Skip to main content
Log in

The Austrian theory of the firm: Retrospect and prospect

  • Published:
The Review of Austrian Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Using as a focusing device the famous arguments of Coase (Economica 4(16), 386–405 1937) and Hayek (The American Economic Review 35(4): 519–530 1945), I sketch in bold strokes what an Austrian theory of the firm would look like. Such a theory would pay serious attention to issues of knowledge, uncertainty, change, and complementarity. I describe a literature in which much of this theory has already been constructed; make connections to closely related literatures in economics and management; and suggest directions for future development.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Elsewhere (Langlois 2006) I have branded this phenomenon repertoire uncertainty, a manifestation of what I long ago called parametric (as against structural) uncertainty (Langlois 1984).

  2. As Nicolai Foss (1996) points out, Harald Malmgren (1961) was a precursor of this revival, whose approach had in addition many “Austrian” aspects to it.

  3. In his recent categorization of classes of “formalizable” theories, Gibbons (2005) includes one (of four) based on the idea of coordination. His examples? Some work by Williamson and Benjamin Klein—but not the likes of Coase or Knight.

  4. And let us not forget Loasby (1976).

  5. For a more fully elaborated discussion of what such a theory would look like, see Langlois (2007).

  6. Another way to buffer uncertainty in the context of the firm is to hold reserve assets (Lachmann 1978, p. 90).

  7. In another assignment, I have sometimes asked students to write about the implications of thinking in terms of complementary assets (Teece 1986) versus thinking in terms of complementary activities (Richardson 1972).

  8. Even if Sautet (2000, p. 94) thinks that, in the end, her notion of entrepreneurship is really “Robbinsian” rather than Kirznerian. From my point of view, the problem is not that Penrose isn’t Austrian but that she isn’t Coasean. Penrose assumes the existence of the firm, and analyzes learning within the firm; but she never asks about firm boundaries, and never considers whether entrepreneurs might be better off taking advantage of resources outside the firm rather than surplus ones within. As Loasby (2002, p. 52) points out, all that is missing in Penrose is “a significant treatment of external organisation and of the continuous restructuring of industries which was emphasised by Allyn Young, and these omissions may be attributed to a deliberate focus on the individual firm, and in particular on the relationship between its internal organisation and the process of internal learning, which may be regarded as one of the two most significant novel elements in her work.”

  9. Garud, Kumaraswamy, and Langlois (2002) collects many of the important papers in this literature.

References

  • Alchian, A., & Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, information costs, and economic organization. American Economic Review, 62(5), 772–795.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chandler, A. D., Jr. (1977). The visible hand: The managerial revolution in American business. Cambridge: The Belknap Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chandler, A. D., Jr. (1990). Scale and scope: The dynamics of industrial capitalism. Cambridge: The Belknap Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4(16), 386–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dulbecco, P., & Garrouste, P. (1999). Towards an Austrian theory of the firm. The Review of Austrian Economics, 12(1), 43–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foss, N. J. (1994). The theory of the firm: The Austrians as precursors and critics of contemporary theory. The Review of Austrian Economics, 7(1), 31–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foss, N. J. (1996). Harold Malmgren’s analysis of the firm: Lessons for modern theorists? Review of Political Economy, 8(4), 349–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foss, K., & Foss, N. J. (2001). Assets, attributes and ownership. International Journal of the Economics of Business, 8(1), 19–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foss, K., Foss, N. J., Klein, P. G., & Klein, S. K. (2002). Heterogeneous capital, entrepreneurship, and economic organization. Journal des Economistes et des Etudes Humaines, 12(1), 79–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foss, K., Foss, N. J., Klein, P. G., & Klein, S. K. (2007). The entrepreneurial organization of heterogeneous capital. Journal of Management Studies 44(6) (November).

  • Garud, R., Kumaraswamy, A., & Langlois, R. N. (Eds.). (2002). Managing in the modular age: Architectures, networks, and organizations. Blackwell Publishing: Oxford.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibbons, R. (2005). Four formal(Izable) theories of the firm? Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 58(2), 200–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart, O. (1989). An economist’s perspective on the theory of the firm. Columbia Law Review, 89(7), 1757–1774.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart, O., & Moore, J. (1990). Property rights and the nature of the firm. The Journal of Political Economy, 98(6), 1119–1158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1945). The use of knowledge in society. The American Economic Review, 35(4), 519–530.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, E. (Ed.). (1998). General purpose technologies and economic growth. MIT Press: Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacobides, M. G., & Winter, S. G. (2005). The co-evolution of capabilities and transaction costs: Explaining the institutional structure of production. Strategic Management Journal, 26(5), 395–413.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1992). Specific and general knowledge, and organizational structure. In L. Werin & H. Wijkander (Eds.), Contract economics (pp. 251–274). Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. M. (1973). Competition and entrepreneurship. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein, B., Crawford, R. G., & Alchian, A. A. (1978). Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process. Journal of Law and Economics, 21(2), 297–326.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lachmann, L. M. (1978). Capital and its structure. Kansas City: Sheed Andrews and McMeel, Inc., by permission of the Institute for Humane Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Langlois, R. N. (1984). Internal organization in a dynamic context: Some theoretical considerations. In M. Jussawalla & H. Ebenfield (Eds.), Communication and information economics: New perspectives (pp. 23–49). Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Langlois, R. N. (1988). Economic change and the boundaries of the firm. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 144(4), 635–657.

    Google Scholar 

  • Langlois, R. N. (1992). Transaction cost economics in real time. Industrial and Corporate Change, 1(1), 99–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langlois, R. N. (1998). Personal capitalism as charismatic authority: The organizational economics of a Weberian concept. Industrial and Corporate Change, 7, 195–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langlois, R. N. (2002). Modularity in technology and organization. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 49(1), 19–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langlois, R. N. (2003). The vanishing hand: The changing dynamics of industrial capitalism. Industrial and Corporate Change, 12(2), 351–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langlois, R. N. (2006). The secret life of mundane transaction costs. Organization Studies, 27(9), 1389–1410.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langlois, R. N. (2007). The entrepreneurial theory of the firm and the theory of the entrepreneurial firm. Journal of Management Studies, 44(6) (November).

  • Langlois, R. N., & Foss, N. J. (1999). Capabilities and governance: The rebirth of production in the theory of economic organization. Kyklos, 52(2), 201–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langlois, R. N., & Robertson, P. L. (1992). Networks and innovation in a modular system: Lessons from the microcomputer and stereo component industries. Research Policy, 21(4), 297–313.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langlois, R. N., & Robertson, P. L. (1995). Firms, markets, and economic change: A dynamic theory of business institutions. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewin, P., & Baetjer, H. (2011). The capital-based view of the firm. Review of Austrian Economics, 24, 335–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewin, P., & Phelan, S. E. (2000). An Austrian theory of the firm. The Review of Austrian Economics, 13(1), 59–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lipsey, R. G., Carlaw, K. I., & Bekar, C. T. (2005). Economic transformations: General purpose technologies and long term economic growth. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loasby, B. J. (1976). Choice, complexity, and ignorance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loasby, B. J. (2002). The significance of Penrose’s theory for the development of economics. In C. Pitelis (Ed.), The growth of the firm: The legacy of Edith Penrose (pp. 45–59). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mahoney, J. T., & Rajendran Pandian, J. (1992). The resource-based view within the conversation of strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, 13(5), 363–380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malmgren, H. B. (1961). Information, expectations and the theory of the firm. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 75(3), 399–421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. G. (1982). An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Noteboom, B. (2003). Elements of a Cognitive Theory of the Firm. Working Paper, Tilburg University.

  • O’Driscoll, G. P., & Rizzo, M. J. (1985). The economics of time and ignorance. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pagano, U. (2000). Public markets, private orderings and corporate governance. International Review of Law and Economics, 20, 453–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Penrose, E. T. (1959). The theory of the growth of the firm. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Polanyi, M. (1958). Personal knowledge. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Richardson, G. B. (1972). The organisation of industry. The Economic Journal, 82(327), 883–896.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sautet, F. E. (2000). An entrepreneurial theory of the firm. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Silver, M. (1984). Enterprise and the scope of the firm. London: Martin Robertson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (1951). A formal theory of the employment relationship. Econometrica, 19(3), 293–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1951). The division of labor is limited by the extent of the market. The Journal of Political Economy, 59(3), 185–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tadelis, S. (2002). Complexity, flexibility, and the make-or-buy decision. The American Economic Review, 92(2), 433–437.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D. J. (1980). Economies of scope and the scope of the enterprise. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 1(3), 223–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D. J. (1986). Profiting from technological innovation: Implications for integration, collaboration, licensing, and public policy. Research Policy, 15(6), 285–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D. J., Pisano, G., & Shuen, A. (1997). Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, 18(7), 509–533.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tirole, J. (1988). The multicontract organization. The Canadian Journal of Economics, 21(3), 459–466.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wernerfelt, B. (1984). A resource-based view of the firm. Strategic Management Journal, 5(2), 171–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wernerfelt, B. (1995). The resource-based view of the firm: ten years after. Strategic Management Journal, 16(3), 171–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications. New York: The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Witt, U. (1998). Imagination and leadership: The neglected dimension of an evolutionary theory of the firm. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 35, 161–177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yu, T. F.-L. (1999). Toward a praxeological theory of the firm. The Review of Austrian Economics, 12(1), 25–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Richard N. Langlois.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Langlois, R.N. The Austrian theory of the firm: Retrospect and prospect. Rev Austrian Econ 26, 247–258 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-012-0171-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-012-0171-y

Keywords

Navigation