Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Monetary Policy, Market Structure and the Income Shares in the U.S

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A general equilibrium model of heterogeneous capital is employed to investigate whether, how and to what extent monetary policy and market structure may have contributed to the decline of the labor share in the U.S. in recent decades. By construction the model allows monetary policy to affect the labor share through two channels, i.e. one linking the policy rate to the real interest rate and another linking the latter to the useful life of producers’ goods, whereas regarding market structure, the more competitive the economy, the higher the labor share. From its solution using U.S. data over the period 2000–2014 it emerges that the persistent reduction in the policy rate on the one hand slowed down the decline in the labor share and on the other accelerated it, because the reduction in the policy rate was accompanied by a robust upward trend in the equilibrium real rate of interest, which increased the useful life of producers’ goods. In turn, to gauge the relative strength of these two opposite effects, the equation of the labor share is estimated by means of the autoregressive distributed lag method. The results show that the adverse effect of monetary policy through the useful life of producers’ goods was more than 12 times as strong as the favorable effect of the policy rate and on this ground I conclude that the monetary policy contributed to the decline of the labor share significantly, at least since 2000. As for the market structure, it is found that even if firms had and attempted to exercise monopoly power, it would be exceedingly difficult to exploit it because the demand of consumers’ goods is significantly price elastic.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For some recent empirical evidence validating this view in the post war period in the U.S., see Levy (1990).

  2. Capital deepening may not be unrelated to globalization and offshoring. According to Gordon (1961, 937) for half a century the prices of producers’ goods in the U.S and certain other advanced countries increased faster than those of consumers’ goods. However, Gordon (1990), Restuccia and Urrutia (2001) and others have found that in more recent decades the relative prices of such goods have declined rather dramatically. In the U.S this development is due to the steep decline in the relative prices of equipment and less so of software, whereas the prices of structures continue their upward trend. Hence, given that during the same period the ratio of exported to imported capital goods has declined rather precipitously, if new machines are invented and designed at home but constructed in low cost countries, their adverse price effect on labor at home may not be independent of the above mentioned manifestations of openness to trade.

  3. Stiglitz (1974) surveyed the central issues in the controversy and appraised the status of the debate up to the middle of the 1970s. Since then the proponents of the Cambridge (U.K) views have continued to battle by focusing mainly on the difficulties in the conceptualization and estimation of aggregate production functions. As argued below, even though their arguments are well-taken, they lack sufficient convincing power to win over a strong following from the camp of neoclassical economists and practitioners. That is why, judging from an impartial perspective, the influence of neoclassical economic theory as of this date is all but invisible.

  4. Kurz (2015) provides a concise summary of the great debate on this issue among Hayek, Keynes and Sraffa. All three agreed that the central bank influences decisively the distribution of income and wealth. Their differences concerned the channels through which these influences are exerted and how they affect the natural coordinative functions of market prices in pushing the economy towards equilibrium.

  5. By adopting this definition, the model laid out below maintains consistency over its analytical properties while escaping from the outstanding criticisms of aggregate capital and aggregate production function. On the other hand though, due to this choice, the model risks appearing simplistic and foreign to contemporary general equilibrium analyses. As the presentation progresses, it will become apparent that the model derives from the long tradition of models with heterogeneous capital, which, by having been erected on utility maximizing consumers and cost minimizing enterprises in competitive markets, it is most pertinent for the study of incomes shares.

  6. For the proof that the second-order conditions are satisfied, see Brems (1968, 148–149)

  7. It should be noted that since by (1) the variable S(t) is measured in labor units no monetary values are involved in (13a), and hence, there arise no issues of aggregation.

  8. In the present model absent from the determination of the useful life of capital are operating policies like the intensity of utilization and maintenance, and capital policies like abandonment and scrapping. For a detailed analysis of these policies and how they determine the useful life of producers’ goods, see Bitros and Flytzanis (2002, 2004).

  9. From this analysis follows that the focus in this paper is on those effects of monetary policy that are channeled to the economy through changes in the service lives of producers’ goods as well as the labor cost for constructing them. These are systematic and emerge in the long run, most likely over the span of many years. On the contrary, the effects of monetary policy on such highly liquid assets as, for example, cash balances and inventories of finished and intermediate goods impact the economy in the short run. This distinction is useful to have in mind because otherwise it is difficult to explain how a breakdown in monetary policy may pass unnoticed for many years.

  10. For empirical evidence to the effect that the incremental output-capital ratio may be unstable, see Gianaris (1969).

  11. Since structures are significantly longer lived fixed assets relative to equipment and software, such a shift would be expected to show as an increase in the ratio of investment in structures to total investment. However, according to the data given by BEA for real private non-residential investment, during the period under consideration this ratio declined from 31.5% in 2000 to 21.6% in 2014.

  12. Mishkin (1996) reviews the channels of monetary policy and emphasizes the importance of changes in the real interest rate for monetary policy to be effective.

  13. In this part the policy rate is approximated by the so-called “federal funds rate”. Later, in the empirical part, the search for the best performing monetary policy instrument extends to several alternative rates.

  14. The relationship between the nominal and the real interest rate is given by \( {i}_c={\widehat{i}}_c-0.0238 \). To avoid repeating the distinction between them, from now on all references will be made to the nominal interest rate.

  15. Depending on the data one looks at, one gets a different view of the level and variability of income shares. The differences in the reported series from various sources in the U.S are significant and arise primarily because of the difficulty to allocate “Proprietors’ income” among labor, profits and interest.

  16. To keep the paper within reasonable bounds, it was deemed appropriate to limit the empirical analysis solely to the labor share.

References

  • Acemoglu D, Robinson A (2015) The rise and fall of general laws of capitalism. J Econ Perspect 29:3–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Armenter R (2015) A bit of a miracle no more: The decline of the labor share. Business Review, Third Quarter, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, pp 1–9

  • Bitros GC (2008) Why the structure of capital and the useful lives of its components matter: a test based on a model of Austrian descent. Rev Austrian Econ 21:301–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bitros GC, Flytzanis E (2002) Towards a general theory of real capital. In: Bitros GC, Katsoulakos Y (eds) Essays in economic theory, growth and labor markets: a festschrift in honor of E. Drandakis. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 125–147

    Google Scholar 

  • Bitros GC, Flytzanis E (2004) Operating policies in a model with terminal scrapping. Eur J Oper Res 194:551–573

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard O, Giavazzi F (2003) Macroeconomic effects of regulation and deregulation in goods and labor markets. Q J Econ 118:879–907

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blitz RC (1958) Capital longevity and economic development. Am Econ Rev 48:313–329

    Google Scholar 

  • Böhm-Bawerk E (1889) Positive Theory of Capital, 2nd volume in the 3-volume work Capital and Interest, translated by G. D. Hunke and H. F. Sennholtz, South Holland, Ill.: Libertarian Press, 1959. (The three volumes were originally published in German in 1984, 1989, and 1909)

  • Brems H (1968) Quantitative economic theory: a synthetic approach. John Wiley & Sons Inc., New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Buiter WH (2007) Is Numérairology the future of monetary economics? Unbundling Numéraire and medium of exchange through a virtual currency and a shadow exchange rate. Open Econ Rev 18:127–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elsby MWL, Hobijn B, Sahin A (2013) The decline of the U.S. labor share. Brook Pap Econ Act (Fall):1–52

  • Feenstra RC, Inklaar R, Timmer M (2013) The next generation of the Penn World Table. National Bureau of Economic Research, working paper 19255, http://www.nber.org/papers/w19255

  • Felipe J, Fisher FM (2003) Aggregation in production functions: what applied economists should know. Metroeconomica 54:208–262

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher I (1930) The theory of interest. The Macmillan Co., New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher FM, Solow R, Kearl JM (1977) Aggregate production functions: some CES experiments. Rev Econ Stud 44:305–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gianaris NV (1969) The instability of incremental capital-output ratio. Socio Econ Plan Sci 3:119–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon RA (1961) Differential changes in the prices of consumers’ and capital goods. Am Econ Rev 51:937–957

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon RJ (1990) The measurement of durable goods prices. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Guscina A (2006) Effects of globalization on labor’s Share in National Income. International Monetary Fund, WP/ 06/294

  • Harrison AE (2005) Has globalization eroded labor’s share? Some cross-country evidence. Working Paper 39649, MPRA

  • Hayek FA (1939) Profits, interest and investment. Routledge & Kegan Paul, Ltd., London

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaldor N (1961) Accumulation and economic growth. In: Lutz FA, Hague DC (eds) The theory of capital. St. Martin’s Press, New York, pp 177–222

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Karabarbounis L, Neiman B (2014) The global decline of the labor share. Q J Econ 129:61–103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein LR, Kosobud RF (1961) Some econometrics of growth: great ratios in economics. Q J Econ 75:173–198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurz HD (2015) Capital theory, crises, and business cycles: the triangular debate between Hayek, Keynes, and Sraffa. J Rev Glob Econ 4:186–191

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy D (1990) Aggregate output, capital and labor in the post-war U. S. economy. Econ Lett 33:41–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindahl E (1939) Studies in the theory of money and capital. G. Allen & Unwin, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Mishkin F (1996) The channels of monetary transmission: lessons for monetary policy. National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper #5464

  • Piketty T (2014) Capital in the twenty-first century, Translation. By A. Goldhammer, The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge

  • Restuccia D, Urrutia C (2001) Relative prices and investment rates. J Monet Econ 47:93–121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solow RM (1958) A skeptical note on the constancy of relative shares. Am Econ Rev 48(4):618–631

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow RM (1977) Law of production and law of algebra: the humbug production function: a comment. Rev Econ Stat 56:121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz JE (1974) Review: the Cambridge-Cambridge controversy in the theory of capital; a view from new haven: a review article. J Polit Econ 82:893–903

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wheelock DC (2011) Have acquisitions of failed banks increased the concentration of U.S. banking markets? Fed Reserve Bank St Louis Rev 93:155–168

    Google Scholar 

  • Wicksell K (1898) Interest and prices. Translated from Swedish by R. F. Kahn in 1936. Reprint, New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1965

  • Wicksell K (1923) Realkapital och Kapitalranta. Ekonomisk Tidskrift, 25, 145–180. Translated as the second appendix to Lectures in Political Economy, 1, London, 1934

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to George C. Bitros.

Appendices

Appendix 1

1.1 Derivation of the money value of the depreciated capital stock

Observe from (5) in the text that the sum total R(υ, τ) of revenues minus operating expenses of a unit of producers’ goods from time τ to the rest of its useful life u is given by:

$$ R\left(\upsilon, \tau \right)={\int}_{\tau}^{\upsilon +u}\left[\frac{P\left(\upsilon \right)}{b\left(\upsilon \right)}{e}^{\mu \left(t-\upsilon \right)}-w\right]{e}^{-i\left(t-\upsilon \right)} dt. $$
(31)

Depreciation on the unit of producers’ goods of vintage υ from τ to time τ + 1 is defined as the decline in its worth during that year:

$$ D\left(\upsilon, \tau \right)=R\left(\upsilon, \tau \right)-R\left(\upsilon, \tau +1\right). $$
(32)

So, on the way to finding the expression for net income, let us derive the expression for R(υ, τ). With the help of (11) and (14), expression (8) simplifies into:

$$ \frac{P\left(\upsilon \right)}{b\left(\upsilon \right)}={we}^{-\mu u} $$
(33)

Substituting this into (31) and carrying out the integration gives the value of one unit of producers’ goods of vintage υ computed as of time τ:

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}R\left(\upsilon, \tau \right)=w\left[{e}^{-\mu u}{\int}_{\tau}^{\upsilon +u}{e}^{\mu \left(t-\tau \right)-i\left(t-\tau \right)} dt-{\int}_{\tau}^{\upsilon +u}{e}^{-i\left(t-\tau \right)} dt\right]=\\ {}\kern2.75em =w\frac{ie^{-\mu \left(\upsilon +u-\tau \right)}-\mu {e}^{-i\left(\upsilon +u-\tau \right)}-\left(i-\mu \right)}{i\left(i-\mu \right)}.\end{array}} $$
(34)

Expression (13a) gives the units of all producers’ goods employed at time t. Hence, its value should be:

$$ Z\left(K(t)\right)=Z(t)={\int}_{t-u}^tR\left(\upsilon, \tau \right)S\left(\upsilon \right) d\upsilon . $$
(35)

In turn, by drawing on (13b) to write:

$$ S\left(\upsilon \right)={e}^{g\left(\upsilon -\tau \right)}S\left(\tau \right), $$
(36)

expression (35) can be transformed into:

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}Z(t)={\int}_{t-u}^tR\left(\upsilon, \tau \right)S\left(\upsilon \right) d\upsilon =\\ {}\kern1.5em =\frac{\eta }{1+\eta}\frac{wS\left(\tau \right)}{i\left(i-\mu \right)}\left[{\int}_{t-u}^{\tau }{ie}^{-\mu \left(\upsilon +u-\tau \right)+g\left(\upsilon -\tau \right)}-\mu {e}^{-\mu \left(\upsilon +u-\tau \right)+g\left(\upsilon -\tau \right)}-\left(i-\mu \right){e}^{g\left(\upsilon -\tau \right)}\right] d\upsilon .\end{array}} $$
(37)

Upon evaluation of this integral and some re-arrangements of terms, we obtain the money value of the undepreciated capital stock as:

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}\kern14em Z(t)=\frac{\eta }{1+\eta}\frac{w}{i} QS(t)\\ {}\mathrm{where}\\ {}\kern8em Q=\frac{{i e}^{-\mu u}}{\left(g-\mu \right)\left(i-\mu \right)}+\frac{\mu {e}^{- iu}}{\left(i-g\right)\left(i-\mu \right)}-\frac{i\mu {e}^{- gu}}{g\left(g-\mu \right)\left(i-g\right)}-\frac{1}{g}.\end{array}} $$
(38)

Expression (38) gives the value of the undepreciated capital stock on which interest is due and paid to the owners of the corresponding money capital.

Appendix 2

1.1 Data used in the computations of the model and the statistical analysis

Table 3 Estimates of certain key variables and parameters of the model
Table 4 Series of computed and reported variables of interest
Table 5 Share of labor from various sources

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bitros, G.C. Monetary Policy, Market Structure and the Income Shares in the U.S. Open Econ Rev 29, 383–413 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-017-9451-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-017-9451-2

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation