:

Having observed the product qualities offered in the market, the two firms compete by simultaneously choosing prices \(p_{H},p_{L}\) and \(p_{E}\) in the product market. In case the incumbent deviates from her announced price strategy, \(p_{L}>\bar{p}_{L}\), she has a reputation loss of \(R\left( i\right) \); otherwise, for \(p_{L}\le \bar{p}_{L}\), there is no additional cost.

Stage 4:

Customers decide whether to buy from the firm that offers the best price-quality combination or whether not to buy at all.

Note that the incumbent’s commitment problem is solved only if both commitment constraints are satisfied, either for the firewall or sandwich scenarios. Consider, for example, the firewall scenario. Suppose the advertising investment \(i_{F}\) is too low such that the commitment constraint \(\left( \text {CC}_{F}\right) \) is violated. In that case, the incumbent will price the fighter brand out of the market, independent of the list price \(\bar{p}_{L}\) announced in Stage 1, because the reputation loss \(R\left( i_{F}\right) \) is not sufficiently high to prevent her from doing so. If, on the other hand, the list price \(\bar{p}_{L}\) announced in Stage 1 is not sufficiently low to satisfy the price constraint \(\left( \text {PC}_{F}\right) \), the incumbent charges \(p_{L}=\bar{p}_{L}\) without any reputation loss, independent of her investment \(i_{F}\). In both cases, no customer demands the fighter brand, and the equilibrium of Proposition 1 results.

Because of this remark, we analyze the list price commitment game as follows: We first assume that the commitment constraints are both satisfied for the firewall and sandwich scenarios. Under this assumption, we then discuss whether the incumbent should better use the firewall or sandwich strategy to launch the fighter brand. This analysis determines the equilibrium qualities, prices, and profits for the commitment case. Given these results, we then consider the question, under which conditions the incumbent’s announcement are credible ex-post.

Suppose that the incumbent has credibly solved her commitment problem in equilibrium. That is, by announcing a list price \(\bar{p}_{L}^{*}\) and choosing an advertising investment \(i^{*}\) she has no incentive to price the fighter brand out of the market. To discuss how the incumbent should position the fighter brand given these assumptions, we build on the consumption decisions derived in the basic model in case the incumbent will not price the fighter brand out of the market. Market competition then determines the optimal equilibrium prices, and the equilibrium demand functions in the firewall and the sandwich scenario. At Stage 2, the entrant can then decide whether to position his product \(q_{E}\) in the low-quality area, \(q_{E}=q_{EF}<q_{L}\) (firewall scenario), or in an intermediate quality area between the incumbent’s two products, \(q_{E}=q_{ES}>q_{L}\) (sandwich scenario), when entering the market. In the first case, the optimal product positioning is similar to the result in Choi and Shin (1992), \(q_{EF}^{*}=4q_{L}/7\), and results in profits \(\pi _{EF}^{*}=\overline{\theta }^{2}q_{L}/48\). In the second case, the entrant’s optimal positioning \(q_{ES}^{*}\in \left( q_{L},q_{H}\right) \) is given by the first-order condition for maximizing profits \(\pi _{ES}\). In sum, the entrant then positions his product below the incumbent’s product if the resulting equilibrium profits exceed those in the sandwich scenario. Otherwise, the entrant chooses a sandwich position.

What position \(q_{L}\) is then optimal for the incumbent’s fighter brand in Stage 1? To answer this question, suppose that the incumbent would contemplate introducing a fighter brand as a firewall and \(q_{L}\) just below her high-quality product \(q_{H}\) such that the entrant will enter the market with a quality \(q_{EF}^{*}\) below \(q_{L}\). Inspecting the total derivative of her reduced-form profits then gives an intuition of the incumbent’s incentives to offer such a fighter brand as a firewallFootnote 21:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\pi _{IF}}{dq_{L}}=\overset{\text {demand effect}}{\overbrace{\underset{>0}{\underbrace{\frac{\partial \pi _{IF}}{\partial x_{L}}}}\underset{>0}{\underbrace{\frac{\partial x_{L}}{\partial q_{L}}}}}}+\overset{\text {1. strategic effect}}{\overbrace{\underset{>0}{\underbrace{\frac{\partial \pi _{IF}}{\partial x_{L}}}}\underset{>0}{\underbrace{\frac{\partial x_{L}}{\partial p_{E}}}}\underset{>0}{\underbrace{\frac{\partial p_{E}}{\partial q_{L}}}}}}+\overset{\text {2. strategic effect}}{\overbrace{\underset{>0}{\underbrace{\frac{\partial \pi _{IF}}{\partial x_{L}}}}\underset{<0}{\underbrace{\frac{\partial x_{L}}{\partial q_{EF}}}}\underset{>0}{\underbrace{\frac{\partial q_{E}}{\partial q_{L}}}}}}+\overset{\text {cannibalization effect}}{\overbrace{\underset{>0}{\underbrace{\frac{\partial \pi _{IF}}{\partial x_{H}}}}\underset{<0}{\underbrace{\frac{\partial x_{H}}{\partial q_{L}}}}}} \end{aligned}$$

We can decompose the total derivative into four effects; the demand effect, the first and second strategic effect, and the cannibalization effect. The demand effect is positive, which implies that decreasing the quality \(q_{L}\) leads to fewer profits for the incumbent through lower demand for the fighter brand. The first strategic effect is also positive saying that decreasing quality \(q_{L}\) leads to less price competition in the market. A lower price \(p_{E}\) of the entrant’s product then reduces the demand for the fighter brand and thus implies fewer profits. However, the second strategic effect is negative, indicating that a lower quality of the fighter brand increases profits. This follows because a lower quality also reduces the entrant’s quality choice, expanding the fighter brand’s demand. Moreover, the cannibalization effect is also negative because a lower quality of her fighter brand cannibalizes the demand for her high-quality product to a lower extent. The analysis shows that the last two adverse effects dominate the first two positive effects. Hence, the incumbent prefers to position her firewall with quality as low as possible.

Of course, this strategy has its limits because the entrant’s profits successively diminish when he responds to a lower quality \(q_{L}\) of the fighter brand with a lower quality \(q_{EF}^{*}\left( q_{L}\right) \). If the incumbent sets \(q_{L}=0\), the entrant’s best response when following this strategy would be \(q_{EF}^{*}\left( 0\right) =0\), resulting in zero profits. But for \(q_{L}=0\), the entrant optimally chooses a product quality above \(q_{L}\) by setting \(q_{ES}^{*}\left( 0\right) =4q_{H}/7\) while earning profits \(\pi _{ES}=\overline{\theta }^{2}q_{H}/48\). On the other hand, the entrant’s profits strictly decrease when he responds to a higher quality of the fighter brand with an even higher quality \(q_{ES}^{*}\) in the immediate quality area \(\left( q_{L},q_{H}\right) \). Continuity then implies that there exists a critical value \(q_{L}^{*}\) such that the entrant is indifferent between positioning in the low-quality range or an intermediate quality range. Then the entrant chooses his product quality \(q_{E}\) below \(q_{L}\) as long as the fighter brand’s quality \(q_{L}\) is greater than \(q_{L}^{*}\) and he positions \(q_{E}\) in an intermediate range \(\left( q_{L},q_{H}\right) \) otherwise.

Hence, to analyze the incumbent’s optimal positioning strategy, it is necessary to consider her profits in the sandwich scenario. Note first that for \(q_{L}=0\), the incumbent’s profits are \(\pi _{IS}=7\overline{\theta }^{2}q_{H}/48\) given the entrant optimally chooses \(q_{ES}^{*}\left( 0\right) =4q_{H}/7\). Inspecting the total derivative of its reduced-form profits then shows that this is the highest profit the incumbent can earn under the sandwich scenario:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\pi _{IS}}{dq_{L}}= & {} \overset{\text {demand effect}}{\overbrace{\underset{>0}{\underbrace{\frac{\partial \pi _{I}}{\partial x_{L}}}}\underset{>0}{\underbrace{\frac{\partial x_{L}}{\partial q_{L}}}}}}+\overset{\text {1. strategic effect on }x_{L}}{\overbrace{\underset{>0}{\underbrace{\frac{\partial \pi _{I}}{\partial x_{L}}}}\underset{>0}{\underbrace{\frac{\partial x_{L}}{\partial p_{E}}}}\underset{<0}{\underbrace{\frac{\partial p_{E}}{\partial q_{L}}}}}}+\overset{\text {1. strategic effect on }x_{H}}{\overbrace{\underset{>0}{\underbrace{\frac{\partial \pi _{I}}{\partial x_{H}}}}\underset{>0}{\underbrace{\frac{\partial x_{H}}{\partial p_{E}}}}\underset{<0}{\underbrace{\frac{\partial p_{E}}{\partial q_{L}}}}}} \\{} & {} +\overset{\text {2. strategic effect on }x_{L}}{\overbrace{\underset{>0}{\underbrace{\frac{\partial \pi _{I}}{\partial x_{L}}}}\underset{<0}{\underbrace{\frac{\partial x_{L}}{\partial q_{ES}}}}\underset{>0}{\underbrace{\frac{\partial q_{ES}}{\partial q_{L}}}}}}+\overset{\text {2. strategic effect on }x_{H}}{\overbrace{\underset{>0}{\underbrace{\frac{\partial \pi _{I}}{\partial x_{H}}}}\underset{<0}{\underbrace{\frac{\partial x_{H}}{\partial q_{ES}}}}\underset{>0}{\underbrace{\frac{\partial q_{ES}}{\partial q_{L}}}}}} \end{aligned}$$

In this case, the total derivative can be decomposed into five effects, the demand effect and two first and second strategic effects. The demand effect is positive as before, implying that a lower quality \(q_{L}\) leads to fewer profits for the incumbent through lower demand for the fighter brand. The first strategic effect on the demand for the fighter brand now is negative because sandwiching the entrant with increasing quality \(q_{L}\) leads to more price competition in the market. A lower price \(p_{E}\) of the entrant’s product then reduces demand for the fighter brand and thus implies fewer profits. For the same reason, a lower price \(p_{E}\) also reduces demand for the premium product and also means fewer profits. Moreover, both strategic effects are negative since a higher quality of the fighter brand sandwiches the entrant’s quality choice on a higher level which implies less demand for the fighter brand and the premium product. Note that the direct cannibalization effect is zero since the quality of her fighter brand in the sandwich scenario has no direct impact on the demand for the incumbent’s high-quality product. The analysis shows that the last two negative effects dominate the first two positive effects.

Figure 1 shows the optimal positioning for the incumbent’s fighter brand: First, the incumbent’s profits are always higher in the firewall scenario than in the sandwich scenario. Hence, she prefers that the entrant positions his product below her fighter brand. Second, her profits in the firewall scenario are decreasing in the quality level of the fighter brand. Hence, she prefers to position the fighter brand slightly above \(q_{L}^{*}\) where the entrant is indifferent between the firewall and sandwich scenario.Footnote 22

Fig. 1
figure 1

Sandwich versus firewall strategy under endogenous price leadership

Proposition 2

Suppose that the incumbent has credibly solved her commitment problem by announcing a list price \(\bar{p}_{L}^{*}\) and investing \(i^{*}\) in advertising this announcement. Then the incumbent will always launch a fighter brand as a firewall. In particular, she offers the premium product \(q_{H}=\overline{q}\) for an equilibrium price \(p_{H}^{*}=\left( 2-\beta _{L}\right) \overline{\theta }\overline{q}/4\) and sells the fighter brand with quality \(q_{L}^{*}=\beta _{L}\overline{q}\) for a price \(p_{L}^{*}=\beta _{L}\overline{\theta }\overline{q}/4.\) The entrant chooses an equilibrium quality \(q_{E}^{*}=\gamma _{L}\overline{q}\) and a price \(p_{E}^{*}=\gamma _{L}\overline{\theta }\overline{q}/8\) with \(\beta _{L}=0.548\) and \(\gamma _{L}=4\beta _{L}/7.\) The resulting pre-advertising equilibrium profits are

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{I}^{*}\left( \overline{q},\beta _{L}\overline{q};\gamma _{L}\overline{q}\right) =\frac{1}{48}\left( 12-5\beta _{L}\right) \overline{\theta }^{2}\overline{q},\ \pi _{E}^{*}\left( \overline{q},\beta _{L}\overline{q};\gamma _{L}\overline{q}\right) =\frac{1}{48}\beta _{L}\overline{\theta }^{2}\overline{q}. \end{aligned}$$

Proof

See Appendix 1. \(\square \)

In this equilibrium, the ideal positioning of the three products shows a familiar structure (see Fig. 2):

Fig. 2
figure 2

Positioning structure in equilibrium and practice under endogenous price leadership

The price-quality positions of the three products exhibit a decreasing ratio in equilibrium. In fact, the relationships

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{p_{H}^{*}}{q_{H}}=\frac{1}{4}\left( 2-\beta _{L}\right) \overline{\theta }>\frac{p_{L}^{*}}{q_{L}^{*}}=\frac{1}{4}\overline{\theta }>\frac{p_{E}^{*}}{q_{E}^{*}}=\frac{1}{8}\overline{\theta } \end{aligned}$$

show that the premium product can maintain the best price-quality ratio in the market, supported by the fighter brand that effectively keeps with its price-quality ratio competition off the backs of the premium product. The entrant only remains in the position as a low price-low quality competitor. The figure also shows the price-quality positioning in the following case in point, see Dolan and Simon (1996, p.213f): A leading incumbent of lighting products introduced a second product to defend its premium product against the attack of highly cheap imports from China. Compared to the premium brand, the fighter brand was slightly modified while its price was about 40% below the one of the premium brand. The Chinese product was priced 60-70% below the premium brand’s price.

How effectively the incumbent uses her fighter brand under endogenous price leadership to protect the high-quality brand can be seen by consulting the market demands of the three products,

$$\begin{aligned} x_{H}^{*}=\frac{1}{2}\overline{\theta }>x_{E}^{*}=\frac{7}{24}\overline{\theta }>x_{L}^{*}=\frac{1}{12}\overline{\theta }. \end{aligned}$$

The target of the fighter brand, to compete with the low-price entrant while still serving the high price segment with the premium product, is met. Compared to the monopoly situation, the incumbent still covers the upper half of the entire market with the premium product. Of course, the price of the premium product is now lower than its monopoly price.

Given these insights, we can now answer the question under which circumstances the incumbent actually has an incentive to commit to her fighter brand credibly. Consider first the list price \(\bar{p}_{L}^{*}\) in Stage 1. Of course, the incumbent will always set \(\bar{p}_{L}^{*}\) higher than or equal to the equilibrium price \(p_{L}^{*}\) of the fighter brand to maximize her profits. Moreover, the upper bound for the list price results from the price constraint \(\left( \text {PC}_{F}\right) \). Using the equilibrium qualities and prices from Proposition 2, the demand for the fighter brand is positive as long as

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{p}_{L}^{*}\le \frac{8-5\beta _{L}}{7-4\beta _{L}}p_{L}^{*}=\beta _{L}p_{L}^{*}, \end{aligned}$$

with \(\beta _{L}=1.094.\) To make her price announcement \(\bar{p}_{L}^{*}\in \left[ p_{L}^{*},\beta _{L}p_{L}^{*}\right] \) binding ex-post, the incumbent’s commitment constraint \(\left( \text {CC}_{F}\right) \) then has to be satisfied. Note that if the incumbent would price her fighter brand out of the market given the entrant has chosen a quality level \(q_{E}^{*}=\gamma _{L}\overline{q}\), the incumbent’s profit would increase to

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{I}^{*}\left( \overline{q};q_{E}^{*}\right) =\frac{7\left( 7-4\beta _{L}\right) }{4\left( 7-\beta _{L}\right) ^{2}}\overline{\theta }^{2}\overline{q}. \end{aligned}$$

Hence, the commitment constraint is satisfied, if

$$\begin{aligned} R\left( i\right) \ge R_{M}^{*}=\frac{\left( 1-\beta _{L}\right) \left( 77-5\beta _{L}\right) }{48\left( 7-\beta _{L}\right) ^{2}}\beta _{L}\overline{\theta }^{2}\overline{q}. \end{aligned}$$

When her investment i at Stage 1 of the model and the corresponding reputation loss \(R\left( i\right) \) is sufficiently high, \(R\left( i\right) \ge R_{M}^{*},\) she has no incentive to price the fighter brand out of the market. Compared to the basic model without endogenous price leadership, the credible launch of her fighter brand then increases her profits by

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta _{M}^{*}=\frac{5}{48}\left( 1-\beta _{L}\right) \overline{\theta }^{2}\overline{q}, \end{aligned}$$

which defines the value of her commitment. Let \(\bar{\imath }_{M}\) be the critical investment such that \(R\left( \bar{\imath }_{M}\right) =R_{M}^{*}\). Since the reputation loss is increasing in her investment and investments in advertising reduce her profits, the incumbent optimally either chooses \(i^{*}=\bar{\imath }_{M}\) to make the list price credible ex-post, or she invests nothing, and her announcement is not binding. As a consequence, the entrant forms a belief about whether the incumbent would later have an incentive to price her fighter brand out of the market or not. In the first case, the entrant then chooses a quality level \(q_{E}=4\overline{q}/7\) according to Proposition 1. In the second case, he chooses a quality level \(q_{E}=\gamma _{L}\overline{q}\) according to Proposition 2.

Proposition 3

Let \(\bar{\imath }_{M}\,\)be defined by \(R\left( \bar{\imath }_{M}\right) =R_{M}^{*}\).

  1. 1.

    If \(\bar{\imath }_{M}\le 5\left( 1-\beta _{L}\right) \overline{\theta }^{2}\overline{q}/48\), the incumbent acts as a price leader. She announces a list price \(\bar{p}_{L}^{*}\in \left[ p_{L}^{*},\beta _{L}p_{L}^{*}\right] \) and chooses an advertising investment \(i_{M}^{*}=\bar{\imath }_{M}\,\) to credibly commit to her fighter brand as characterized in Proposition 2. The incumbent’s post-advertising profits then are

    $$\begin{aligned} \pi _{I}^{*}\left( \overline{q},\beta _{L}\overline{q};\gamma _{L}\overline{q}\right) -\bar{\imath }_{M}. \end{aligned}$$
  2. 2.

    If \(\bar{\imath }_{M}>5\left( 1-\beta _{L}\right) \overline{\theta }^{2}\overline{q}/48\), the incumbent chooses not to invest, \(i_{M}^{*}=0\), and her profits are the same as in Proposition 1.

Proof

See Appendix 1. \(\square \)

The interpretation of this result is straightforward: Depending on the incumbent’s loss in reputation when she deviates from the announced price strategy, she uses a price commitment whenever the benefits exceed the costs, that is, whenever the value of commitment is higher than the necessary investment in advertising. In the first case, the loss in reputation as a function of her advertising investment is relatively steep which makes the investment \(i^{*}\) necessary for not deviating from her announcement beneficial. In the second case, the function \(R\left( i\right) \) is less steep so that the investment \(i^{*}\) necessary for a credible commitment exceeds the difference in profits \(R_{M}^{*}\) from doing so.

The fact that the incumbent’s list price is not unique in equilibrium is due to the rationality of customers. They know in equilibrium that the incumbent will sell the fighter brand for \(p_{L}^{*}\) and discount it by \(\left( \bar{p}_{L}^{*}-p_{L}^{*}\right) \). Hence, the list price announced is irrelevant for their decision. The finding would be different if we would assume that the incumbent could influence customers’ buying decisions by the announced posted price \(\bar{p}_{L}^{*}\in \left[ p_{L}^{*},\beta _{L}p_{L}^{*}\right] \). In this case, the list price serves as a reference point, and the size of the discount adds to the willingness to buy. Then that \(\bar{p}_{L}^{*}=\beta _{L}p_{L}^{*}\) and the list price is uniquely determined.

Concerning the entrant’s cost when entering the market, the following remarks are worth noting:

Remark 1

Suppose the quality positioning of the entrant requires some investment. That is, let \(c_{E}\left( q\right) \) be the entrant’s cost in developing a specific quality q, with \(c_{E}\left( q\right) =\delta _{E}q^{2}/2\) where the cost parameter \(\delta _{E}\) reflects the efficiency of the entrant’s investments into quality development. The entrant’s decision whether to position his product below the quality of the fighter brand, \(q_{E}=q_{EF}<q_{L}\), or between the incumbent’s products \(q_{E}=q_{ES}\in \left( q_{L},q_{H}\right) \) then is not only affected by corresponding marginal revenues but also by the marginal quality costs of these two options. Of course, the higher the cost parameter \(\delta _{E}\), the lower the optimal quality positioning of his product, independent of the underlying firewall or sandwich scenario. That is, \(\partial q_{EF}^{*}/\partial \delta _{E}<0\) as well as \(\partial q_{ES}^{*}/\partial \delta _{E}<0\).Footnote 23 However, the cost effect is more significant in the sandwich scenario than in the firewall scenario. To see this, consider the critical value \(q_{L}^{*}\left( \delta _{E}\right) \) such that the entrant is indifferent between positioning his product in the low-quality range or the intermediate quality range. Since his quality positioning is higher in the sandwich scenario than in the firewall scenario, \(q_{ES}^{*}\left( \delta _{E}\right) >q_{EF}^{*}\left( \delta _{E}\right) \), his quality cost in the first case is higher than in the second case. But then the critical value \(q_{L}^{*}\left( \delta _{E}\right) \) for which the entrant is indifferent between both scenarios is decreasing in the entrant’s efficiency of quality development, that is, \(\partial q_{L}^{*}/\partial \delta _{E}<0\).

Remark 2

Suppose the entrant has to bear entry costs \(F_{E}\ge 0\) when entering the market. If these costs are sufficiently high, the entrant will never enter, and the incumbent does not need to launch a second product while offering the maximal quality \(q_{H}=\overline{q}\). Using the equilibrium payoffs from Proposition 1, this happens whenever \(F_{E}\ge \pi _{E}^{*}\left( \overline{q};4\overline{q}/7\right) =\overline{\theta }^{2}\overline{q}/48\). Suppose the entrant’s entry costs are lower than this critical value. In that case, our analysis above shows that the incumbent can block entry by offering a fighter brand if endogenous price leadership is beneficial. According to Proposition 2, this happens when \(F_{E}\ge \pi _{E}^{*}\left( \overline{q},\beta _{L}\overline{q};\gamma _{L}\overline{q}\right) =\beta _{L}\overline{\theta }^{2}\overline{q}/48\). If the entrant’s entry costs are even lower than this critical value, the incumbent may follow two different strategies under endogenous price leadership: she may accommodate or deter entry. In the first case, her pre-advertising profits are \(\pi _{I}^{*}\left( \overline{q},\beta _{L}\overline{q};\gamma _{L}\overline{q}\right) =\left( 12-5\beta _{L}\right) \overline{\theta }^{2}\overline{q}/48\) according to Proposition 2. For deterrence, note that the incumbent cannot use her fighter brand \(q_{L}\) since any reduction in this quality level would encourage the entrant to position his product between the incumbent’s products \(q_{E}\in \left( q_{L},q_{H}\right) \). Hence, the incumbent can pursue a deterrence strategy only by re-positioning her premium product. Let \(q_{H}=48F_{E}/\beta _{L}\overline{\theta }^{2}\) be the quality of the premium product such that the entrant breaks even, \(\pi _{E}^{*}\left( q_{H},\beta _{L}q_{H};\gamma _{L}q_{H}\right) -F_{E}=\beta _{L}\overline{\theta }^{2}q_{H}/48\). Then the incumbent earns pre-advertising profits \(\pi _{I}^{*}\left( q_{H},\beta _{L}q_{H};\gamma _{L}q_{H}\right) =\left( 12-5\beta _{L}\right) F_{E}/\beta _{L}\) which are lower than \(\pi _{I}^{*}\left( \overline{q},\beta _{L}\overline{q};\gamma _{L}\overline{q}\right) \) since \(\beta _{L}\overline{\theta }^{2}\overline{q}/48>F_{E}\). Hence, re-positioning is never optimal for the incumbent, and entry occurs.

4.2 Dual channeling

Another possibility for the incumbent to commit to the pricing of her fighter brand is to delegate this decision to another party, see Hadfield (1991). In the context of our model, the incumbent can, for example, give the sale of the fighter brand to an independent retailer or sales force - henceforth, she. Such a strategy was, for example, chosen by Anheuser-Busch, see Ritson (2009). In the sixties, the company introduced a new fighter brand called Busch Bavarian with a separate sales force and distinct distribution to distance it from its other two premium brands, Budweiser and Michelob.

We analyze how such dual channeling can serve as a commitment device in the following. The sequence of events in this modified interaction is as follows:

Stage 1a:

The incumbent, already producing a product with quality level \(q_{H}=\overline{q}\), can introduce a fighter brand with quality \(q_{R} \). If she does so, she delegates the sale of this second product to an independent retailer by offering a contract \(\left( w,x_{R},L\right) \), where w denotes the wholesale price for selling a product of quality \(q_{R} \) to the retailer, \(x_{R}\) denotes the quantity she supplies, and L denotes the franchise fee the retailer pays to the incumbent for doing her business.

Stage 1b:

The retailer decides whether to accept this contract or not. She accepts whenever her profits are non-negative.

Stage 2:

The entrant enters the market and offers a product of quality \(q_{E}.\)

Stage 3:

Having observed the product qualities offered in the market, the three firms choose prices: The incumbent sets \(p_{H},\) the retailer sets \(p_{R},\) and the entrant sets \(p_{E}\).

Stage 4:

Customers decide whether to buy from the firm that offers the best price-quality combination or whether not to buy at all. The incumbent and the retailer both honor the contract signed.Footnote 24

Different from the basic model, the incumbent now maximizes her profits \(\pi _{I}\left( q_{H},q_{R};q_{E}\right) =p_{H}x_{H}+wx_{R}+L\), whereas the retailer chooses the price \(p_{R}\) of the fighter brand to maximize

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{R}\left( q_{H},q_{R};q_{E}\right) =\left( p_{R}-w\right) x_{R}-L. \end{aligned}$$

The entrant still maximizes his profits \(\pi _{E}\left( q_{H},q_{R};q_{E}\right) =p_{E}x_{E}\).

How does the equilibrium behavior change in this dual channeling setup compared to the extended model in Sect. 4.1? First, we immediately see that the optimal price competition in the sandwich scenario is identical in both models. The incumbent’s maximization problem in the sandwich scenario consists of two subproblems - choosing the optimal price for the premium product and the one for the fighter brand. Both subproblems, however, are independent of each other since no cannibalization occurs, so it does not matter whether the retailer or the incumbent sets the price for the fighter brand.

Second, however, market competition in the firewall scenario is now different: Since the retailer, when setting his optimal price \(p_{R}\) does not care about the cannibalization effect with the incumbent’s brand product, the optimal price reactions differ. In particular, price competition between the premium and the fighter brand is lower but price competition between the fighter brand and the entrant’s product more fierce. To see this more clearly, note that the incumbent’s optimal price setting for her premium and fighter brand in the basic model is characterized by

$$\begin{aligned} p_{H}^{*}-p_{L}^{*}=\frac{1}{2}\overline{\theta }\left( q_{H}-q_{L}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

To avoid cannibalization with her premium product, she always keeps the price difference between her two products constant. Hence, the price competition between the fighter brand and the entrant’s product has direct feedback on the price of her premium product, and the incumbent is less willing to lower the price for the fighter brand. This feedback then is less strict in case the retailer is in charge of pricing the fighter brand:

$$\begin{aligned} p_{H}^{*}-\frac{1}{2}p_{R}^{*}=\frac{1}{2}\overline{\theta }\left( q_{H}-q_{R}\right) +\frac{1}{2}w. \end{aligned}$$

In this case, price competition between the retailer and the entrant does not influence the incumbent’s premium product price as much as when the incumbent competes with the entrant. But this implies that the incumbent is less restricted in setting the price \(p_{H}\) and she will therefore choose in equilibrium a higher price for her premium product. On the other side of the market, the retailer’s price for the fighter brand is less dependent on the incumbent’s price, and she will therefore intensify competition with the entrant.

Moreover, the wholesale price w influences the feedback of price competition between the retailer and the entrant on the price of the incumbent’s premium product. In fact, the higher the wholesale price, the larger the price spread between the premium product and fighter brand. Hence, by not charging any wholesale price, \(w=0\), the incumbent can increase the market demand for her premium product, which is higher than the one in the monopoly market. Note that \(w=0\) does not imply a loss in profits for the incumbent because she optimally sets \(L^{*}=\left( p_{R}-w\right) x_{R}\) such that the retailer always breaks even. Doing so still ensures that the retailer accepts contracting and results in profits for the incumbent equal to \(\pi _{M}=p_{H}x_{H}+p_{R}x_{R}\).

Another consequence of the intensified price competition under dual channeling is a lower quality of the fighter brand in equilibrium. The reasoning for this observation is the following. The lower prices imply that the entrant’s profits in the presence of a retailer are smaller than without delegation in the firewall scenario by a factor

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{q_{H}-q_{L}}{4q_{H}-q_{L}}<1. \end{aligned}$$

Since her profits in the sandwich scenario are unchanged, and the optimal quality level of the fighter brand follows from equalizing her profits in both scenarios, see Sect. 4.1, a lower profit in the firewall scenario directly implies that \(q_{R}^{*}<q_{L}^{*}.\)

Proposition 4

If the incumbent uses dual channeling to commit to the launch of her fighter brand credibly, she offers the premium product \(q_{H}=\overline{q}\) for an equilibrium price \(p_{H}^{*}=\left( 0.276\right) \overline{\theta }\overline{q}\) and chooses a quality level \(q_{R}^{*}=\left( 0.486\right) \overline{q}\) for the fighter brand. She offers a contract with \(w^{*}=0\), \(x_{R}^{*}=\left( 0.308\right) \overline{\theta }\) and \(L^{*}=\left( 0.005\right) \overline{\theta }^{2}\overline{q}\) which the retailer accepts who offers the fighter brand for a price \(p_{L}^{*}=\left( 0.003\right) \overline{\theta }\overline{q}\). The entrant chooses an equilibrium quality \(q_{E}^{*}=\left( 0.337\right) \overline{q}\) and a price \(p_{E}^{*}=\left( 0.001\right) \overline{\theta }\overline{q}\). The resulting equilibrium profits are \(\pi _{R}^{*}\left( \overline{q},q_{R}^{*};q_{E}^{*}\right) =0\) and

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{I}^{*}\left( \overline{q},q_{R}^{*};q_{E}^{*}\right) =\left( 0.152\right) \overline{\theta }^{2}\overline{q},\ \pi _{E}^{*}\left( \overline{q},q_{R}^{*};q_{E}^{*}\right) =\left( 0.001\right) \overline{\theta }^{2}\overline{q}\text {.} \end{aligned}$$

Proof

See Appendix 1. \(\square \)

Of course, in equilibrium, the incumbent loses profits by delegating the pricing of her fighter brand to an independent retailer. The positioning of the three products compared to the basic model shows the following structure (see Fig. 3):

Fig. 3
figure 3

Positioning structure in equilibrium with and without a dual channeling

The price-quality positions of the three products in dual channeling exhibits a decreasing ratio in equilibrium,

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{p_{H}^{*}}{q_{H}^{*}}=\left( 0.276\right) \overline{\theta }>\frac{p_{R}^{*}}{q_{R}^{*}}=\left( 0.073\right) \overline{\theta }>\frac{p_{E}^{*}}{q_{E}^{*}}=\left( 0.03\right) \overline{\theta } \end{aligned}$$

as in the basic model. However, the market’s price-quality ratios are lower than those in a market, where the incumbent can commit herself to the pricing of her fighter brand by endogenous price leadership.

4.3 The optimal commitment device

Proposition 4 shows that the incumbent always benefits from dual channeling compared to the non-commitment scenario,

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{I}^{*}\left( \overline{q},q_{R}^{*};q_{E}^{*}\right) >\pi _{I}^{*}\left( \overline{q};\frac{4}{7}\overline{q}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Hence, she prefers to commit herself to launch a fighter brand credibly. In the following, we consider her decision whether to use endogenous price leadership or dual channeling as a commitment device. We consider two influencing variables, the reputation elasticity

$$\begin{aligned} \rho _{R}\left( i\right) =R^{\prime }\left( i\right) \frac{i}{R\left( i\right) }, \end{aligned}$$

which measures how customers react to a deviation from the incumbent’s price announcement and the attractiveness of the market,

$$\begin{aligned} \alpha =\overline{\theta }^{2}\overline{q}, \end{aligned}$$

as a measure of the quality level \(\overline{q}\) of the incumbent’s premium product and customers’ maximal willingness \(\overline{\theta }\) to pay for quality.

Proposition 5

The incumbent always commits to the launch of the fighter brand. Depending on the attractiveness \(\alpha \) of the market, the optimal commitment device is as follows: There exists a critical value \(\alpha ^{*}\) such that

  • if \(\alpha \le \alpha ^{*}\), the incumbent prefers an endogenous price commitment with a list price, and

  • if \(\alpha \ge \alpha ^{*}\), she favors dual channeling.

Moreover, the critical value \(\alpha ^{*}\) is increasing in the reputation elasticity \(\rho _{R}\).

Proof

See Appendix 3 and the proof of Proposition 8 for the more general case including an endogenous price commitment with a fixed price. \(\square \)

The interpretation of this result follows directly from our previous discussions: On the one hand, the incumbent’s profit gains from a commitment are highest for a list price commitment and lowest for dual channeling. On the other hand, the necessary advertising investments for a credible commitment are reverse: no investments for dual channeling, some investments for a price leadership with a list price commitment.

To discuss how the reputation elasticity and the market attractiveness influence the optimality of these commitment devices, consider first the sensitivity of customers to a deviation from the incumbent’s price announcement. If the reputation elasticity is low, the incumbent cannot credibly commit herself not to price the fighter brand out of the market, and dual channeling is the only option. If the reputation elasticity is sufficiently high, an endogenous price commitment with a list price becomes possible. In this case, the higher advertising investments by the incumbent necessary to make her announcement credible are worthwhile due to the increased commitment value.

Concerning the market attractiveness, note that the higher \(\alpha \), the higher the commitment value, making higher investments in advertising necessary. Suppose the market is not very attractive. Then the investment in advertising necessary for endogenous price leadership is small for a list price commitment and the incumbent prefers the list price commitment with the highest profits. If the market’s attractiveness increases, this commitment device is not possible anymore because the investment necessary for its credibility is too high. In this case, the incumbent prefers dual channeling as a commitment device since her reduced profits when cooperating with a retailer are independent of any investment in her reputation.

5 Conclusion

The present paper considered the optimal launch of a fighter brand to thwart a new entrant. Starting with the observation that the incumbent will always price such a second product out of the market, we showed that the price policy for the fighter brand is crucial for its success. We, therefore, analyzed two commitment devices, endogenous price commitment with a list price and dual channeling with price delegation to a retailer. We showed that the incumbent always prefers to use a commitment device and that endogenous price announcements are optimal if the market is not attractive and customers react sufficiently sensitive to a deviation.

The incumbent’s ability to set up a commitment device enables him to act like a Stackelberg leader. However, different from the conventional wisdom that a Stackelberg pricing leader wants to raise prices, the incumbent in the present model is trying to use her first-mover advantage to commit to lowering the price. At first sight, such a paradoxical behavior seems to be odd. At second sight, however, the rationality for this behavior is grounded on the timing of moves: In a standard Stackelberg pricing game with given differentiated products, the Stackelberg leader takes the price response of the follower into account when deciding on her pricing. In our model of vertical differentiated products \(q_{H}\) and \(q_{E}\) with \(q_{H}>q_{E}\), the incumbent’s optimal price \(p_{H}^{S}\) when acting as price leader is

$$\begin{aligned} p_{H}^{S}=\frac{\overline{\theta }q_{H}\left( q_{H}-q_{E}\right) }{\left( 2q_{H}-q_{E}\right) }, \end{aligned}$$

which is higher than the optimal price \(p_{H}^{*}\) in the simultaneous pricing game.Footnote 25 The difference to the present model then lies in the fact that product qualities are not fixed when the incumbent commits to her pricing strategy. In particular, the entrant can perfectly imitate the incumbent’s fighter brand in quality and price, thus driving the fighter out of the market.

A key ingredient of our model is the uniform distribution of customers. While this is a common assumption in the literature on vertical differentiation and makes our analysis tractable, it is not without loss of generality. For suppose customers have bimodally distributed preferences. Then the incumbent might be incentivized to offer a second, low-quality product in addition to the premium product without a threat of entry. An entrant can then offer his product in the intermediate range of the market between the two modes, leading to a sandwich instead of a firewall scenario. However, the incumbent then faces no commitment problem since the low-quality product will generate positive profits, regardless of whether the entrant entered the market. On the other hand, the commitment problem is not an artifact of the uniform distribution of customers but can be established even under a more general distribution assumption.Footnote 26 For suppose, customers’ preferences are log-concave distributed. Building on the analysis by Benassi et al. (2019), it is easy to show that the incumbent would never launch a second product without the threat of entry.Footnote 27 Hence, when launching a fighter brand to influence the positioning of the entrant’s product, the incumbent faces a similar commitment problem as in our basic model with a uniform distribution of customers. As a consequence, the central insights of our analysis carry over to more general distribution assumptions.

Another key ingredient of our model is the assumption that the entrant is perfectly informed about the incumbent’s commitment device. As argued in the introductory section, this assumption implies that if the launch of the fighter brand would not preemptive, its quality will not influence the quality decision of the entrant’s product launch. Under asymmetric information, however, the quality decision of the entrant could still be affected even if the launch of the fighter brand may happen after the entrant decides its quality.Footnote 28 To see this suppose that the entrant is unsure about the credibility of the incumbent’s commitment to introduce a fighter brand after his quality choice \(q_{E}\). In the case of endogenous price leadership, for example, the advertising investments might be private information of the incumbent so that the entrant is unsure about the degree of commitment that her announcement is binding ex-post. Consequently, the entrant has to form some belief about the credibility of the incumbent’s commitment. Now suppose that her price commitment is not binding ex-post but that the entrant expects the announcement to be credible. If this case happens, it will lead to a two-product market constellation in which the entrant positions his product in the lower market segment and the incumbent prices the fighter brand out of the market, \(q_{E}^{*}=\frac{4}{7}\beta _{L}\overline{q}<q_{H}^{*}=\overline{q}.\) Hence, the possibility of a launch would influence the entrant’s quality choice even if this launch of the fighter brand might happen after the entrant decides on quality.Footnote 29

Our analysis assumed that customers were aware of the differences in product quality. In particular, we implicitly assumed that customers have perfect knowledge that the fighter brand is simply a lower quality product at a lower price than the premium brand, which is, however, not necessarily the case, see Ritson (2009, p.88). In 1994 Kodak’s best-selling Gold Plus film lost market share as many of its customers switched to Fujicolor’s Super G film, priced 20% lower. To combat its competitor, Kodak launched a fighter brand called Funtime. This product had lower quality than its premium brand - Kodak manufactured Funtime with an older, less effective technology than Gold Plus - and was sold at the same price as Fuji’s offering. However, since most customers were unaware of the quality differences, they saw Funtime as a high-quality Kodak film at a lower price. This consumption behavior seriously damaged Kodak’s reputation for high quality, and Gold Plus sales were more damaged than Fuji’s. Two years later, in 1996, Kodak then withdrew Funtime from the market. The story shows that the success of a fighter brand also depends crucially on how the incumbent brands her products. The incumbent would label the premium product and the second, lower-quality product with a single brand name using umbrella branding. On the other hand, the incumbent may also sell her two products under different names. In the context of this paper, one would expect that if customers are uncertain about product characteristics, umbrella branding might play an informational role and increase the cannibalization of the premium brand.

Another key assumption of our model that might influence the results of this paper is the nature of competition between the firms. We assumed that market competition is in prices. Consequently, the qualities of the fighter brand and the entrant’s product are strategic complements in our model. Aoki (1988), however, shows in a vertical differentiation model with a sequential quality choice that qualities are strategic complements for the high-quality firm but strategic substitutes for the low-quality firm if the market is characterized by Cournot competition. In our model, this result suggests that under quantity competition, the incumbent has to increase the quality of her fighter brand to reduce the quality of the entrant’s product. This, however, makes the firewall strategy less attractive due to the cannibalization effect. In turn, one might expect that the sandwich strategy becomes more profitable for the incumbent.

And finally, we assumed that the incumbent has no launching costs when introducing a second product. Hence, it is always optimal to launch a fighter brand to thwart new entrants. In general, however, an incumbent has different responses available to face new competition, see Jost (2014). For example, the incumbent could lower the price for her premium product or decrease, respectively, increase her premium product quality. The analysis shows that these strategies might be optimal under different extensions of our basic model. Suppose, for example, that the incumbent has to bear some costs when launching a second product and, in addition, is uncertain about the entry. Investing in such a situation in a product launch imposes costs that might be worthless if the entrant does not enter. Instead of making such a risky long-term decision implying sunk costs, it might be more beneficial for the incumbent to wait until the entrant enters the market. She could then use a price defense to defend the premium product as a short-term tactical decision.