Skip to main content
Log in

The spinning jenny and the guillotine: technology diffusion at the time of revolutions

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Cliometrica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Scale economies and demand, combined with the relative prices of input factors, can provide an economic explanation to the location and timing of the Industrial Revolution. Its labor-saving innovations were profitable only above a minimum output threshold, which allowed to cover the upfront cost of capital. In turn, the possibility to exceed such threshold depended on consumer demand, which was affected by the level and by the distribution of real income. The case of the spinning jenny and the cotton industry in England and France serves as a valuable case study to show how scale and demand considerations might have mattered even at the eve of the Industrial Revolution, thus implying also a potentially important role for income distribution.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Allen (2009b, p. 908).

  2. See Baines (1835, pp. 109–112, 522–525).

  3. Notice that, given that food is included in the subsistence basket, this structure of consumer utility is consistent with Engel’s law. Some recent works have resorted precisely to Engel’s Law in the attempt to make sense of transition out of the Malthusian regime (see Strulik and Weisdorf 2008; Voigtländer and Voth 2013).

  4. The respectable subsistence basket of Table 1 corresponds to the one defined by Allen (2001) but for the addition of rent, which is here included since this datum is reliably available for each of the two countries taken into consideration. It is important to notice that the subsistence basket defined in Table 1 accounts for basic clothing necessities by including the consumption of linen, while the need for a finer textile like cotton is plausibly excluded from subsistence.

  5. The fact that average real income per capita was higher in England than in France has been discussed at greater depth by Allen (2009a, pp. 25–26).

  6. Notice that the difference between England and France in terms of income distribution is even more striking when the “inequality extraction ratio” (IER) is considered rather than the sole Gini coefficient, as discussed by Milanovic et al. (2011). The IER is computed by subtracting the cost of the subsistence basket from each income class to then compute the Gini coefficient on the remaining income levels. The computations made by Milanovic et al. (2011, pp. 263–264, Table 2) show that the IER amounted to 55.4 % in England and 76.1 % in France, respectively, in 1759 and 1788.

  7. The fact that the share of people living above subsistence was at least twice as large in England relative to France is robust to the definition of the respectable subsistence basket and to the definition of the average household size proposed by Allen (2001). As discussed by Humpries (2012), both aspects are problematic since setting the daily adult consumption of calories to 1,941 and the average household size to four members might underestimate the actual cost of respectability. In the present case, however, the ratio between the share of people living above subsistence in England relative to France, R, remains above two for wide variations of the total cost of respectability. For instance, increasing by 50 % the cost of respectability both in England and France still determines a ratio R > 2. Moreover, the definition of the respectable subsistence basket adopted here already entails an higher cost relative to the one proposed by Allen (2001), as rent is included in the present definition.

  8. Notice that the consumption model sketched here might well imply that the demand for "extreme luxury” goods was higher in France than in England, despite the fact that the former country had a lower average real income relative to the latter. In fact, the share of people who earned, for instance, four times the income necessary to attain subsistence was higher in France 1788 than it was in England 1759. Therefore, the very upper class in France was richer than its English counterpart, which might have led to a higher consumption of "extreme luxury” goods in France.

  9. Notice that the focus of the present analysis on demand per spinner rather on the total market size represents a relevant difference with respect to the approach taken, for instance, by Daudin (2010).

  10. See Gragnolati et al. (2011) and Allen (2011b) for further details on these two scenarios.

  11. Notice that assuming s = 1 % produces an estimate of the typical Q for England that is quite close to the one proposed by Allen (2009a, b), that is, 100lbs. As discussed by Bythell (1964), it is difficult to quantify the share of labor in the textile industry that was devoted to the processing of cotton throughout the eighteenth century. Precisely for this reason the present work has adopted a methodology that allows to largely prescind from that information. In any case, just to have a rough idea of the weight of cotton in terms of employment, also Bythell (1964, p. 344) reports multiple sources estimating the number of weavers in England to be between 200,000 and 250,000 before 1833 that corresponded approximately to 1 % of the population. Clearly, this percentage would grow if also spinners were included, but on the other hand, the cotton industry was already much bigger by 1833 than it was by the mid-eighteenth century.

  12. To the contrary, Mokyr (1977, p. 995) claimed that "it is not an easy task to substantiate the case for increasing returns in manufacturing anywhere before, say, 1870”.

  13. According to Allen (2009a, p. 193), by 1790 there were 900 jennies in France and 20,070 in England.

  14. For instance, Chaptal (1819, p. 5) describes the technological state of the French cotton industry by 1819 as follows: “L’état actuel de nos filatures par les mécaniques dites mull-jennys et continues, nous permet de fournir par an à la fabrication des tissus ou de la bonneterie plus de 25 millions de livres de fil de coton, indépendamment de ce qui se file encore au rouet ou à la main dans les montagnes: la filature est aussi parfaite qu’on peut le désirer; et si jusqu’ici on a paru négliger de filer les numros les plus fins, c’est qu’on a préféré ceux dont le débit et la consommation étoient plus assurés et plus étendus”.

  15. For an overview of the literature on the transition toward factory productions see Mokyr (2001).

  16. In order to simplify the exposition, Fig. 5 was obtained under the assumption that all spinners used either the spinning wheel or the jenny, but not the two technologies contemporaneously.

  17. Incidentally, this fact shows that the concerns raised by Allen (2011b) about leisure/work decisions and labor availability are not stringent in the case of the jenny. It is indeed for this reason that the labor Eqs. (3) and (4) were used without imposing any constraint on L.

  18. The quantification of a full working year in 250 days comes from Allen (2009b, p. 916).

  19. In this respect, it is worth noting that it was technically possible to build small cottage water frames that could be used as a domestic spinning machine rather than inside factories; yet, the Arkwright partnership decided to build only bigger frames in order to prevent losing control of the patent, since "everyone would have copied it and built their own machines in the privacy of their own homes” (Hills 1979, p. 123).

  20. The reference is to Mokyr (1977, p. 1005): “[T]he traditional notion that supply and demand were somehow symmetric in the industrialization process is unfounded. The determination of ‘when’, ‘where’, and ‘how fast’ are to be sought first and foremost in supply, not demand related processes”.

References

  • Allen R (2001) The great divergence in European wages and prices from the middle ages to the First World War. Explor Econ Hist 38(4):411–447

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allen R (2009a) The British industrial revolution in global perspective. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen R (2009b) The industrial revolution in miniature: the spinning jenny in Britain, France, and India. J Econ Hist 69(4):901–927

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allen R (2011a) Data: wage and price history. London and Paris. http://www.nuffield.ox.ac.uk/General/Members/allen.aspx (Last consulted in June 2011)

  • Allen R (2011b) The spinning jenny: a fresh look. J Econ Hist 71(2):461–464

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allen R (2011c) Why the industrial revolution was British: commerce, induced innovation, and the scientific revolution. Econ Hist Rev 64(2):1–28

    Google Scholar 

  • Ashton T (1955) An economic history of england: the eighteenth century. Methuen, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Aspin C, Chapman S (1964) James Hargreaves and the spinning jenny. Helmshore Local History Society, Preston

    Google Scholar 

  • Baines E (1835) History of the cotton manufacture in Great Britain. Fisher H, Fisher, R, Jackson P, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Berg M (2004) In pursuit of luxury: global history and British consumer goods in the eighteenth century. Past & present 182(1):85–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broadberry S, Gupta B (2009) Lancashire, India, and shifting competitive advantage in cotton textiles, 1700–1850: the neglected role of factor prices. Econ Hist Rev 62(2):279–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bythell D (1964) The hand-loom weavers in the english cotton industry during the industrial revolution: some problems. Econ Hist Rev 17(2):339–353

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaptal J (1819) De l’Industrie Française, vol II. Antoine-Augustin Renouard, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Crafts N (2010) Explaining the first industrial revolution: two views. Eur Rev Econ Hist 15:153–168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crouzet F (1966) Angleterre et France au XVIIIe Siècle: Essai d’Analyse Comparée de Deux Croissances Économiques. Ann Hist Sci Soc 21e(Année(2):254–291

    Google Scholar 

  • Daudin G (2010) Domestic trade and market size in late-eighteenth-century France. J Econ Hist 70(3):716–743

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Vries J (1994) The industrial revolution and the industrious revolution. J Econ Hist 54(2):249–270

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • English W (1973) A technical assessment of Lewis Paul’s spinning machine. Text Hist 4(1):68–83

    Google Scholar 

  • Gentleman’s Magazine (1738) vol 8. E. Cave at St. John’s Gate, London

  • Global Price and Income History Group (2011) Early income distributions. http://gpih.ucdavis.edu/Distribution.htm (Last consulted in June 2011)

  • Gragnolati U, Moschella D, Pugliese E (2011) The spinning jenny and the industrial revolution: a reappraisal. J Econ Hist 71(2):458–463

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hills R (1979) Hargreaves, Arkwright and Crompton. Why three inventors? Text Hist 10(1):114–126

    Google Scholar 

  • Hobsbawm E (1952) The machine breakers. Past Present 1:57–70

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horn J (2005) Machine-breaking in England and France during the age of revolution. Labour-Le Travail 55:143–166

    Google Scholar 

  • Humpries J (2012) The Lure of aggregates and the pitfalls of the patriarchal perspective: a critique of the high wage economy interpretation of the British industrial revolution. Econ Hist Rev (forthcoming)

  • Lindert P, Williamson J (1982) Revising England’s social tables, 1688–1812. Explor Econ Hist 19(4):385–408

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maddison A (2010) Statistics on world population, GDP, and Per Capita GDP, 1–2008 AD. http://www.ggdc.net/Maddison/content.shtml (Last updated in March 2010)

  • Milanovic B, Lindert P, Williamson J (2011) Pre-industrial inequality. Econ J 121(551):255–272

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell B (1988) British historical statistics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell B, Deane P (1971) Abstract of British historical statistics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr J (1977) Demand vs. supply in the industrial revolution. J Econ Hist 37(4):981–1008

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr J (1990) The lever of riches: technological creativity and economic progress. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr J (2001) The rise and fall of the factory system: chnology, firms, and households since the industrial revolution. In: Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol 55. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1–45

  • Mokyr J (2009) The enlightened economy: an economic history of Britain, 1700–1850. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Morrisson C, Snyder W (2000) The income inequality of France in historical perspective. Eur Rev Econ Hist 4(1):59–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mulhall M (1892) The dictionary of statistics—part 1. A–P. Routledge and sons, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy K, Shleifer A, Vishny R (1989) Income distribution, market size, and industrialization. Q J Econ 104(3):537–564

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nuvolari A (2002) The ‘Machine Breakers’ and the industrial revolution. J Eur Econ Hist 31(2):393–426

    Google Scholar 

  • Sharp P, Weisdorf J (2012) French revolution or industrial revolution? A note on the contrasting experiences of England and France up to 1800. Cliometrica 6(1):79–88

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strulik H, Weisdorf J (2008) Population, food, and knowledge: a simple unified growth theory. J Econ Growth 13(3):195–216

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Voigtländer N, Voth H (2013) The three horsemen of riches: Plague, war and urbanization in early modern europe. Rev Econ Stud (forthcoming)

  • Wadsworth A, Mann J (1931) The cotton trade and industrial lancashire, 1600–1780. Manchester University Press, Manchester

    Google Scholar 

  • Young A (1770) A 6 months tour through the North of England, vol IV, 2nd edn. Strahan and Nicoll, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Young A (1794) Travels during the years 1787, 1788, and 1789, vol I, 2nd edn. Richardson, London

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors are grateful to Alessandro Nuvolari for his suggestions and support.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding authors

Correspondence to Ugo M. Gragnolati, Daniele Moschella or Emanuele Pugliese.

Additional information

All authors share equal responsibilities for the present work.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Gragnolati, U.M., Moschella, D. & Pugliese, E. The spinning jenny and the guillotine: technology diffusion at the time of revolutions. Cliometrica 8, 5–26 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-012-0092-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-012-0092-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation