Skip to main content
Log in

Mean reversion adjusted betas used in business valuation practice: a research note

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A major concern in business valuation is how to derive a beta value that adequately represents the assessment of long-term risk for a company. Against this background Morningstar (Ibbotson SBBI valuation yearbook 2012: market results for stocks, bonds, bills, and inflation 1926–2011. Ibbotson Associates, 2013), Bloomberg and Thomson Reuters recommend adjusting betas estimated for company valuation purposes (using \(\beta _{i}^{adj.}=.371+.635\beta _{i}^{raw}\) commonly named as the “\(\frac{1}{3}+\frac{2}{3}\)-adjustment”) to take into account research findings from Blume (J Finance 26(1):1–10, 1971) demonstrating that betas revert towards the mean value of one over time. Using theoretical analysis as well as a simulated data set reflecting real market patterns, we analyse the eligibility of this beta adjustment formula for company valuation practice. We show that derived adjustment formula coefficients are influenced by the variation of market returns, the length of the analysis period chosen, the measurement error for beta, as well as the distribution of true betas, quantifying the impact of all four elements, and confirm the regression to the mean fallacy interpretation as discussed by Friedman (J Econ Lit 30(4):2129–2132, 1992), Quah (Scand J Econ 95(4):427–443, 1993), Stigler (Stat Sci 11(3):244–252, 1996, Stat Methods Med Res 6(2):103–114, 1997), and Barnett et al. (Int J Epidemiol 34(1):215–220, 2004). We further demonstrate the biasing effect on company values when using the \(\frac{1}{3}+\frac{2}{3}\)-adjustment which is particularly intensified for small betas measured. Based on our analysis we conclude that the recommended \(\frac{1}{3}+\frac{2}{3}\)-adjustment as a justification for converging risk profiles lacks fundamental substance and, accordingly, its potential use in business valuation should be subject to critical consideration.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. According to Fama (1977) a constant equity cost of capital over multiple time periods is in line with the academic framework of the CAPM and is, therefore, an appealing practical approach due to its simplicity. For a literature review on the CAPM and asset pricing see Ross (1978), Dimson and Mussavian (1999), Subrahmanyam (2010) and Goyal (2012). When using the expression “Capital Asset Pricing Model” or the acronym CAPM we refer in our paper to the asset pricing model of Sharpe (1964), Lintner (1965), Mossin (1966), and Black (1972).

  2. For modified betas in general see also Pratt and Grabowski (2010, p. 167).

  3. For an up-to-date application see Ernstberger et al. (2011).

  4. Consequently, the portfolio betas are estimated with fresh data and, therefore, without a statistically caused measurement error. But this approach reduces the data available for estimating beta since one period is lost. For the measurement error and the aligned errors-in-variables-problem see Shanken (1992).

  5. See Morningstar (2013, p. 78), Blume (1971, p. 8), Table 4. Similar to the adjustment of Blume (1971) is the Merill Lynch, Pierce, Fenner, & Smith Inc. (MLPFS). Different approaches are the adjustments of Vasicek (1973) and the James–Stein Approach (Stein 1956, 1961) which are not discussed here. For further discussion on adjustments (see Klemkosky and Martin 1975, p. 1126; Schultz and Zimmermann 1989, pp. 200–201; Bauer 1992, pp. 101–102; Zimmermann 1997, p. 246, p. 251; Sharpe 1999, pp. 479–480).

  6. As an alternative to analytical analysis, simulations help to understand the behaviour of frequentist statistical results and, therefore, contribute to assess inferences derived from empirical data. For a general discussion on Monte Carlo simulations see Mooney (1997).

  7. For the early tests see Black et al. (1972), Miller and Scholes (1972), Fama and MacBeth (1973), and Blume and Friend (1973).

  8. For the (second-pass) cross section regression see Fama and MacBeth (1973), Black et al. (1972), and e.g. Levy (2012, pp. 191–192), and Goyal (2012, pp. 9–12).

  9. Where \(\lim _{T\rightarrow \infty }\sigma _{\hat{\beta }_{i}}^{2}=\lim _{T\rightarrow \infty }\sigma _{\varepsilon _{i}}^{2}(( T-2) \sigma _{R_{M}}^{2}) ^{-1}=0\), \(\hat{\beta }_{i}\) denotes the beta estimator, \(\beta _{i}\) the true but unknown beta.

  10. In addition, the assumption that the true but unobservable beta, \(\beta _{i}\), is constant over time may not be given.

  11. See Ernstberger et al. (2011) for the advantages of sorting in general.

  12. In the framework of empirical time series tests of the CAPM, a rotation of the security market line can be observed. Thus, empirically observed returns are too high for the low beta portfolios and too low for the high beta portfolios when compared to the predicted returns received from the standard CAPM based on beta estimates from the sorting period. See e.g. Stambaugh (1982), Black et al. (1972), Stambaugh (1982), Reichling (1995), Fama and French (2004, p. 33), Black et al. (1972) addressed this problem by separating the estimation period from the portfolio formation period which reduces the time series of utilisable data.

  13. See Blume (1975, p. 794–795).

  14. The index \(i\) describes a single company (where \(i=1,\ldots ,n\)), e.g. \(\hat{\beta }_{i}\), \(p\) a portfolio (where \(p=1,\ldots ,P\)), e.g. \(\hat{\beta }_{p}\), \(T\) the specific the cross section, e.g. \(\hat{\beta }_{T}\), and no index the pooled sample, e.g. \(\hat{\beta }\).

  15. The risk free rate is assumed to be fixed and is, therefore, not considered throughout calculations.

  16. Spurious measurement errors may occur due to the estimation process as will be illustrated in Sect. 3.

  17. Although the S&P 500 captures the market only partially, the choice of the market proxy is not critical in our case since we use the data for demonstration purposes only. In addition, empirical analyses show that there are high correlations between the monthly returns of the S&P 500, the NYSE, NYSE/AMEX and NYSE/AMEX/NASDAQ according to Morningstar (2013, p. 73), indicating a minor impact by the selected market proxy used here. Furthermore, we select a long time period in order to capture various economic patterns.

  18. Due to the assumptions of true beta \(\beta \sim N\left( 1;.16\right)\) the intercept is \(\gamma _{0}=1-\gamma _{1}\).

  19. In order to minimise spurious errors apart from the theoretical discussion of Sect. 2.2 we use a high number of stocks (Mooney 1997).

  20. Hence, true betas are distributed around the market mean of one, \(\mu _{\beta }=1\), with a standard deviation of \(\sigma _{\beta }=.4\), \(\beta \sim N\left( 1;.16\right)\).

  21. For simplicity the risk-free rate is set fix over each time period analysed and is, therefore, left out of the regression analysis.

  22. With reference to real market data as reported by Morningstar (2013, pp. 76–77), there are more outliers which result in a peak at a \(R^{2}\) of nearly zero and consequently outliers with high standard deviations of beta. Due to the fixed standard deviation used in the simulation, this pattern cannot be completely reproduced. Nevertheless, the simulated values for the cross section are comparable to real market data as reported by Morningstar (2013, pp. 76–77), which is based on a 5 year window regression.

  23. Portfolio betas are calculated as the mean of single betas estimated in that portfolio.

  24. Furthermore, this pattern confirms the suggestion of Lo and MacKinlay (1990) and Liang (2000) that sorting biases (CAPM) tests if variables used for grouping portfolios (here, the beta) are correlated with the coefficients being tested.

  25. The correspondent 7 years variance of market returns for the first regression window, \(T=1\), is \(\sigma _{R_{M}}^{2}=.001248\).

  26. Superior to adjusting portfolio betas would be choosing portfolio betas of period \(T=2\) as a starting point for further tests (as suggested by Black et al. 1972) or forming portfolios according to a random sampling approach (as suggested by Liang 2000).

  27. Accordingly, the corresponding sum squared error, for the portfolio betas estimated in the first regression window (first dashed vertical line in Fig. 1), \(\hat{\beta }_{p,T=1}\), therefore, decreases from \(.009867\) to \(.002929\) for adjusted portfolio betas, \(\hat{\beta }_{p,T=1}^{adj.}\). Thereby, the sum squared error, \(SSE\), is calculated as the squared difference between the portfolio betas estimated and the true underlying portfolio betas scaled by the total number, \(P\), of portfolios, \(SSE=\sum _{p}^{P}( \hat{\beta }_{p}-\beta _{p}) ^{2}P^{-1}\) (here \(P=10\)).

  28. Blume (1975) observes this pattern in the first as well as in the second subsequent period even after considering and adjusting the portfolio betas of the sorting period by a revised adjustment formula concluding that “companies of extreme risk [...] have less extreme risk characteristics over time” (Blume 1975, p. 794). He argues, therefore, that the mean reversion effect exists beyond measurement errors. Similarly, CAPM tests reveal a rotation of the security market line (e.g. Friend and Blume 1970; Black et al. 1972; Stambaugh 1982; Fama and French 2004). This has been observed with returns rather than with betas indicating that the linear form of the CAPM may not hold or that there may be additional pricing factors or that beta may vary over time. See Elgers et al. (1979) and Blume (1979) for a discussion about possible reasons for mean reversion effects. Generally, the reasons are seen in the order bias and in non-stationary betas, according to Jacobs and Z’graggen (1996, p. 94). For a practical application of adjustments for portfolios as well as for single stocks see Bauer (1992, p. 104), Blume (1971), Blume (1975), Klemkosky and Martin (1975), Elton et al. (1978), Eskew (1979), Eubank and Zumwalt (1979b), Eubank and Zumwalt (1979a), Dimson and Marsh (1983), Hawawini and Vora (1983), Winkelmann (1984), Hawawini et al. (1985), Ushman (1987), and Schultz and Zimmermann (1989). See further Mantripragada (1980) and Reeves and Wu (2013).

  29. Where true beta changes with \(\beta _{i,t}=\beta _{i,t-1}+\varepsilon _{t}\) with \(\varepsilon _{t}\sim N( 0,\sigma _{\varepsilon _{t}}^{2})\) and \(\sigma _{\varepsilon _{t}}=.04\). This autoregressive movement is defined as being set to vary in the range of the grand market mean of one plus/minus three standard deviations with \(\beta _{i,t}\in [ -.2;2.2]\).

  30. The regression window was changed from 7 to 5 years for illustrative purposes only, to reveal the convergence effect more strongly by taking more side by side adjacent regression windows into account.

  31. NYSE Constituent List as provided by Thomson Reuters. Even though a resulting survivorship bias may be criticised, its effect is non-essential here since first, the market index as the counterpart for estimating beta is calculated on the basis of these remaining companies and second, there is no fundamental interpretation deduced from these numbers since they serve as an illustration of the theoretically discussed statistical effect.

  32. Even though our approach is equal to the use of an equally weighted index resulting in a symmetric distribution of betas measured, which is a common use in research, business valuation practice commonly uses a value weighted index (e.g. S&P 500, DAX, etc.). Hence, returns of stocks with a lower market value are thus underrepresented in returns of a value weighted index. These stocks might, therefore, reveal a smaller correlation to that market index possibly resulting in a smaller beta measured since \(\pm \sqrt{R^{2}}=\rho _{R_{i},R_{M}}\Leftrightarrow R^{2}=\hat{\beta }_{i}\frac{\sigma _{R_{i},R_{M}}}{\sigma _{R_{i}}^{2}}\). As a result, with a value weighted index empirically measured betas might reveal a non symmetric distribution and analyses like those of Figs. 2 and 3 might not necessarily reveal an alleged mean reversion to a mean of one.

  33. For a more detailed illustration of this approximation using the example of the slope, \(\gamma _{1}\), between the first, \(T=1\), and subsequent, \(T=2\), 7 years regression window of Fig. 1 we refer to "Appendix A".

  34. The correspondent 7 years variance of market returns in \(T=1\) is \(\sigma _{R_{M}}^{2}=.001248\).

  35. The sum squared error, \(SSE\), is calculated as the squared difference between the beta estimated and the true underlying beta scaled by the total number, \(n\), of stocks, \(SSE=\sum _{i}^{n}( \hat{\beta }_{i}-\beta _{i}) ^{2}n^{-1}\) (here \(n=10,000\)).

  36. Figure 4 is provided without additional tables.

  37. One may have noted that the reported mean estimated variance of single stocks, \(\hat{\sigma }_{\hat{\beta }_{i}}^{2}\), and the mean estimated variance of all stocks, \(\hat{\sigma }_{\hat{\beta }}^{2}\), of the Tables 2 and 4 are consistently higher than the theoretical ones of Table 1 (\(\sigma _{\beta _{i}}^{2}\) and \(\sigma _{\beta }^{2}\) respectively). This is due to the Jensen Inequality and the fact that a sample variance is chi square and not symmetrically distributed. Furthermore, the mean values of the estimated variance of all stocks, \(\hat{\sigma }_{\hat{\beta }}^{2}\), in Table 4 slightly differ from those in Table 2 since values in Table 4 are calculated over the cross section on a rolling window basis whereas values in Table 2 are calculated simultaneously over the pooled sample.

  38. The adjustment with reference to Blume (1971), \(\beta _{i}^{adj.}=.371+.635\beta _{i}^{raw}\), represents the average coefficients of five subsequently performed regressions using a regression window of 7 years over the time period from 7/1926 to 6/1968. Even though our analysis is based on the S&P 500 (while Blume 1971 uses NYSE stocks) and we are only able to cover the time series covered by Blume (1971) partially, we achieve similar results to Blume (1971).

  39. Where \(Var[ \hat{\beta }_{i}^{adj.}] =Var[ \gamma _{0}+\gamma _{1}\hat{\beta }_{i}] =\gamma _{1}^{2}\sigma _{\hat{\beta }_{i}}^{2}\).

  40. We use a sixth degree Taylor Approximation here. See "Appendix C" for the derivation. For literature on how to adjust for effects arising from the Jensen Inequality due to using econometric estimators for determining cost of capital, we refer to Butler and Schachter (1989), Cooper (1996), Breuer et al. (2014) and Elsner and Krumholz (2013).

  41. With Eq. (12) in the form of \(f_{V_{i}}\left( R_{E,i}\right) =\sum _{t=1}^{\infty }\frac{E\left( D_{t}\right) }{\left( 1+R_{E,i}\right) ^{-t}}=\left( R_{f}+\left[ E\left( R_{M}\right) -R_{f}\right] \beta _{i}\right) ^{-1}\) where \(E( D_{t}) =E\left( D\right) =1\).

  42. Note that the continuously ascending \(R^{2}\) is caused by the evenly created dataset and the property of \(R^{2}=\rho _{R_{i},R_{M}}^{2}=\frac{\sigma _{R_{i},R_{M}}^{2}}{\sigma _{R_{M}}^{2}\sigma _{R_{i}}^{2}}=\hat{\beta }_{i}\frac{\sigma _{R_{i},R_{M}}}{\sigma _{R_{i}}^{2}}\).

  43. For literature on how to correct for the effect resulting from the Jensen Inequality see footnote (40). Where \(E[ f_{V_{i}}( \hat{\beta }_{i})] \ge f_{V_{i}}( E[ \hat{\beta _{i}}]) =f_{V_{i}}( \beta _{i})\).

  44. In order to stabilise results due to the exemplary risk free rate, \(R_{f}=3\,\%\), and the expected market risk premium, \(E\left( R_{M}\right) -R_{f}=5\,\%\), chosen, betas estimated up to \(-.4\) have been winsorised.

  45. See e.g. approaches of Claus and Thomas (2001), Gebhardt et al. (2001), Gode and Mohanram (2003), Easton (2004), Ohlson and Juettner-Nauroth (2005), Daske et al. (2006), and Nekrasov and Ogneva (2011).

References

  • Barnett AG, Pols JCvd, Dobson AJ (2004) Regression to the mean: what it is and how to deal with it. Int J Epidemiol 34(1):215–220

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bauer C (1992) Das Risiko von Aktienanlagen, Reihe Finanzierung, Steuern, Wirtschaftsprüfung, vol 15. Müller Botermann, Köln

    Google Scholar 

  • Berk JB (2000) Sorting out sorts. JFinance 55(1):407–427

  • Black F (1972) Capital market equilibrium with restricted borrowing. J Bus 45(3):444–455

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black F, Jensen MC, Scholes M (1972) The capital asset pricing model: some empirical tests. In: Jensen MC (ed) Studies in the theory of capital markets. Praeger, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Blume ME (1970) Portfolio theory: a step toward its practical application. J Bus 43(2):152–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blume ME (1971) On the assessment of risk. J Finance 26(1):1–10

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blume ME (1975) Betas and their regression tendencies. J Finance 30(3):785–795

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blume ME (1979) Betas and their regression tendencies: some further evidence. J Finance 34(1):265–267

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blume ME, Friend I (1973) A new look at the capital asset pricing model. J Finance 28(1):19–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Botosan CA (2006) Disclosure and the cost of capital: what do we know? Account Bus Res 36:31–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breuer W, Fuchs D, Mark K (2014) Estimating cost of capital in firm valuations with arithmetic or geometric mean—or better use the Cooper estimator? Eur J Finance 20(6):568–594

  • Butler JS, Schachter B (1989) The investment decision: estimation risk and risk adjusted discount rates. Financial Manag 18(4):13–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Claus J, Thomas J (2001) Equity premia as low as three percent? Evidence from analysts’ earnings forecasts for domestic and international stock markets. J Finance 56(5):1629–1666

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper I (1996) Arithmetic versus geometric mean estimators: setting discount rates for capital budgeting. Eur Financ Manag 2(2):157–167

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daske H, Gebhardt G, Klein S (2006) Estimating the expected cost of equity capital using analysts’ consensus forecasts. Schmalenbach Bus Rev 58(1):2–36

    Google Scholar 

  • Dimson E, Marsh PR (1983) The stability of UK risk measures and the problem of thin trading. J Finance 38(3):753–783

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dimson E, Mussavian M (1999) Three centuries of asset pricing. J Bank Finance 23(12):1745–1769

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easton PD (2004) PE ratios, PEG ratios, and estimating the implied expected rate of return on equity capital. Account Rev 79(1):73–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elgers PT, Haltiner JR, Hawthorne WH (1979) Beta regression tendencies: statistical and real causes. J Finance 34(1):261–263

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elsner S, Krumholz HC (2013) Corporate valuation using imprecise cost of capital. J Bus Econ 83(9):985–1014

  • Elton EJ, Gruber MJ, Urich TJ (1978) Are betas best? J Finance 33(5):1375–1384

    Google Scholar 

  • Ernstberger J, Haupt H, Vogler O (2011) The role of sorting portfolios in asset-pricing models. Appl Financ Econ 21(18):1381–1396

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eskew RK (1979) The forecasting ability of accounting risk measures: some additional evidence. Account Rev 54(1):107–118

    Google Scholar 

  • Eubank AAJ, Zumwalt JK (1979a) An analysis of the forecast error impact of alternative beta adjustment techniques and risk classes. J Finance 34(3):761–776

    Google Scholar 

  • Eubank AAJ, Zumwalt JK (1979b) How to determine the stability of beta values. J Portf Manag 5(2):22–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF (1977) Risk-adjusted discount rates and capital budgeting under uncertainty. J Financ Econ 5(1):3–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF, French KR (1997) Industry costs of equity. J Financ Econ 43(2):153–193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF, French KR (2004) The capital asset pricing model: theory and evidence. J Econ Perspect 18(3):25–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF, MacBeth JD (1973) Risk, return, and equilibrium: empirical tests. J Polit Econ 81(3):607

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher L (1966) Some new stock-market indexes. J Bus 39(1):191–225

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman M (1992) Do old fallacies ever die? J Econ Lit 30(4):2129–2132

    Google Scholar 

  • Friend I, Blume M (1970) Measurement of Portfolio performance under uncertainty. Am Econ Rev 60(4):561–575

    Google Scholar 

  • Galton F (1869) Hereditary genius. Macmillan and Co, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Galton F (1889) Natural inheritance. Macmillan, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gebhardt WR, Lee CMC, Swaminathan B (2001) Toward an implied cost of capital. J Account Res 39(1):135–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gode D, Mohanram P (2003) Inferring the cost of capital using the Ohlson–Juettner model. Rev Account Stud 8(4):399–431

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goyal A (2012) Empirical cross-sectional asset pricing: a survey. Financ Mark Portf Manag 26(1):3–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham JR, Harvey CR (2001) The theory and practice of corporate finance: evidence from the field: complementary research methodologies: the interplay of theoretical, empirical and field-based research in finance. J Financ Econ 60(2–3):187–243

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hawawini GA, Vora A (1983) Is adjusting beta estimates an illusion? J Portf Manag 10(1):23–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hawawini GA, Michel PA, Corhay A (1985) New evidence on beta stationarity and forecast for belgian common stocks. J Bank Finance 9(4):553–560

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling H (1933) Review of the triumph of mediocrity in business, by Horace Secrist. J Am Stat Assoc 28(184):463–465

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobs A, Z’graggen P (1996) Varianz der Eigenkapitalkosten von Schweizer Aktiengesellschaften. Swiss J Econ Stat 132(I):87–108

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen JLWV (1906) Sur les fonctions convexes et les inégalités entre les valeurs moyennes. Acta Mathematica 30(1):175–193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klemkosky RC, Martin JD (1975) The adjustment of beta forecasts. J Finance 30(4):1123–1128

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy H (2012) The capital asset pricing model in the 21st century, 1st edn. Cambridge Univ Press, Cambridge and Mass

    Google Scholar 

  • Liang B (2000) Portfolio formation, measurement errors, and beta shifts: a random sampling approach. J Financ Res 23(3):261–284

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lintner J (1965) The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock Portfolios and capital budgets. Rev Econ Stat 47(1):13–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lo AW, MacKinlay AC (1990) Data-snooping biases in tests of financial asset pricing models. Rev Financ Stud 3(3):431–467

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mantripragada KG (1980) Beta adjustment methods. J Bus Res 8(3):329–339

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller MH, Scholes M (1972) Rates of return in relation to risk: a re-examination of some recent findings. In: Jensen MC (ed) Studies in the theory of capital markets. Praeger, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Mooney CZ (1997) Monte Carlo simulation, Sage university papers series. In: Quantitative applications in the social sciences, vol 7–116. Sage Publications, Thousand Oaks and Calif

  • Morningstar (2013) Ibbotson SBBI valuation yearbook 2012: market results for stocks, bonds, bills, and inflation 1926–2011, Ibbotson Associates

  • Mossin J (1966) Equilibrium in a capital asset market. Econometrica 34(4):768–783

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nekrasov A, Ogneva M (2011) Using earnings forecasts to simultaneously estimate firm-specific cost of equity and long-term growth. Rev Account Stud 16(3):414–457

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nissim D, Penman SH (2001) Ratio analysis and equity valuation: from research to practice. Rev Account Stud 6(1):109–154

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ohlson JA, Juettner-Nauroth BE (2005) Expected EPS and EPS growth as determinants of value. Rev Account Stud 10(2–3):349–365

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Penman SH (2013) Financial statement analysis and security valuation, 5th edn. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Pratt SP, Grabowski RJ (2010) Cost of capital, 4th edn. Wiley, Hoboken

    Google Scholar 

  • Quah D (1993) Galton’s Fallacy and tests of the convergence hypothesis. Scand J Econ 95(4):427–443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reeves JJ, Wu H (2013) Constant versus time-varying beta models: further forecast evaluation. J Forecast 32(3):256–266

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reichling P (1995) Warum ist die Wertpapierkennlinie zu flach? Finanzmarkt und Portf Management 9(1):96–110

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross SA (1978) The current status of the capital asset pricing model (CAPM). J Finance 33(3):885–901

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schultz J, Zimmermann H (1989) Risikoanalyse schweizerischer Aktien: Stabilität und Prognose von Betas. Finanzmarkt und Portf Manag 3(3):196–209

    Google Scholar 

  • Secrist H (1933) The triumph of mediocrity in business. Northwestern Univ, Evanston

    Google Scholar 

  • Shanken J (1992) On the estimation of beta-pricing models. Rev Financ Stud 5(1):1–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sharpe WF (1964) Capital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. J Finance 19(3):425–442

    Google Scholar 

  • Sharpe WF (1999) Investments, 6th edn. Prentice Hall international editions. Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River

  • Stambaugh RF (1982) On the exclusion of assets from tests of the two-parameter model: a sensitivity analysis. J Financ Econ 10(3):237–268

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stein C (1956) Inadmissibility of the usual estimator for the mean of a multivariate normal distribution. In Neyman J (ed) Proceedings of the third Berkeley symposium on mathematical statistics and probability. University of California Press, Berkeley, pp 197–206

  • Stein C (1961) Estimation with quadratic loss. In: Neyman J (ed) Proceedings of the fourth Berkeley symposium on mathematical statistics and probability. University of California Press, Berkeley, pp 361–380

  • Stigler SM (1996) The history of statistics in 1933. Stat Sci 11(3):244–252

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler SM (1997) Regression towards the mean, historically considered. Stat Methods Med Res 6(2):103–114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Subrahmanyam A (2010) The cross-section of expected stock returns: what have we learnt from the past twenty-five years of research? Eur Financ Manag 16(1):27–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ushman NL (1987) A comparison of cross-sectional and time-series beta adjustment techniques. J Bus Finance Account 14(3):355–375

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vasicek OA (1973) A note on using cross-sectional information in bayesian estimation of security betas. J Finance 28(5):1233–1239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winkelmann M (1984) Aktienbewertung in Deutschland, Quantitative Methoden der Unternehmungsplanung, vol 19. Hain, Königstein/Ts

    Google Scholar 

  • Zimmermann P (1997) Schätzung und Prognose von Betawerten: Eine Untersuchung am deutschen Aktienmarkt, vol 7. Uhlenbruch, Bad Soden/Ts

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to F. Echterling.

Appendices

Appendix A: Progression of the slope at the portfolio level

Figure 7 highlights the slope progression of a regression for portfolio betas from the subsequent period, \(\hat{\beta }_{p,T=2}\), on portfolio betas from the first regression window, \(\hat{\beta }_{p,T=1}\), of Fig. 1 (where a 7 years’ regression window has been used), \(\hat{\beta }_{p,T=2}\sim \hat{\beta }_{p,T=1}\), dependent on the numbers of portfolios used in which to group estimated betas. In order to avoid any bias on the calculation of portfolio means caused by an uneven allocation of stocks to portfolios, the numbers, \(P\), used for portfolio formation (x-axis in Fig. 7; namely 2, 4, 5, 8, 10, 16, 20, 25, 40, 50, 80, 100, 125, 200, 250, 400, 500, and 625) guarantees a portfolio allocation with a balanced number of stocks.

As outlined in Sect. 3.3, the slope moves closer to the slope of a similar regression on a single beta level according to Eq. (6) (here: \(\gamma _{1}=0.622514\) of \(\hat{\beta }_{T=2}\sim \hat{\beta }_{T=1}\)), the more portfolios are used within which to sort the stocks. If the maximum number of portfolios is reached (here: 10,000), the portfolio regression is identical to a regression represented by the Eqs. (6) and (8).

Fig. 7
figure 7

Progression of the slope at the portfolio level. The estimated slope of the regression \(\hat{\beta }_{p,T=2}\sim \hat{\beta }_{p,T=1}\) (of Fig. 1) dependent on the numbers of portfolios used within which to group estimated betas

Appendix B: Sensitivity of \(\gamma _{0}\) and \(\gamma _{1}\)

In order to provide a sensitivity analysis for our values \(\hat{\gamma }_{0}=.374824\) and \(\hat{\gamma }_{1}=.622514\) in the first period, \(T=1\) (whereas the mean over our 50 years period as reported in Table 4 was \(\hat{\gamma }_{0}=.307447\) and \(\hat{\gamma }_{1}=.692847\); 7 years regression window example similar to Blume (1971) we use the corresponding first available variance of market index returns from 01/1964 to 12/1970 of the S&P 500 with \(\sigma _{R_{M}}^{2}=.001248\) and vary the values for the variance of the error term, \(\sigma _{\varepsilon _{i}}\), and for the distribution of true beta, \(\sigma _{\beta }\), which were explicitly assumed to be fix in the analysis before, using \(\sigma _{\varepsilon _{i}}=.1\) and \(\sigma _{\beta }=.4\). For varying values of \(\sigma _{\varepsilon _{i}}\) around \(.10\) and \(\sigma _{\beta }\) around \(.40\) we still receive similar results as those suggested by Morningstar (2013) with (Table 6) reference to Blume (1971) (\(\gamma _{0}\equiv .371\), \(\gamma _{1}\equiv .635\)).

Table 6 Sensitivity analysis of a regression according to Eqs. (6) and (8)

Appendix C: Taylor expansion valuation example

If constant cost of equity capital is assumed with an exogenously given and constant market risk premium, \(E\left( R_{M}\right) -R_{f}\), and risk free rate, \(R_{f}\), Eq. (18) may be approximated by an \(N\)-th degree Taylor Series expansion, \(T_{N}f( R_{E,i};\mu _{R_{E,i}})\). For \(R_{E,i}\) as the beta dependent measurement the expansion notes in the form of Eq. (19) whereas \(R_{E,i}\) is decomposed to \(R_{E,i}\equiv \mu _{R_{E,i}}+\sigma _{R_{E,i}}e\) with \(e\sim N\left( 0,1\right)\) as a standard error.

$$\begin{aligned} f_{V_{i}}\left( R_{E,i}\right)&= \sum _{t=1}^{\infty }\frac{E\left( D_{t}\right) }{\left( 1+R_{E,i}\right) ^{t}}\end{aligned}$$
(18)
$$\begin{aligned} f_{V_{i}}\left( R_{E,i}\right)&\approx T_{N}f\left( R_{E,i};\mu _{R_{E,i}}\right) =\sum _{n=0}^{N}\frac{f^{\left( n\right) }\left( \mu _{R_{E,i}}\right) }{n!}\left( R_{E,i}-\mu _{R_{E,i}}\right) ^{n}=\sum _{n=0}^{N}\frac{f^{\left( n\right) }\left( \mu _{R_{E,i}}\right) }{n!}\sigma _{R_{E,i}}^{n}e^{n} \end{aligned}$$
(19)

For a perpetual dividend stream of \(E\left( D_{t}\right) =E\left( D\right) =1\) the expansion and, therefore, the expected company value determined by betas measured then simplifies to Eq. (20). Since for odd orders, \(n\), \(E\left[ e^{n}\right] =0\), a sixth order approximation notes as Eq. (21).

$$\begin{aligned} E\left[ f_{V_{i}}\left( R_{E,i}\right) \right]&\approx\sum _{n=0}^{N}\frac{f^{\left( n\right) }\left( \mu _{R_{E,i}}\right) }{n!}\sigma _{R_{E,i}}^{n}E\left[ e^{n}\right] =\sum _{n=0}^{N}\frac{\left( -1\right) ^{n}n!\mu _{R_{E,i}}^{-\left( 1+n\right) }}{n!}\sigma _{R_{E,i}}^{n}E\left[ e^{n}\right] \nonumber \\&\approx\sum _{n=0}^{N}\left( -1\right) ^{n}\mu _{R_{E,i}}^{-\left( 1+n\right) }\sigma _{R_{E,i}}^{n}E\left[ e^{n}\right] \end{aligned}$$
(20)
$$\begin{aligned} E\left[ f_{V_{i}}\left( R_{E,i}\right) \right]&\approx T_{6}f\left( R_{E,i};\mu _{R_{E,i}}\right) =\mu _{R_{E,i}}^{-1}+\frac{\sigma _{R_{E,i}}^{2}}{\mu _{R_{E,i}}^{3}}+\frac{3\sigma _{R_{E,i}}^{4}}{\mu _{R_{E,i}}^{5}}+\frac{15\sigma _{R_{E,i}}^{6}}{\mu _{R_{E,i}}^{7}} \end{aligned}$$
(21)

Whereas the first part of Eq. (21), \(\mu _{R_{E,i}}^{-1}\), represents the theoretical true company value, the rest represents the effect due to the Jensen Inequality.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Echterling, F., Eierle, B. Mean reversion adjusted betas used in business valuation practice: a research note. J Bus Econ 85, 759–792 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11573-014-0750-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11573-014-0750-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation