Skip to main content
Log in

Emission permits, innovation and sanction in an evolutionary game

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Economia Politica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper studies the evolutionary dynamics of a market regulated by an auctioned emission trading system with a price floor in which there exist three populations of firms that interact strategically: (i) non-polluting, (ii) polluting and compliant, (iii) polluting but non-compliant. Firms that adopt a non-polluting technology need no permits to operate, while firms that use a polluting technology can either buy the required permits (and be compliant) or not (being non-compliant). The latter do not buy emission permits and face the risk to be sanctioned if discovered. From the analysis of the model emerges that all three types of firms coexist at the equilibrium only under specific parameter values. More precisely, it can generically be excluded the coexistence between non-polluting firms and non-compliant polluting ones. The regulatory authority can favor the extinction of non-compliant firms by increasing their probability of being discovered and/or the sanction level. Moreover, the regulatory authority can favor the diffusion of innovation by increasing the permits price floor since polluting-compliant firms exit the market and new non-polluting firms enter the market. However, this policy instrument should be used with caution because it tends to increase also the number of non-compliant firms.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Free allowances can be allocated to an installation either ex-ante, that is before emissions are produced, based on historical emissions or output (what is generally known as “grandfathering”), or ex-post proportionally to the emissions generated or to the corresponding output (often called “output-based allocation”).

  2. For instance, the European Union Emission Trading System aims at reducing GHG emissions of the covered sectors by 43% in 2030 compared to their emission levels in 2005, when the system was introduced (Borghesi et al. 2016).

  3. More precisely, Milliman and Prince (1989) and Jung et al. (1996) show that an auctioned ETS is a preferable policy instrument respect to, in descending welfare order, emission taxes and subsides, grandfathered permits, emissions standards. The debate on which is the best environmental policy instrument to spread innovation is beyond of the scope of the paper. See Requate 2005 for a theoretically literature review on the effects of environmental policy instruments on innovation.

  4. It can be argued that using permits received for free implies an opportunity cost, therefore in principle the allocation method should not influence the firms’ operational decision. However, the allocation method modifies firms’ behavior in practice since receiving permits for free or not changes the relative convenience of alternative investments ex-ante (Marcantonini et al. 2017).

  5. Parameter d captures how “dirty” is the polluting technology adopted by P-firms: for any given level of \(q_{P}\), the dirtier is the technology being adopted, the higher the demand of permits and thus also their price, ceteris paribus. It can obviously be influenced by many factors, including the kind and number of alternative clean technologies at disposal, as well as the supply-side policies of the Public Administration. As will be shown (cf. equation 8 below), an increase in d lowers the amount \(q_{P}\) just like an increase in the price floor. Differently from the price floor, however, parameter d is not directly influenced by the regulator.

  6. Based on system (6), the planes are invariant, namely \({\dot{s}}=0\) and \({\dot{m}}=0\) hold if \(s=0\) and \(m=0\), respectively.

  7. That is, conditions (15), (16) can only admit interior solutions with \(q_{NP}>0\) and \(q_{PP}>0\).

References

  • Arguedas, C., Camacho, E., & Zofío, J. L. (2010). Environmental policy instruments: Technology adoption incentives with imperfect compliance. Environmental and Resource Economics, 47, 261–274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borghesi, S. (2014). Water tradable permits: A review of theoretical and case studies. Journal of Environmental Planning and Management, 57(9), 1305–1332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borghesi, S., Montini, M., & Barreca, A. (2016). The European Emission Trading System and Its Followers. Springer Briefs in Environmental Science. Cham: Springer International Publishing.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. The Journal of Law and Economics, 3(1), 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crocker, T. D. (1966). The structuring of atmospheric pollution control systems. In H. Wolozing (Ed.), The Economics of Air Pollution (pp. 61–86). New York: W.W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dales, J. (1968). Pollution, Property, and Prices. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downing, P. B., & White, L. J. (1986). Innovation in pollution control. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 13, 18–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellerman, A. D., Convery, F. J., & De Perthuis, C. (2010). Pricing carbon: The European Union emissions trading scheme. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischer, C., Parry, I. W., & Pizer, W. A. (2003). Instrument choice for environmental protection when technological innovation is endogenous. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 45, 523–545.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hofbauer, J., & Sigmund, K. (1988). The Theory of Evolution and Dynamical Systems. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jung, C., Krutilla, K., & Boyd, R. (1996). Incentives for advanced pollution abatement technology at the industry level: An evaluation of policy alternatives. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 30, 95–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keeler, A. G. (1991). Noncompliant firms in transferable discharge permit markets: Some extensions. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 21, 180–189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malik, A. S. (1990). Markets for pollution control when firms are noncompliant. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 18, 97–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malueg, D. (1989). Emission credit trading and the incentive to adopt new pollution abatement technology. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 18, 52–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marcantonini, C., Teixido-Figueras, J., Verde, S. F., & Labandeira, X. (2017). Low-carbon innovation and investment in the EU ETS. Policy Brief 2017/22, RSCAS, European University Institute. Forence, Italy.

  • Milliman, S. R., & Prince, R. (1989). Firm incentives to promote technological change in pollution control. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 17, 247–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Montgomery, W. D. (1972). Markets in licenses and efficient pollution control programs. Journal of Economic Theory, 5(3), 395–418.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Requate, T. (2005). Dynamic incentives by environmental policy instruments—a survey. Ecological Economics, 54, 175–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stranlund, J. K. (2017). The economics of enforcing emissions markets. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 11(2)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Villegas-Palacio, C., & Coria, J. (2010). On the interaction between imperfect compliance and technology adoption: Taxes versus tradable emissions permits. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 38, 274–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weibull, J. W. (1995). Evolutionary Game Theory. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Simone Borghesi.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Mathematical appendix

Mathematical appendix

1.1 First order conditions

By imposing non negativity constraints \(q_{P}\geqslant 0\), \(q_{PP}\geqslant 0\), \(q_{NP}\geqslant 0\), and applying Khun-Tucker conditions, we obtain that given the values of the variables mns the quantities \( q_{NP},q_{P},q_{PP}\) are chosen according to the first order conditions:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi _{P}}{\partial q_{P}}= \,& {} p-C_{P}^{V}\cdot q_{P}-p_{T}\leqslant 0 \text {, }\frac{\partial \pi _{P}}{\partial q_{P}}\cdot q_{P}=0 \end{aligned}$$
(14)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi _{PP}}{\partial q_{PP}}=\, & {} p-C_{P}^{V}\cdot q_{PP}\leqslant 0 \text {, }\frac{\partial \pi _{PP}}{\partial q_{PP}}\cdot q_{PP}=0 \end{aligned}$$
(15)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi _{NP}}{\partial q_{NP}}=\, & {} p-C_{NP}^{V}\cdot q_{NP}\leqslant 0 \text {, }\frac{\partial \pi _{NP}}{\partial q_{NP}}\cdot q_{NP}=0 \end{aligned}$$
(16)

Remark 1

From (14) and (15) it follows that \(q_{P}\leqslant q_{PP}\) always holds.

Remark 2

Consider the case in which there exist values of \(q_{NP}>0\) and \(q_{PP}>0\) that satisfy conditions (15), (16) and, therefore, equations:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi _{PP}}{\partial q_{PP}}=\, & {} p-C_{P}^{V}\cdot q_{PP}=0 \\ \frac{\partial \pi _{NP}}{\partial q_{NP}}=\, & {} p-C_{NP}^{V}\cdot q_{NP}=0 \end{aligned}$$

From such equations, it follows:

$$\begin{aligned} p-C_{P}^{V}\cdot q_{PP}=p-C_{NP}^{V}\cdot q_{NP} \end{aligned}$$

and then:

$$\begin{aligned} q_{NP}=\frac{C_{P}^{V}}{C_{NP}^{V}}\cdot q_{PP} \end{aligned}$$
(17)

From Eq. (17) it results that if \(q_{PP}\) becomes equal to zero, then also \(q_{NP}\) becomes equal to zero, and vice-versa; moreover, from Remark 1, it occurs also to \(q_{P}\). Consequently, taking into account that \(p=Q-a\cdot \left( m\cdot q_{NP}+n\cdot q_{P}+s\cdot q_{PP}\right) >0\) when the quantities \(q_{NP}\), \(q_{P}\), \(q_{PP}\) are sufficiently low, it occurs that PP-firms and NP-firms never choose \(q_{PP}=0\) and \(q_{NP}=0\), respectively.Footnote 7 This implies that NP-firms and PP-firms always produce strictly positive quantities, regardless of the values of variables m, n, s.

1.2 Proof of Proposition 1

Taking into account Remark 2 and Eq. (17), in order to determine the values \(q_{NP}\), \(q_{P}\), \(q_{PP}\), it is sufficient to analyze only conditions (14), (15). Differently from (15), (16), condition (14) can be satisfied also for \(q_{P}=0\). Therefore, P-firms, which buy emission permits, could choose to produce a zero output, given m, n, s; such an event can occur only if \(\overline{p_{T}}>0\), and, therefore, \(p_{T}>0\) also for \(q_{P}=0\).

Consider first the case in which (14) is satisfied for \(q_{P}>0\). In such a context, conditions (14), (15) become:

$$\begin{aligned} p-C_{P}^{V}\cdot q_{P}-p_{T}= & {} 0 \end{aligned}$$
(18)
$$\begin{aligned} p-C_{P}^{V}\cdot q_{PP}= & {} 0 \end{aligned}$$
(19)

From (18), (19) it derives:

$$\begin{aligned} p-C_{P}^{V}\cdot q_{P}-p_{T}=p-C_{P}^{V}\cdot q_{PP} \end{aligned}$$

from which:

$$\begin{aligned} C_{P}^{V}\cdot q_{P}+p_{T}=C_{P}^{V}\cdot q_{PP} \end{aligned}$$
(20)

Substituting (5) in (20), it becomes:

$$\begin{aligned} C_{P}^{V}\cdot q_{P}+\overline{p_{T}}+d\cdot q_{P}\cdot n=C_{P}^{V}\cdot q_{PP} \end{aligned}$$

from which we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} q_{PP}=\frac{\overline{p_{T}}}{C_{P}^{V}}+\left( 1+\frac{d}{C_{P}^{V}}\cdot n\right) \cdot q_{P} \end{aligned}$$
(21)

Finally, substituting (4) and (21) in (18), and taking account of (17), we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned}&Q-a\cdot \frac{\overline{p_{T}}}{C_{P}^{V}}\cdot \left( \frac{C_{P}^{V}}{ C_{NP}^{V}}\cdot m+s\right) -\overline{p_{T}}\nonumber \\=\, & {} q_{P}\cdot \left[ C_{P}^{V}+(a+d)\cdot n+a\cdot \left( \frac{C_{P}^{V}}{C_{NP}^{V}}\cdot m+s\right) \right. \nonumber \\&\left. \cdot \left( 1+\frac{d}{C_{P}^{V}}\cdot n\right) \right] \end{aligned}$$
(22)

Equation (22) determines the equilibrium value of \(q_{P}\). Once determined \(q_{P}^{*}\), the equilibrium values of \(q_{PP}\) and \(q_{NP}\) are respectively determined by Eqs. (21) and (17). This completes the proof of Proposition 1.

1.3 The separatrix between the regimes with \(q_{P}>0\) and with \(q_{P}=0\)

Setting \(q_{P}=0\), Eq. (22) becomes:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{C_{P}^{V}}{C_{NP}^{V}}\cdot m+s=\frac{C_{P}^{V}}{a\cdot \overline{p_{T} }}\cdot \left( Q-\overline{p_{T}}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(23)

Equation (23) represents the plane (in the space (mns)) that separates the region in which \(q_{P}>0\) (below the plane) from that in which \(q_{P}=0\) (above the plane). If the values of m and/or s are sufficiently high to satisfy conditions \(\left( C_{P}^{V}/C_{NP}^{V}\right) \cdot m+s\geqslant \left( C_{P}^{V}/a\cdot \overline{ p_{T}}\right) \cdot \left( Q-\overline{p_{T}}\right) \), then the polluting-compliant firms choose \(q_{P}=0\).

1.4 Proof of Proposition 2

To prove Proposition 2, notice that when \(q_{P}=0\), the equilibrium values of \(q_{PP}\) and \(q_{NP}\) are determined by (19), taking into account Eq. (17), and that the demand function can be rewritten as \(p=Q-a\cdot \left( \frac{C_{P}^{V}}{C_{NP}^{V}}\cdot m+s\right) \cdot q_{PP}\).

1.5 Proof of Proposition 3

Below the plane represented by Eq. (23), that is in the region where \(q_{P}>0\), we have \(\dot{s}=0\) and \(\dot{m}=0\) if the following equations are respectively satisfied:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{PP}= & {} -C_{P}^{F}-T+p\cdot q_{PP}-\frac{C_{P}^{V}}{2}\cdot q_{PP}^{2}=0 \end{aligned}$$
(24)
$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{NP}= & {} -C_{NP}^{F}+p\cdot q_{NP}-\frac{C_{NP}^{V}}{2}\cdot q_{NP}^{2}=0 \end{aligned}$$
(25)

Using condition (17), Eq. (25) can be rewritten as:

$$\begin{aligned} -C_{NP}^{F}+p\cdot \frac{C_{P}^{V}}{C_{NP}^{V}}\cdot q_{PP}-\frac{C_{NP}^{V} }{2}\cdot \left( \frac{C_{P}^{V}}{C_{NP}^{V}}\right) ^{2}\cdot q_{PP}^{2}=0 \end{aligned}$$

Multiplying both sides for \(C_{NP}^{V}/C_{P}^{V}\), we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{C_{NP}^{V}}{C_{P}^{V}}\cdot \left[ -C_{NP}^{F}+p\cdot \frac{C_{P}^{V}}{ C_{NP}^{V}}\cdot q_{PP}-\frac{C_{NP}^{V}}{2}\cdot \left( \frac{C_{P}^{V}}{ C_{NP}^{V}}\right) ^{2}\cdot q_{PP}^{2}\right] =0 \end{aligned}$$

from which:

$$\begin{aligned} -C_{NP}^{F}\cdot \frac{C_{NP}^{V}}{C_{P}^{V}}+p\cdot q_{PP}-\frac{C_{P}^{V}}{ 2}\cdot q_{PP}^{2}=0 \end{aligned}$$
(26)

Notice that in Eqs. (25), (26), the coefficients of \( q_{PP}^{2} \) and \(q_{PP}\) coincide, therefore a value of \(q_{PP}\) such that \( \overset{\cdot }{s}=\overset{\cdot }{m}=0\) can exist only in the case in which the following equality

$$\begin{aligned} T=C_{NP}^{F}\cdot \frac{C_{NP}^{V}}{C_{P}^{V}}-C_{P}^{F} \end{aligned}$$

holds. This proves Proposition 3.

1.6 Stability and phase planes

Figure 8 shows three numerical examples where only one stationary state is attractive, \(P_{2}\) in Fig. 8a, \(P_{4} \) in Fig. 8b, and \(P_{6}\) in Fig. 8c. In the figures, an empty dot “\(\circ \)” indicates a non attractive stationary state (that is, with at least one eigenvalue with positive real part), while a full dot “\(\bullet \)” denotes a locally attractive stationary state (that is, with 3 eigenvalues with negative real part).

The phase space corresponding to the numerical example in which \(P_{6}\) (where PP-firms are not present) is attractive is shown in Fig. 9. Differently, Fig. 10 illustrates a non generic case (the equality condition (13) is satisfied) in which all three types of firms coexist and there exists a segment (the black line that links \(P_{4}\) to \(P_{6}\)) constituted by (Lyapunov) stable stationary states. Conversely, the red line that links \(P_{2}\) to \(P_{5}\) is constituted by unstable stationary states located in the invariant plane \(n=0\) where there are not P-firms.

Fig. 8
figure 8

Numerical examples in which stationary states of type \(P_{2}\) (Fig. 8a), \(P_{4}\) (Fig. 8b) and \(P_{6}\) (Fig. 8c) are attractive

Fig. 9
figure 9

Phase space in which there is coexistence between NP-firms and PP-firms (\(P_{6}\) is attractive)

Fig. 10
figure 10

Phase space in which all three types of firms coexist

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Antoci, A., Borghesi, S., Iannucci, G. et al. Emission permits, innovation and sanction in an evolutionary game. Econ Polit 37, 525–546 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40888-020-00179-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40888-020-00179-4

Keywords

JEL Classification:

Navigation