Skip to main content
Log in

Distributed knowledge and the organization of economic activity

  • Manuscript
  • Published:
Computational and Mathematical Organization Theory Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper develops a simple simulation model to study the relation between the nature of knowledge and the architecture of economic systems. The market and the firm are different mechanisms for coordinating economic activity in a system where knowledge is widely dispersed. While the market solves coordination problems by decentralizing decision-making, the firm solves coordination problems by centralizing knowledge. The market incurs the cost of finding potential exchange partners and agreeing on terms of trade, while the firm incurs the cost of centralizing dispersed knowledge. The market therefore has an advantage over the firm in coordinating activities in which knowledge is difficult to centralize. The nature of knowledge involved in an economic activity influences not only the choice of the institution through which it is coordinated but also the internal structure of the institution. More specifically, the more hierarchical the firm, the better it is at using changing knowledge, but the worse it is at using knowledge which is difficult to transfer from one individual to another. Therefore, the number of layers in the hierarchy of the firm is influenced by the rate at which knowledge changes relative to the difficulty associated with communicating it.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. As Langlois (2013, p. 248) put it, though Hayek was writing in the context of the socialist calculation debate, Coase and Hayek “really are addressing the same problem: what are the limits of the market and of the firm”. In a similar vein, Foss and Klein (2014, p. 472) argue that “the Hayekian challenge to planning applies to firms as well as to centrally planned economies, and raises fundamental issues that are still not resolved in organisation theory relating to the use of authority, planning, and direction in the presence of dispersed knowledge”.

  2. Coase (1937) did not say much about the origin of cost of the firm. Coase (1988, p. 40, italics ours) recalling his seminal article says: “Of course, organizing a firm would be profitable only if the costs avoided were greater than the costs that would be incurred by the firm in coordinating the activities of the factors of production. I did not attempt to uncover the factors that would determine when this would be so”.

  3. In Hayek’s (1945, p. 522) words: “To know of and put to use a machine not fully employed, or somebody’s skill which could be better utilized, or to be aware of a surplus stock which can be drawn upon during an interruption of supplies, is socially quite as useful as the knowledge of better alternative techniques. And the shipper who earns his living from using otherwise empty or half-filled journeys of tramp-steamers, or the estate agent whose whole knowledge is almost exclusively one of temporary opportunities, or the arbitrageur who gains from local differences of commodity prices, are all performing eminently useful functions based on special knowledge of circumstances of the fleeting moment not known to others.”

  4. Polanyi (2009) describes a psychological experiment where participants were given an electric shock whenever they uttered associations of certain words. The participants learned to forestall shocks by avoiding utterances of certain associations. However, they were not able to articulate what they were doing. They had learned to avoid shocks, but the knowledge of how to do so was functional and relational. The knowledge did not exist detached from the context in which it was learned.

  5. Our formal model will show that the market too suffers from an increase in the tacitness and dynamism of knowledge, but less so than the firm. This is because the redundancy associated with the massively parallel process of interactions within the market allows it to considerably overcome the problems associated with using dynamic and tacit knowledge.

  6. Negative and positive values of the inputs are merely a means to set up a coordination problem, i.e. the problem of reallocation of inputs so as to maximize output. It makes no difference if the support of the distribution is shifted to strictly positive or strictly negative values with a concomitant change in the production function itself. An earlier version of the model worked with each worker possessing two goods. In that setting they began with an inoptimal combination of the two inputs. The model was simplified to a system with a single good because one good proved sufficient to depict a coordination problem.

  7. The market takes several time steps to converge to its asymptotic output. By 100 time steps this convergence is near-complete (from a numerical point of view).

  8. We divide by the hypothetical maximum potential output, which is the output when the total quantity of input among all workers sums to zero. This sum may be non-zero for particular simulations as it depends on random initial allocation among workers. Nonetheless, this issue does not matter for the comparison of the system as all outputs are normalized with the same denominator.

References

  • Alchian AA, Demsetz H (1972) Production, information costs, and economic organization. Am Econ Rev 62(5):777–795

    Google Scholar 

  • Aoki M (1986) Horizontal vs. vertical information structure of the firm. Am Econ Rev 76:971–983

    Google Scholar 

  • Axtell RL (2003) Economics as distributed computation, Chapter 3. In: Terano T, Deguchi H, Takadama K (eds) Meeting the challenge of social problems via agent-based simulation. Springer, Berlin, pp 3–23

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Barnard CI (1938) The functions of the executive. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhardwaj M, Monin J (2006) Tacit to explicit: an interplay shaping organization knowledge. J Knowl Manag 10(3):72–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton P, Farrell J (1990) Decentralization, duplication, and delay. J Polit Econ 98(4):803–826

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase RH (1937) The nature of the firm. Economica 4(16):386–405

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase RH (1988) The nature of the firm: influence. J Law Econ Organ. 4(1):33–47

    Google Scholar 

  • Conner KR, Prahalad CK (1996) A resource-based theory of the firm: knowledge versus opportunism. Organ Sci 7(5):477–501

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cyert RM, March JG (1963) A behavioral theory of the firm. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs

    Google Scholar 

  • Foss NJ, Klein PG (2014) Hayek and organization studies. In: Oxford handbook of sociology, social theory and organization studies: contemporary currents, pp 467–86

  • Ghoshal S (2005) Bad management theories are destroying good management practices. Acad Manag Learn Educ 4(1):75–91

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghoshal S, Moran P (1996) Bad for practice: a critique of the transaction cost theory. Acad Manag Rev 21(1):13–47

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grant RM (1996) Toward a knowledge based theory of the firm. Strateg Manag J 17(2):109–122

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haldin-Herrgard T (2000) Difficulties in diffusion of tacit knowledge in organizations. J Intellect Cap 1(4):357–365

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart O (1989) An economist’s perspective on the theory of the firm. Columbia Law Rev 89(7):1757–1774

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek FA (1945) The use of knowledge in society. Am Econ Rev 35(4):519–530

    Google Scholar 

  • Hill C (1990) Cooperation, opportunism, and the invisible hand: implications for transaction cost theory. Acad Manag Rev 15(3):500–513

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kogut B, Zander U (1992) Knowledge of the firm, combinative capabilities, and the replication of technology. Organ Sci 3(3):383–397

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langlois RN (1992) Transaction-cost economics in real time. Ind Corp Change 1(1):99–127

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langlois RN (2013) The Austrian theory of the firm: retrospect and prospect. Rev Austrian Econ 26(3):247–258

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Madhavan A (2000) Market microstructure: a survey. J Financ Mark 3(3):205–258

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nickerson JA, Zenger TR (2004) A knowledge-based theory of the firm. Organ Sci 15(6):617–632

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Penrose ET (1959) The theory of the growth of the firm. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Polanyi M (2009) The tacit dimension. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Radner R (1992) Hierarchy: the economics of managing. J Econ Lit 30(3):1382–1415

    Google Scholar 

  • Ryle G (1945) Knowing how and knowing that: the presidential address. Proc Aristot Soc 46:1–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sah RK, Stiglitz JE (1988) Committees, hierarchies and polyarchies. Econ J 98(391):451–470

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon HA (1965) Administrative behavior. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Stein JC (2002) Information production and capital allocation: decentralized versus hierarchical firms. J Financ 57(5):1891–1921

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsoukas H (1996) The firm as a distributed knowledge system: a constructionist approach. Strateg Manag J 17(S2):11–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock G (1997) The economic theory of bureaucracy. Prentice Hall/Harvester Wheatsheaf Hemel Hempstead, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Wallis JJ, North D (1986) Measuring the transaction sector in the American economy, 1870-1970. In: Long-term factors in American Economic Growth. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 95–162

  • Williamson OE (1971) The vertical integration of production: market failure considerations. Am Econ Rev 61(2):112–123

    Google Scholar 

  • Zack MH (1999) Managing codified knowledge. Sloan Manag Rev 40(4):45–58

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Vipin P. Veetil.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

A Comparing the ideas developed in this paper with those in the literature on knowledge and information based theories of economic organization

A Comparing the ideas developed in this paper with those in the literature on knowledge and information based theories of economic organization

Over the years, a wide variety of answers have been proposed to the question of why some activities are organized through markets and others through firms. Williamson (1971) and Alchian and Demsetz (1972), among others, argue that firms exist because markets fail in the presence of opportunistic behavior. This constituted significant progress over the earlier view that economic organization is determined by technology alone (Barnard 1938). Some scholars however found opportunistic behavior explanations to be unsatisfactory (Hart 1989). Coase (1988, p. 44) recalls that during his empirical work in the 1930s, he found himself more worried about opportunistic behavior than the businessmen who engaged in market contracts. This is not surprising. Markets have a variety of ways to solve problems associated with opportunistic behavior including reputation and social norms (Hill 1990; Ghoshal 2005). Furthermore, firms are not immune to moral harzard and adverse selection problems (Ghoshal and Moran 1996). As Coase (1988, p. 43) noted, opportunistic behavior does not necessarily make the market more costly than the firm and therefore may not explain the division of economic activities between the two institutions.

Knowledge-based theories and information-based theories of economic organization emerged in response to these critiques. The ideas proposed in this paper fall within this literature. One of the significant contributions of this paper is that we attempt to explain ‘the organization of the economy’ and ‘the internal structure of the firm’ using a unitary factor. Most knowledge and information based theories either explain the internal structure of the firm (Aoki 1986), or the division of economic activity between the firm and the market, but not both. Nickerson and Zenger (2004, p. 617) is one of the few papers which simultaneously studies the question of “boundary choice (i.e., internal versus external) and the choice among alternative internal approaches to organizing”. They however do not attempt to solve the problem from the point of view of coordinating dispersed knowledge. In what follows we compare the ideas developed in this paper to some of the most relevant papers on knowledge and information based theories of economic organization.

1.1 A.1 Knowledge-based theories

Some of the literature on knowledge-based theories of the economic organization grew out of Penrose (1959) and Cyert and March's (1963) work on economic organization. While the literature on firms as knowledge-entities is large, only a subset of the literature compares the costs of using the firm to the cost of using the market. In so far as we seek to understand the architecture of economic systems, comparing the costs of alternate arrangements of organizing economic activity is the crux of the matter. Among the theories which compare firms and markets, one set of theories compare firms and markets in producing knowledge (Langlois 1992; Kogut and Zander 1992; Langlois 2013), while another set compares the two mechanisms in coordinating knowledge (Grant 1996; Conner and Prahalad 1996). Naturally, the ideas developed in this paper belong to the second set of theories. This paper is unique among the second set in so far as it presents a formal model of the transmission of knowledge and its impact of economic organization.

Grant begins with Hayek’s claim that the basic economic problem is how to coordinate the plans of economic actors in a system where knowledge is widely distributed. Grant accepts the view that markets are efficient at using knowledge, but claims that this is not true for all kinds of knowledge. He argues that markets cannot integrate knowledge that is non-rival and tacit, and firms exist because markets fail to coordinate activities that involve the use of such knowledge. Conner and Prahalad argue that firms are better than markets at using knowledge because they allow individuals to use knowledge that they do not fully possess or fully understand. Grant and Conner and Prahalad differ from Hayek and Polanyi’s thesis that tacit knowledge is best used through distributed interactions rather than central control. In contrast to Grant and Conner and Prahalad, our setting closely aligns with Hayek and Polanyi’s thesis on the use of tacit knowledge.

It is worth noting some of the defining features of our argument which mark its boundaries and therefore distinguish it from other knowledge-based theories. First, the literature on knowledge-based theories of the firm uses the word ‘knowledge’ in many senses, including the ‘relations between individuals’. Following Hayek, we use the word knowledge to mean attributes possessed by individuals and not the relations between individuals. Second, knowledge has dimensions other than dynamism and tacitness. For instance, Tsoukas (1996) distinguishes between four kinds of knowledge: explicit knowledge held by individuals, explicit knowledge held by the firm, tacit knowledge held by individuals, and tacit knowledge held by the firm. We limit ourselves to two dimensions of knowledge held by individuals. Third, we do not study the ways in which tacit knowledge is codified and converted into more explicit knowledge, see Zack (1999), Haldin-Herrgard (2000), and Bhardwaj and Monin (2006) for such an analysis. We assume the nature of knowledge to be an exogenous variable that influences the nature of economic organization. The purpose of this assumption is to isolate and study the impact of knowledge on economic organization; it is not to deny the bi-directional relation between the nature of knowledge and economic organization. Fourth, we study the problems associated with centralizing knowledge from workers, we do not study the problems associated with passing instructions to workers. See Tullock (1997) and Simon (1965) for a discussion on costs and frictions associated with communication from managers to workers.

1.2 A.2 Information theoretic literature

The information theoretic literature studies firms and markets as alternate arrangements of processing information. Within this literature, our paper is closely related to Sah and Stiglitz (1988), Bolton and Farrell (1990), Radner (1992), and Stein (2002). Sah and Stiglitz (1988) study how centralized and decentralized systems aggregate errors in human decision making. Bolton and Farrell compare centralized and decentralized systems in solving coordination problems when information is private. They argue that decentralized systems produce lower-cost solutions but involve delay or duplication. Radner studies how the firm processes information to derive its optimal structure. Stein studies the dependence of internal structure of the firm on information. He argues that the performance of hierarchies improves with the ease of passing information, an insight largely consistent with our own.

While our study incorporates features of the afore noted studies, it differs from them in significant ways. Sah & Stiglitz model the market as a system in which one agent considers a project after it has been rejected by another agent. They do not allow for parallel decision-making in the market. Massively parallel interactions are however an essential feature the market (Axtell 2003). We model the market as a system in which agents make decisions in parallel without knowing what other agents do. Bolton & Farrell study the problem of entry in a decentralized system between two agents who do not know each other’s costs. They however do not allow the agents to communicate with each other. We believe the problem of communicating private knowledge plays an essential role in determining the architecture of an economic system. We allow agents in the market and the firm to communicate with each other. Radner studies how firms solve non-associative problems, which are problems whose parts can be solved independently of each other. We study how the market and the firm solve a coordination problem which by its very nature is associative. Furthermore, neither Radner nor Stein compare the market and the firm as alternative mechanisms for using different kinds of information. In short, we address a gap in the literature by studying parallel interactions between agents who communicate with each other in both the market and the firm.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Veetil, V.P. Distributed knowledge and the organization of economic activity. Comput Math Organ Theory 28, 95–111 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10588-021-09350-z

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10588-021-09350-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation