Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

What Have We Called as “Poverty”? A Multidimensional and Longitudinal Perspective

  • Published:
Social Indicators Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Although the multidimensional approach to poverty is a common-sense idea, there have been numerous debates on what kind of dimensions can be included in the concept. As one way of addressing the issue, I introduce a dimension of ‘time’, which could help us to select more relevant dimensions by displaying the changes in their influence on the multidimensional poverty over a period of time. After the thirteen waves of British Household Panel Survey data, 1996–2008, are analyzed for a multidimensional poverty based on the Capability approach, I find out that most of the dimensions that have mentioned in previous research demonstrate a consistent influence on poverty over the period, which implies that existing literature on multidimensional poverty has been on the right path. Also, it turns out that the dimensions of ‘health’ and ‘social capital’ are getting more weights in measuring the multidimensional poverty, while ‘economic resources’ dimension is still the most influential factor for the construct. The findings seem to suggest that the multidimensional approach as it stands is quite relevant, though an agreeable list of dimensions of poverty still requires far more intellectual endeavor.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. It is certain that the negative impressions on the result of the “War” also have a lot to do with the implementation part of a policy process, which were convincingly argued in Pressman and Wildavsky (1979)’s ground–breaking research.

  2. It is certain that it also depends heavily on regional differences. Recently, the U.S. Census Bureau begins to produce the Supplemental Poverty Measurement series, and one of the main arguments for it is that it is indispensable to take the geographic variation in the cost of living into account when we measure poverty (Meyer and Sullivan 2012).

  3. Tomlinson et al. (2008), however, argue that even the initial students of poverty measurement already realized the need to take account of social conditions. Also, they find that Adam Smith already considered “shame and stigma” as an inherent components of poverty.

  4. It is also worthwhile to note that S. Anand and Sen (1997) argues that the tendency to concentrate on other variables than income, such as, the inability to take part in the life of the community, is especially strong in the more affluent countries.

  5. It has to be noted that the existence of one operational definition does not necessarily mean there should be one composite index for social exclusion. Marlier and Atkinson (2010) even advocate that the key dimensions of social exclusion should not be aggregated into one index “not to conceal dissensions in a ‘scientific’ model” (Erikson 1974).

  6. It has three main “pillars”, which can be outlined as “Promote the effective exercise of fundamental rights”, “Promote an integrated approach and action”, and “Promote participation and partnership”(Demeyer & Farrell 2005).

  7. Sen (1992) argues that to have a choice to go without food, i.e., for religious reason, shows one has more freedom than the other one who only has a choice to eat (no matter whether it is possible), for example, people in the sub-Saharan Africa who usually cannot but live in a deprivation of food.

  8. On the contrary, Nussbaum (2003) argues enthusiastically for a list of central capabilities as a guideline.

  9. “Lack of functionings” does not imply a binary distinction. With some difficulty in designing measurement system, it is entirely possible to make a measurement that can distinguish the extent of it.

  10. Commenting on the study of deprivation begun by Townsend (1979b)’s approach to non-monetary poverty index, Veit-Wilson (1987) poses a question on how a selected list of indicators by a researcher can be justified.

  11. Measuring these conditions, the author strongly recommends using both objective and subjective indicators. While objective indicators refer to the observation of factual conditions, subjective indicators stand for “measurement of attitudes” (Allardt 1993). For example, the ratio of students to teachers can be an objective indicator for an educational environment, whereas subjective indicators can be obtained by asking students’ opinion about the educational environment.

  12. “Existential” categories indicate four aspects of human existence: being, having, doing, and interacting, each of which corresponds to personal or collective attribute, institutional context, actions, and locations and milieus (as times and spaces), respectively. On the other hand, “axiological” categories denote nine dimensions of human needs.

  13. Alkire (2002) replaces this term as “leisure”, but I will use the original term since Max-Neef (1993) argues that this term has some productive meaning, and therefore is totally different from laziness.

  14. Specific meanings of these dimensions are not elaborated by the author, but indicators of the dimensions are fully provided.

  15. Robeyns (2000) reviews twelve researches adopting the capability approach, and all of them regard health as an important functioning.

  16. Tomer (2002) puts it in this way, “It is not about how much food one consumes; it is about eating tasty food and being well-nourished.”

  17. These phrases indicate that there is still a room for inevitable arbitrariness in terms of choosing specific indicators, because the concept of “modern American society” or “every-day life activities” implies cultural or relative aspects of poverty.

  18. Foster and Shorrocks (1988) point that arbitrary decisions also exist in traditional poverty measurements. They identify two main sources of arbitrariness: (1) the precise functional form adopted to aggregate influences the results eventually obtained, and (2) how to set a poverty line. See also Haughton (2009); Ringen (1988).

  19. For more detailed discussion on the arbitrariness in multidimensional poverty measurement, see Qizilbash (2004).

  20. Clark and Qizilbash (2008) find that their ‘supervaluationist’ approach to the choice of indicators that is based on the rule of unanimity cannot yield robust results empirically. See also discussion between Sen (2004a) and Nussbaum (2003).

  21. Due to the difficulty in distinction, researchers such as Bane and Ellwood (1986), or Stevens (1999) try some ad-hoc method, like attributing a change smaller than ±10 % of poverty line to measurement error.

  22. See https://www.understandingsociety.ac.uk/about/bhps-in-understanding-society.

  23. Since the multiple imputation method generally stands on the assumption of missing at random (MAR), this should not be understood as concluding that missingness is irrelevant. However, as van Buuren (2012) shows, the multiple imputation method is “remarkably robust against not missing at random (NMAR)” situation. Besides, I utilize the fully conditional specification (FCS) which are known to provide multiple imputation results minimal bias and maximal efficiency (Meng 1994; Collins et al. 2001). Also, the examination of ‘relative bias’—according to Graham (2012), it can be assessed by looking into the residual covariance matrix in SEM context—displays that the bias introduced by missingness is not great.

  24. There are two points involving measurement error. The first is that no single variable represents appropriately a functioning, and the second is that a subjective evaluation often implies the "anchoring" problem, different connotations due to a reference group (Kuklys 2005; Kuklys and Robeyns 2004).

  25. Kline (2011) categorizes the indices other than Chi square statistic as “approximate fit indexes” because these statistics do not take sampling error into account and they can vary across samples for a same model. He further points that the thresholds for the indexes would not be justified because models with an acceptable model fit can still account for a part of model very poorly.

  26. As a matter of fact, Brown (2006) points that the transformation would not change the explanatory power of the original solution.

  27. For the purpose of model evaluation, Kline (2011) argues for reporting the unstandardized factor loadings as well. The table as well as model fit statistics for each year can be found in Appendix 3.

  28. Meyer and Sullivan (2012) delve into the diverse measures of poverty to understand how different people are categorized as poor by those measurements. They find that a ‘health spending’ indicator, which is the proxy for health status in the newly-developed “Supplemental Poverty Measurement (SPM)” in the U.S., has a rather complex relationship with health status. It does not necessarily mean that health spending is not a reliable observation, but it does suggest that we need to consider health status itself whenever it is available.

  29. Anand et al. (2005) argue that it is better for policymakers to try to enhance the choice set available to people rather than to point out what people choose to do accurately.

  30. This point is epitomized by Sen (1979a)’s Cambridge University lecture title “Equality of What?” If measuring poverty is an evaluation of a situation, we have an agreement on neither what kind of situation we should look into nor what criteria we should be based on. Sen calls this “a valuation problem”.

References

  • Addison, T., Hulme, D., & Kanbur, R. (2009). Poverty dynamics: Interdisciplinary perspectives. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Alkire, S. (2002). Dimensions of human development. World Development, 30(2), 181–205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alkire, S. (2008). Choosing dimensions: The capability approach and multidimensional poverty. In N. Kakwani & J. Silber (Eds.), The many dimensions of poverty. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alkire, S., & Black, R. (1997). A practical reasoning theory of development ethics: Furthering the capabilities approach. Journal of International Development, 9(2), 263–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allardt, E. (1993). Having, loving, being: An alternative to the swedish model of welfare research. In M. C. Nussbaum & A. K. Sen (Eds.), The quality of life. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anand, P., Hunter, G., Carter, I., Dowding, K., Guala, F., & Van Hees, M. (2009). The development of capability indicators. Journal of Human Development and Capabilities, 10(1), 125–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anand, P., Hunter, G., & Smith, R. (2005). Capabilities and well-being: Evidence based on the Sen-Nussbaum approach to welfare. Social Indicators Research, 74(1), 9–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anand, P., Krishnakumar, J., & Tran, N. B. (2010). Measuring welfare: Latent variable models for happiness and capabilities in the presence of unobservable heterogeneity. Journal of Public Economics, In Press, Accepted Manuscript.

  • Anand, S., & Sen, A. K. (1997). Concepts of human development and poverty: A multidimensional perspective. Human Development Papers, 1–19.

  • Antolin, P., Dang, T. T., & Oxley, H. (2000). Poverty Dynamics in Six OECD Countries (OECD Economic Studies No. 02550822). OECD Publications and Information Centre.

  • Atkinson, A. B. (1999). The contributions of Amartya Sen to welfare economics. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 101(2), 173–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson, A. B. (2003). Multidimensional deprivation: Contrasting social welfare and counting approaches. Journal of Economic Inequality, 1(1), 51–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson, A. B., Marlier, E., & Nolan, B. (2004). Indicators and targets for social inclusion in the European Union. Journal of Common Market Studies, 42(1), 47–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ballon, P., & Krishnakumar, J. (2010). Measuring Multidimensional Poverty: A Model-Based Index of Capability Deprivation (Unpublished Work). Geneva.

  • Bane, M. J., & Ellwood, D. T. (1986). Slipping into and out of poverty: The dynamics of spells. Journal of Human Resources, 21(1), 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basu, K. (1987). Achievements, capabilities and the concept of well-being. Social Choice and Welfare, 4(1), 69–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bauman, K. J. (2003). Extended measures of well-being: living conditions in the United States, 1998 [sssssGovernment Document]. USA: U.S Census Bureau.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benner, C., & Pastor, M. (2012). Just growth: Inclusion and prosperity in America’s metropolitan regions. New York, NY: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bérenger, V., & Verdier-Chouchane, A. (2007). Multidimensional measures of well-being: Standard of living and quality of life across countries. World Development, 35(7), 1259–1276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Betti, G., Cheli, B., Lemmi, A., & Verma, V. (2005). The fuzzy approach to multidimensional poverty: The case of Italy in the 90’s. [Conference Paper] UNDP. August 29–31, 2005.

  • Betti, G., & Verma, V. (1998). Measuring the Degree of Poverty in a Dynamic and Comparative Context: A Multi-Dimensional Approach using Fuzzy Set Theory (Electronic Article No. 22). Universita di Siena, Dipartimento di Metodi Quantitativi.

  • Blank, R. M. (2008). Presidential address: How to improve poverty measurement in the United States. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 27(2), 233–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boarini, R., & d’Ercole, M. M. (2006). Measures of Material Deprivation in OECD Countries (Generic No. 37). OECD.

  • Booth, C. (1892). Life and labour of the people of London. London, U.K.: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Booysen, F. (2002). An overview and evaluation of composite indices of development. Social Indicators Research, 59(2), 115–151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bossert, W., Chakravarty, R., Satya, & D’Ambrosio, C. (2009). Multidimensional poverty and material deprivation [Electronic Article]. Society for the Study of Economic Inequality (ECINEQ).

  • Bossert, W., D’Ambrosio, C., & Peragine, V. (2007). Deprivation and social exclusion. Economica, 74(296), 777–803.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bourguignon, F., & Chakravarty, S. R. (2003). The measurement of multidimensional poverty. Journal of Economic Inequality, 1(1), 25–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradshaw, J. (2000). Prospects for poverty in britain in the first twenty-five years of the next century. Sociology-the Journal of the British Sociological Association, 34(1), 53–70.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bradshaw, J., & Finch, N. (2003). Overlaps in dimensions of poverty. Journal of Social Policy, 32(4), 13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brady, D. (2003). Rethinking the sociological measurement of poverty. Social Forces, 81(3), 36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandolini, A., & D’Alessio, G. (1998). Measuring well-being in the functioning space [Unpublished Work]. Rome, Banca d’Italia.

  • Brown, T. A. (2006). Confirmatory factor analysis for applied research. New York, NY: The Guilford Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carr-Hill, R. (1986). An approach to monitoring social welfare. In P. Nolan & S. Paine (Eds.), Rethinking socialist economics: A new agenda for Britain. New York: St. Martin’s Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cellini, S. R., McKernan, S.-M., & Ratcliffe, C. (2008). The dynamics of poverty in the United States: A review of data, methods, and findings. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 27(3), 577–605.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappero-Martinetti, E. (2000). A multidimensional assessment of well-being based on Sen’s functioning approach. Rivista Internazionale di Scienze Sociali, 2, 207–239.

    Google Scholar 

  • Citro, C. F., & Michael, R. T. (1995). Measuring poverty: A new approach. Washington, DC: National Academy Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark, D. A. (2003). Concepts and perceptions of human well-being: Some evidence from South Africa. Oxford Development Studies, 31(2), 173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, D. A., & Qizilbash, M. (2008). Core poverty, vagueness and adaptation: A new methodology and some results for South Africa. Journal of Development Studies, 44(4), 519–544.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collins, L. M., Schafer, J. L., & Kam, C. M. (2001). A comparison of inclusive and restrictive strategies in modern missing data procedures. Psychological Methods, 6(3), 330–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costa, M. (2002). A multidimensional approach to the measurement of poverty (IRISS Working Paper Series). IRISS at CEPS/INSTEAD. Retrieved December from http://ideas.repec.org/p/irs/iriswp/2002-05.htmlsss

  • Couch, K. A., & Pirog, M. A. (2010). Poverty measurement in the U.S., Europe, and developing countries. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 29(2), 217–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cummins, R. A. (1996). The domains of life satisfaction: An attempt to order chaos. Social Indicators Research, 38(3), 303–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dagum, C., & Costa, M. (2004). Analysis and measurement of poverty: Univariate and multivariate approaches and their policy implications: A case study: Italy. In C. Dagum & G. Ferrari (Eds.), Household Behaviour. Equivalence Scales, Welfare and Poverty Heidelberg, Germany: Physica-Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Danziger, S., & Haveman, R. H. (2001). Understanding Poverty. Cambridge, MA: Russell Sage Foundation; Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Danziger, S., & Weinberg, D. H. (1986). Fighting poverty: What works and what doesn’t. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demeyer, B., & Farrell, F. (2005). Indicators of social quality and the anti-poverty strategies. European Journal of Social Quality, 5, 1–2.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desai, M. (1991). Human development: concepts and measurement. European Economic Review, 35(2–3), 350–357.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desai, M., & Shah, A. (1988). An econometric approach to the measurement of poverty. Oxford Economic Papers, 40(3), 505–522.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deutsch, J., & Silber, J. (2005). Measuring multidimensional poverty: An empirical comparison of various approaches. Review of Income and Wealth, 51(1), 145–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dewilde, C. (2004). The multidimensional measurement of poverty in Belgium and Britain: A categorical approach. Social Indicators Research, 68(3), 331–369.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doyal, L., & Gough, I. (1991). A theory of human need. New York: Guilford Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Duclos, J. Y., Sahn, D. E., & Younger, S. D. (2006). Robust multidimensional poverty comparisons. The Economic Journal, 116(514), 943–968.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duncan, G. J., Gustafsson, B., Hauser, R., Schmauss, G., Messinger, H., Muffels, R., & Ray, J.-C. (1993). Poverty dynamics in eight countries. Journal of Population Economics, 6(3), 215–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erikson, R. (1974). Welfare as a planning goal. Acta Sociologica, 17, 273–288.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esposito, L., & Chiappero-Martinetti, E. (2008). Multidimensional Poverty Measurement: Restricted and Unrestricted Hierarchy among Poverty Dimensions [Unpublished Work]. Oxford. Retrieved from www.ophi.org.uk

  • Federman, M., & Garner, T. I. (1996). What does it mean to be poor in America? Monthly Labor Review, 119(5), 3.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foster, J. E. (1984). On economic poverty: A survey of aggregate measures. Advances in Econometrics, 3, 215–252.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foster, J. E., & Shorrocks, A. F. (1988). Poverty orderings and welfare dominance. Social Choice and Welfare, 5(2), 179–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fukuda-Parr, S. (2003). The human development paradigm: Operationalizing Sen’s ideas on capabilities. Feminist Economics, 9(2/3), 301.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham, J. W. (2012). Missing data: Analysis and design. New York, NY: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Grusky, D. B., & Kanbur, R. (2006). Introduction: The conceptual foundations of poverty and inequality measurement. In D. B. Grusky & R. Kanbur (Eds.), Poverty and Inequality. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hacourt, G. (2003). Poverty indicators: Starting from the experience of people living in poverty (Report). European Anti-Poverty Network.

  • Haughton, J. H. (2009). Handbook on poverty and inequality. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayati, D., Karami, E., & Slee, B. (2006). Combining qualitative and quantitative methods in the measurement of rural poverty: The case of Iran. Social Indicators Research, 75(3), 361–394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Himmelfarb, G. (1991). Poverty and compassion: The Moral Imagination of the Late Victorians. New York, NY: Vintage Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hu, L., & Bentler, P. M. (1999). Cutoff criteria for fit indexes in covariance structure analysis: Conventional criteria versus new alternatives. Structural Equation Modeling, 6, 1–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hulme, D., & McKay, A. (2007). Identifying and measuring chronic poverty: Beyond monetary measures? In N. Kakwani & J. Silber (Eds.), The Many Dimensions of Poverty. New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jäntti, M. (2009). Mobility in the United States in comparative perspective. Focus, 26(2), 38–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jenkins, S. P., & Micklewright, J. (2007). Inequality and poverty re-examined. Oxford New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., Krueger, A. B., Schkade, D., Schwarz, N., & Stone, A. (2004). Toward national well-being accounts. American Economic Review, 94(2), 429–434.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kakwani, N., & Silber, J. (2007). The many dimensions of poverty. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kangas, O., & Ritakallio, V.-M. (1998). Different methods—different results? approaches to multidimensional poverty. In H.-J. Andress (Ed.), Empirical poverty research in a comparative perspective (pp. 167–203). Hants, UK: Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan, D. (2000). Structural equation modeling: foundations and extensions. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim, S.-G. (2014). Fuzzy multidimensional poverty measurement: An analysis of statistical behaviors. Social Indicators Research, 120(3), 635–667.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kline, R. B. (2011). Principles and practice of structural equation modeling (3rd ed.). New York, NY: Guilford Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuklys, W. (2005). Amartya Sen’s capability approach: theoretical insights and empirical applications. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuklys, W., & Robeyns, I. (2004). Sen’s capability approach to welfare economics (Report). Cambridge University.

  • Lelli, S. (2001). Factor analysis vs. Fuzzy sets theory: Assessing the influence of different techniques on Sen’s functioning approach (Report). K. U. Leuven, DPS.

  • Lichter, D. T., & Crowley, M. L. (2002). Poverty in America: Beyond Welfare Reform (Vol. 57) (Generic No. 2). The Population Reference Bureau.

  • Maasoumi, E., & Lugo, M. A. (2008). The information basis of multivariate poverty assessments. In N. Kakwani & J. Silber (Eds.), Quantitative approaches to multidimensional poverty measurement. New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marlier, E., & Atkinson, A. B. (2010). Indicators of poverty and social exclusion in a global context. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 29(2), 285–304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Max-Neef, M. A. (1993). Human scale development: Conception, Application and further reflections. New York: The Apex Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meng, X.-L. (1994). Multiple imputation with uncongenial sources of input (with Discussion). Statistical Science, 9(4), 538–573.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, B. D., & Sullivan, J. X. (2012). Identifying the disadvantaged: official poverty, consumption poverty, and the new supplemental poverty measure. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26(3), 111–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Millar, J. (2003). Gender, poverty and social exclusion. Social Policy and Society, 2(3), 181–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morduch, J. (1994). Poverty and vulnerability. American Economic Review, 84(2), 221–225.

    Google Scholar 

  • Muffels, R. (1993). Deprivation standards and style of living indices. In J. Berghman & B. Cantillon (Eds.), The European face of social security: Essays in honour of Herman Deleeck. Avebury: Brookfield, VT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Muffels, R., Berghman, J., & Dirven, H.-J. (1992). A multi-method approach to monitor the evolution of poverty. Journal of European Social Policy, 2(3), 193–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mussard, S., & Pi Alperin María, N. (2005). Multidimensional decomposition of poverty: A Fuzzy Set approach (Report). Groupe de Recherche en Économie et Développement International. Retrieved from http://ideas.repec.org/p/shr/wpaper/05-08.html

  • Narayan, D., Patel, R., Schafft, K., Rademacher, A., & Koch-Schulte, S. (2000). Can anyone hear us?: Voices from 47 countries. New York: Oxford University Press for the World Bank.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Nolan, B., & Whelan, C. T. (2010). Using non-monetary deprivation indicators to analyze poverty and social exclusion: Lessons from Europe? Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 29(2), 305–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nussbaum, M. C. (2000). Women and human development: The capabilities approach. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Nussbaum, M. C. (2003). Capabilities as fundamental entitlements: Sen and social justice. Feminist Economics, 9(2/3), 33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Orshansky, M. (1965). Counting the poor: Another look at the poverty profile. Social Security Bulletin, 28(1), 3–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Øyen, E. (1996). Poverty Research Rethought. In E. Øyen, S. M. Miller, & S. A. Samad (Eds.), Poverty: a global review: Handbook on international poverty research (pp. 3–17). Boston, MA: Scandinavian University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pastor, M., & Benner, C. (2008). Been down so long: Week market cities and regional equity. In R. McGahey & J. Vey (Eds.), Restoring Prosperity in Older Industrial Areas. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pressman, J., & Wildavsky, A. B. (1979). Implementation: How great expectations in Washington are dashed in Oakland. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Qizilbash, M. (1996). Capabilities, well-being and human development: A Survey. Journal of Development Studies, 33(2), 143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Qizilbash, M. (1997). Pluralism and well-being indices. World Development, 25(12), 2009–2026.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Qizilbash, M. (2004). On the Arbitrariness and robustness of multidimensional poverty rankings. Journal of Human Development, 5(3), 355–375.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rank, M. R., & Hirschl, T. A. (2001). The occurrence of poverty across the life cycle: Evidence from the PSID. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 20(4), 737–755.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ringen, S. (1988). Direct and indirect measures of poverty. Journal of Social Policy, 17(03), 351–365.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ringen, S. (1995). Well-being, measurement, and preferences. Acta Sociologica, 38(1), 3–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robeyns, I. (2000). An Unworkable idea or a promising alternative? Sen’s capability approach re-examined [Unpublished Work]. Leuven, Germany.

  • Robeyns, I. (2003). Sen’s capability approach and gender inequality: Selecting relevant capabilities. Feminist Economics, 9(2/3), 61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robeyns, I. (2006). The Capability Approach in Practice. Journal of Political Philosophy, 14(3), 351–376.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rowntree, B. S. (1901). Poverty: A study of town life. London, UK: Macmillian.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmid, J., & Leiman, J. M. (1957). The development of hierarchical factor solutions. Psychometrika, 22, 53–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seccombe, K. (2000). Families in poverty in the 1990s: Trends, causes, consequences, and lessons learned. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 62, 1094–1113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seers, D. (1969). The meaning of development. International Development Review, 11(2), 2–6.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seidl, C. (1988). Poverty Measurement: A Survey. In D. Bös, M. Rose, & C. Seidl (Eds.), Welfare and efficiency in public economics (pp. 71–147). New York: Springer-Verlag.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. K. (1979a). Equality of what? [Electronic Article]. April 17, 2010.

  • Sen, A. K. (1979b). Issues in the measurement of poverty. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 81(2), 285–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. K. (1979c). Personal utilities and public judgments: Or what’s wrong with welfare economics. The Economic Journal, 89(355), 537–558.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. K. (1985a). Commodities and capabilities. New York: Elsevier Science.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. K. (1985b). A Sociological approach to the measurement of poverty: A reply to professor peter townsend. Oxford Economic Papers, 37(4), 669–676.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. K. (1985c). The Standard of Living [Electronic Article]. University of Cambridge.

  • Sen, A. K. (1992). Inequality reexamined. Cambridge: Russell Sage Foundation; Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. K. (1993). Capability and well-being. In M. C. Nussbaum & A. K. Sen (Eds.), The Quality of Life. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. K. (1997). On economic inequality. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. K. (2000). A decade of human development. Journal of Human Development, 1(1), 17–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. K. (2004a). Capabilities, lists, and public reason: Continuing the conversation. Feminist Economics, 10(3), 77–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. K. (2004b). Elements of a theory of human rights. Philosophy and Public Affairs, 32(4), 315–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smeeding, T. (2006). Poor people in rich nations: The United States in comparative perspective. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(1), 69–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stevens, A. H. (1994). The dynamics of poverty spells: Updating Bane and Ellwood. The American Economic Review, 84(2), 34–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stevens, A. H. (1999). Climbing out of poverty, falling back in. Journal of Human Resources, 34(3), 557–588.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E., Sen, A. K., & Fitoussi, J.-P. (2009). Report by the Commission on the Measurement of Economic Performance and Social Progress [Electronic Article]. The Commission on the Measurement of Economic Performance and Social Progress. Retrieved February 11, 2011 from http://www.stiglitz-sen-fitoussi.fr/documents/rapport_anglais.pdf

  • Sugden, R. (1993). Review: Welfare, resources, and capabilities: A Review of inequality reexamined by Amartya Sen. Journal of Economic Literature, 31(4), 1947–1962.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, M. F., Brice, J., Buck, N., & Prentice-Lane, E. (2010). British Household Panel Survey user manual (Vols. A: Introduction, Technical report and Appendices). U.K.: University of Essex.

  • Thorbecke, E. (2005). Multidimensional poverty: Conceptual and measurement issues [Conference Paper]. UNDP International Poverty Centre. Auguest 29–31, 2005.

  • Thorbecke, E. (2007). Multidimensional poverty: Conceptual and measurement issues. In N. Kakwani & J. Silber (Eds.), The many dimensions of poverty. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tomer, J. F. (2002). Human well-being: A new approach based on overall and ordinary functionings. Review of Social Economy, 60(1), 23–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tomlinson, M., Walker, R., & Williams, G. (2008). Measuring poverty in Britain as a multidimensional concept, 1991 to 2003. Journal of Social Policy, 37(04), 597–620.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Townsend, P. (1979a). Introduction: Concepts of poverty and deprivation. In P. Townsend (Ed.), Poverty in the United Kingdom: a survey of household resources and standards of living (pp. 31–62). London: Penguin Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Townsend, P. (1979b). Poverty in the United Kingdom: A survey of household resources and standards of living. London: Penguin Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Townsend, P. (1985). A sociological approach to the measurement of poverty: A rejoinder to Professor Amartya Sen. Oxford Economic Papers, 37(4), 659–668.

    Google Scholar 

  • Valletta, R. G. (2006). The ins and outs of poverty in advanced economies: Government policy and poverty dynamics in Canada, Germany, Great Britain, and the United States. Review of Income and Wealth, 52(2), 261–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Buuren, S. (2012). Flexible imputation of missing data. Boca Raton, FL: CRC Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Veit-Wilson, J. (1987). Consensual approaches to poverty lines and social security. Journal of Social Policy, 16(02), 183–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Volkert, J. (2006). European union poverty assessment: A capability perspective. Journal of Human Development, 7(3), 359–383.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagle, U. (2005). Multidimensional poverty measurement with economic well-being, capability, and social inclusion: A case from Kathmandu, Nepal. Journal of Human Development, 6(3), 301–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagle, U. (2008). Multidimensional poverty measurement: Concepts and applications. New York: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, J., & Wang, X. (2012). Structural equation modeling: Applications using mplus. Chichester, UK: Higher Education Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Weinberg, D. H. (1991). Poverty dynamics and the poverty gap, 1984-86. The Journal of Human Resources, 26(3), 535–544.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Whelan, B. J. (1993a). Non-monetary Indicators of Poverty. In J. Berghman & B. Cantillon (Eds.), The European face of social security: Essays in honour of Herman Deleeck. Avebury: Brookfield, VT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Whelan, C. T. (1993b). The role of social support in mediating the psychological consequences of economic stress. Sociology of Health and Illness, 15(1), 86–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Whelan, B. J., & Whelan, C. T. (1995). In What Sense is Poverty Multidimensional? In G. Room (Ed.), Beyond the threshold: The measurement and analysis of social exclusion (pp. 29–48). Bristol: The Policy Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zheng, B. (1997). Aggregate poverty measures. Journal of Economic Surveys, 11(2), 123–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sung-Geun Kim.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Indicators for Each Dimension and their Measurement

Dimension

Name

Description

Economic resources

Household income

Financial situation

Annual household income for year 2005

Self-evaluation of personal financial situation

Healtht

Health status

Health status over last 12 months

Satisfaction with health

How satisfied with current health

Health inhibits activities

Whether health prohibits respondents from doing things they want to do

Employment

Permanent job

Current job status: permanent, temporary or no job

Job security satisfaction

How satisfied with job security

Overall job satisfaction

Overall, how satisfied with job

Housing

Lack of adequate heating

Y/N question

Leaky roof/Shortage of space Noise from neighbors

Street noise/Condensation Not enough light/Damp walls Rot in windows and floors

Y/N question

Durable goods

TV/VCR/Freezer/Washer Dishwasher/Microwave/Computer/CDP Phone/Cellphone/Internet/Cars

Y/N question

Social capital

Feed visitors once a month

Intention of feeding visitors once a month

Talking to neighbors

Frequency of talking to neighbors

Meeting people

Frequency of meeting people (friends or relatives) at home or elsewhere

Local group activities

Frequency of attending meetings for local groups/vol- untary organizations

Voluntary works

Frequency of doing unpaid voluntary work

Indicators

Measurement

Income

Eight-fold income bracket (based on 15, 30, 45, 60, 75, 90 percentiles)

Financial situation

1 (Very difficult)—5 (living comfortably)

Permanent job

1 (Contractual), 2(seasonal), 3 (permanent)

Job satisf. security

1 (Not satisfied at all)–7 (completely satisfied)

Job satisf. overall

1 (Not satisfied at all)–7 (completely satisfied)

Health status

1 (Very poor)–5 (excellent)

Satisf. health

1 (Not satisfied at all)–7 (completely satisfied)

Health inhibits activities

1 (Yes), 2 (no)

Feed visitors

1 (No), 2 (yes)

Talking to neighbors

1 (Never)–5 (on most days)

Meeting people

1 (Never)–5 (on most days)

Local group activities

1(Never)–5 (at least once a week)

Voluntary works

1(Never)–5 (at least once a week)

Housing

Average over 9 binary indicators

Durable goods

Average over 12 binary indicators

Appendix 2: Detailed Result for 1996

figure a

Unstandardized result

 

Estimate

S.E.

Est./S.E.

P value

Economic resources (econres)

 Income (econres1)

0.730

0.092

7.955

0.000

 Financial situation (econres2)

1.000

0.000

999.000

999.000

Employment (emp)

 Permanent job (emp1)

1.000

0.000

999.000

999.000

 Job satisfaction: security (emp2)

3.359

0.801

4.196

0.000

 Job satisfaction: overall (emp3)

3.135

0.712

4.401

0.000

 Health (health)

    

 Health status (health1)

1.000

0.000

999.000

999.000

 Satisfaction: health (health2)

0.833

0.016

50.555

0.000

 Health inhibits activities (health3)

0.905

0.017

53.598

0.000

Social capital (scapital)

 Feeding visitors (sc1)

1.000

0.000

999.000

999.000

 Local group acitvities (sc3)

2.081

0.312

6.678

0.000

 Voluntary works (sc4)

2.624

0.339

7.745

0.000

Well-being

 Durable goods (durablep)

1.000

0.000

999.000

999.000

 Housing (housep)

0.328

0.044

7.458

0.000

 Social Capital

1.000

0.000

999.000

999.000

 Economic resources

4.128

0.374

11.028

0.000

 Health

5.369

0.531

10.117

0.000

 Employment

0.617

0.167

3.699

0.000

Correlated variables

 Scapital with emp

−0.002

0.003

−0.560

0.576

 Sc3 with sc4

0.444

0.068

6.520

0.000

 Durablep with econres1

0.077

0.006

12.045

0.000

 Durablep with sc1

0.050

0.005

9.887

0.000

 Sc1 with econres2

0.187

0.021

9.016

0.000

 Sc1 with econres1

0.258

0.027

9.617

0.000

 Housep with econres2

0.022

0.003

8.410

0.000

 Health3 with econres1

0.211

0.029

7.188

0.000

Standardized result

 

Estimate

S.E.

Est./S.E.

P value

Economic resources (econrres)

 Income (econres1)

0.528

0.038

14.032

0.000

 Financial situation (econres2)

0.723

0.048

15.163

0.000

Employment (emp)

 Permanent job (emp1)

0.222

0.048

4.593

0.000

 Job satisfaction: security (emp2)

0.747

0.059

12.646

0.000

 Job satisfaction: overall (emp3)

0.698

0.057

12.274

0.000

Health (health)

 Health status (health1)

0.916

0.009

100.510

0.000

 Satisfaction: health (health2)

0.763

0.010

76.668

0.000

 Health inhibits activities (health3)

0.829

0.012

71.516

0.000

Social capital (scapital)

 Feeding visitors (sc1)

0.229

0.025

9.324

0.000

 Local group acitvities (sc3)0.476

0.069

6.922

0.000

 

 Voluntary works(sc4)

0.601

0.074

8.071

0.000

Well-being

 Durable goods (durablep)

0.402

0.025

16.319

0.000

 Housing (housep)

0.219

0.025

8.725

0.000

 Social capital

0.445

0.047

9.556

0.000

 Economic resources

0.582

0.042

13.800

0.000

 Health

0.597

0.034

17.768

0.000

 Employment

0.283

0.040

7.031

0.000

Correlated variables

 Scapital with emp

−0.041

0.073

−0.561

0.575

 Sc3 with sc4

0.631

0.038

16.643

0.000

 Durablep with econres1

0.390

0.026

14.781

0.000

 Durablep with sc1

0.222

0.022

10.089

0.000

 Sc1 with econres2

0.278

0.038

7.300

0.000

 Sc1 with econres1

0.312

0.033

9.399

0.000

 Housep with econres2

0.212

0.026

8.266

0.000

 Health3 with econres1

0.445

0.062

7.172

0.000

Correlation residual

 

Econres1

Econres2

Health1

Health2

Health3

Emp1

Emp2

Emp3

Sc1

Sc3

Sc4

Housep

Econres1

            

Econres2

0.000

           

Health1

0.068

0.001

          

Health2

−0.017

0.017

0.001

         

Health3

0.000

−0.052

−0.008

0.009

        

Emp1

0.098

0.076

−0.004

−0.003

0.003

       

Emp2

−0.093

0.007

−0.005

0.087

−0.029

0.072

      

Emp3

−0.123

0.062

0.023

0.142

−0.078

−0.180

0.003

     

Sc1

0.000

0.000

0.091

0.073

0.126

0.030

0.006

0.038

    

Sc3

0.015

0.040

0.023

−0.055

−0.047

−0.083

−0.026

0.049

−0.004

   

Sc4

−0.046

−0.009

0.019

−0.044

0.018

−0.132

−0.031

0.021

0.003

0.000

  

Housep

0.005

0.000

−0.003

0.003

−0.011

0.019

0.007

0.005

0.020

0.008

−0.002

0.000

Durablep

0.000

0.006

−0.002

−0.022

0.029

0.023

−0.032

−0.031

0.000

−0.003

0.011

−0.001

Appendix 3: Unstandardized Factor Loadings

 

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

Income

0.730***

(0.092)

0.807***

(0.056)

0.738***

(0.056)

0.900***

(0.043)

0.680***

(0.047)

1.003***

(0.063)

0.978***

(0.041)

0.749***

(0.040)

0.723***

(0.034)

0.589***

(0.060)

0.689***

(0.041)

0.844***

(0.063)

1.231***

(0.084)

Financial situation

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

1.000

(0.000)

Permanent job

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

0.278***

(0.048)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

Job satisf.Security

3.359***

(0.801)

1.266***

(0.135)

5.065***

(0.935)

1.353***

(0.223)

9.012

(4.915)

2.756***

(0.395)

1.967***

(0.418)

5.203***

(1.220)

1.088***

(0.103)

1.000

(0.000)

3.025***

(0.537)

5.358**

(1.822)

2.911**

(0.839)

Job satisf.Overall

3.135***

(0.712)

1.759***

(0.128)

3.247***

(0.522)

0.242**

(0.076)

6.893

(4.020)

2.400***

(0.311)

0.348**

(0.118)

7.075***

(1.762)

1.566***

(0.101)

0.885***

(0.071)

3.237***

(0.588)

5.532**

(2.016)

3.717**

(1.111)

Health status

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

Satisf.Health

0.833***

(0.016)

0.887***

(0.010)

0.838***

(0.013)

0.819***

(0.010)

0.811***

(0.014)

 

0.821***

(0.008)

0.805***

(0.008)

0.796***

(0.018)

0.846***

(0.013)

0.846***

(0.014)

0.839***

(0.013)

0.831***

(0.019)

Health inhibits activities

0.905***

(0.017)

0.939***

(0.010)

0.901***

(0.013)

0.794***

(0.010)

0.866***

(0.015)

1.080***

(0.049)

0.932***

(0.009)

0.890***

(0.009)

0.527***

(0.015)

0.928***

(0.013)

0.910***

(0.014)

0.903***

(0.014)

0.938***

(0.019)

Feed visitors

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

 

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

Talking to neighbors

 

−0.009

(0.024)

0.752***

(0.133)

0.330***

(0.068)

0.629***

(0.126)

1.000

(0.000)

0.402***

(0.085)

0.839***

(0.133)

1.522***

(0.226)

0.578***

(0.124)

0.515***

(0.102)

0.430***

(0.109)

−0.008

(0.097)

Meeting people

 

0.224***

(0.063)

0.406***

(0.115)

−0.090

(0.068)

0.145

(0.107)

−0.273

(0.164)

−0.029

(0.082)

−0.229*

(0.113)

0.215

(0.148)

0.310**

(0.115)

0.430***

(0.099)

0.366***

(0.105)

0.362**

(0.109)

Local group activities

2.081***

(0.312)

0.157**

(0.053)

1.627***

(0.270)

2.168***

(0.185)

4.739***

(0.545)

2.628***

(0.330)

2.611***

(0.202)

2.670***

(0.281)

2.963***

(0.289)

1.868***

(0.297)

0.992***

(0.154)

1.299***

(0.227)

2.302***

(0.216)

Voluntary works

2.624***

(0.339)

0.162*

(0.064)

1.949***

(0.305)

1.203***

(0.150)

5.367***

(0.614)

1.397***

(0.397)

2.699***

(0.215)

1.062**

(0.317)

2.812***

(0.302)

1.176***

(0.229)

1.081***

(0.168)

0.949***

(0.208)

1.124***

(0.158)

Economic resources

4.128***

(0.374)

5.997***

(0.341)

4.488***

(0.632)

5.480***

(0.221)

15.127***

(2.021)

5.809***

(0.405)

6.959***

(0.320)

7.548***

(0.361)

11.826***

(0.647)

4.956***

(0.375)

4.767***

(0.279)

3.612***

(0.246)

2.835***

(0.222)

Employment

0.617***

(0.167)

2.191***

(0.218)

0.315***

(0.083)

1.296***

(0.216)

0.573

(0.331)

0.795***

(0.139)

1.652***

(0.360)

0.670***

(0.167)

3.474***

(0.307)

3.720***

(0.354)

0.549***

(0.108)

0.315**

(0.116)

0.533**

(0.162)

Health

5.369***

(0.531)

5.772***

(0.340)

2.202***

(0.374)

3.588***

(0.249)

9.397***

(1.309)

4.876***

(0.348)

6.529***

(0.300)

5.930***

(0.267)

7.491***

(0.378)

6.065***

(0.525)

3.086***

(0.191)

4.112***

(0.438)

3.859***

(0.232)

Social capital

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

Durable goods

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

Housing

0.328***

(0.044)

0.427***

(0.036)

0.645***

(0.054)

0.399***

(0.023)

0.920***

(0.128)

0.439***

(0.035)

0.437***

(0.029)

0.454***

(0.030)

0.788***

(0.044)

0.322***

0.036)

0.283***

(0.020)

0.229***

(0.024)

0.198***

(0.027)

  1. Standard errors in parenthesis
  2. *** p < 0.001; ** p < 0.01; * p < 0.05

Model fit statistics

Year

Sample size

χ2

D.F.

P value

CFIa

TLI

RMSEA

Testb

WRMRc

1996

4850

473.87

54

0.00

0.97

0.96

0.04

1.00

1.87

1997

11,193

1041.95

71

0.00

0.98

0.97

0.04

1.00

2.54

1998

10,906

823.11

72

0.00

0.98

0.96

0.03

1.00

2.26

1999

15,623

975.41

65

0.00

0.98

0.97

0.03

1.00

2.44

2000

15,603

548.00

68

0.00

0.98

0.97

0.02

1.00

1.86

2001

18,867

685.23

55

0.00

0.95

0.93

0.02

1.00

2.33

2002

16,597

893.57

66

0.00

0.99

0.98

0.03

1.00

2.32

2003

16,238

837.38

66

0.00

0.99

0.98

0.03

1.00

2.26

2004

15,791

685.50

66

0.00

0.99

0.98

0.02

1.00

2.05

2005

15,617

851.13

78

0.00

0.97

0.96

0.02

1.00

2.32

2006

15,392

859.47

77

0.00

0.97

0.96

0.03

1.00

2.33

2007

14,873

782.83

74

0.00

0.97

0.96

0.02

1.00

2.21

2008

7746

726.37

81

0.00

0.95

0.94

0.03

1.00

2.12

  1. aAccording to Hu and Bentler (1999) larger than .90 implies a good model fit
  2. bClose-fit test’, the probability of RMSEA < .05
  3. cWeighted root mean square residual

Appendix 4: Unstandardized Factor Loadings After Multiple Imputation

 

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

Income

0.656***

(0.095)

0.750***

(0.056)

0.674***

(0.060)

0.882***

(0.041)

0.637***

(0.034)

0.845***

(0.038)

0.854***

(0.061)

0.681***

(0.038)

0.691***

(0.035)

0.468***

(0.051)

0.667***

(0.044)

0.739***

(0.063)

0.945***

(0.056)

Financial situation

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

Permanent job

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

0.408***

(0.036)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

Job satisf. security

2.567***

(0.565)

1.222***

(0.134)

4.001***

(0.763)

2.032***

(0.538)

3.241***

(0.460)

1.902***

(0.098)

2.774

(1.617)

3.204***

(0.538)

1.143***

(0.118)

1.000

(0.000)

2.357***

(0.383)

3.064**

(0.881)

1.366***

(0.197)

Job satisf. overall

2.039***

(0.499)

1.589***

(0.126)

2.531***

(0.388)

0.892**

(0.273)

3.371***

(0.584)

1.468***

(0.101)

1.210

(0.881)

4.289***

(0.983)

1.523***

(0.087)

0.913***

(0.050)

2.766***

(0.500)

3.391**

(1.084)

1.536***

(0.288)

Health status

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

Satisf. health

0.852***

(0.018)

0.900***

(0.010)

0.846***

(0.014)

0.818***

(0.010)

0.823***

(0.009)

 

0.833***

(0.008)

0.820***

(0.009)

0.822***

(0.018)

0.854***

(0.013)

0.867***

(0.014)

0.853***

(0.013)

0.854***

(0.016)

Health inhibits activities

0.912***

(0.018)

0.943***

(0.010)

0.902***

(0.013)

0.790***

(0.010)

0.913***

(0.009)

1.053***

(0.032)

0.941***

(0.008)

0.900***

(0.010)

0.620***

(0.018)

0.928***

(0.013)

0.920***

(0.014)

0.911***

(0.015)

0.946***

(0.023)

Feed visitors

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

 

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

Talking to neighbors

 

−0.006

(0.092)

0.789***

(0.153)

0.416***

1.673**

(0.026)

(0.267)

(0.148)

0.573***

(0.081)

0.431***

0.499*

0.478**

(0.080)

0.108

1.000

(0.127)

(0.000)

(0.109)

0.450***

(0.149)

0.930**

(0.106)

Meeting people

 

0.242***

(0.065)

0.448**

(0.141)

−0.024

(0.079)

0.104

(0.072)

−0.378***

(0.120)

0.046***

(0.099)

−0.105***

(0.125)

0.378***

(0.179)

0.247***

(0.115)

0.405**

(0.123)

0.484***

(0.131)

0.105***

(0.111)

Local group activities

2.358***

(0.429)

0.158**

(0.055)

1.882***

(0.310)

2.524***

(0.224)

4.708***

(0.387)

2.474***

(0.229)

2.595***

(0.209)

2.422***

(0.307)

2.841***

(0.320)

2.135***

(0.294)

1.244***

(0.177)

1.283***

(0.285)

2.493***

(0.238)

Voluntary works

3.020***

(0.449)

0.175*

(0.069)

2.277***

(0.348)

1.403***

(0.176)

5.032***

(0.407)

1.477***

(0.285)

2.659***

(0.220)

1.100**

(0.332)

2.770***

(0.328)

1.368***

(0.253)

1.497***

(0.206)

0.959***

(0.247)

1.438***

(0.168)

Economic resources

5.008***

(0.606)

6.767***

(0.444)

6.911***

(1.021)

6.253***

(0.326)

14.796***

(1.647)

7.212***

(0.335)

7.398***

(0.382)

7.995***

(0.398)

11.709***

(0.772)

5.705***

(0.407)

4.695***

(0.331)

3.957***

(0.281)

3.689***

(0.314)

Employment

1.286**

(0.456)

2.750***

(0.266)

0.670*

(0.260)

1.456***

(0.351)

1.909***

(0.374)

1.473***

(0.114)

1.788*

(0.787)

1.441***

(0.303)

4.464***

(0.384)

3.767***

(0.311)

0.836***

(0.148)

0.863**

(0.274)

1.760***

(0.327)

Health

6.308***

(0.920)

6.285***

(0.401)

3.293***

(0.546)

4.933***

(0.411)

10.824***

(1.221)

5.176***

(0.217)

7.386***

(0.395)

6.709***

(0.400)

8.314***

(0.460)

5.646***

(0.420)

3.414***

(0.338)

5.573***

(0.655)

4.507***

(0.447)

Social capital

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

Durable goods

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

1.000

(0.000)

Housing

0.391***

(0.065)

0.460***

(0.042)

0.679***

(0.059)

0.481***

(0.029)

1.163***

(0.132)

0.552***

(0.025)

0.466***

(0.033)

0.450***

(0.031)

0.780***

(0.054)

0.376***

(0.036)

0.261***

(0.024)

0.242***

(0.029)

0.241***

(0.036)

  1. Standard errors in parenthesis
  2. *** p < 0.001; ** p < 0.01; * p < 0.05

Appendix 5: Standardized Factor Loadings after Multiple Imputation

 

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

Income

0.500***

(0.040)

0.504***

(0.023)

0.458***

(0.025)

0.567***

(0.016)

0.474***

(0.015)

0.570***

(0.015)

0.539**

(0.022)

0.476***

(0.016)

0.484***

(0.015)

0.372***

(0.024)

0.471***

(0.019)

0.473***

(0.025)

0.570***

(0.023)

Financial situation

0.764**

(0.056)

0.672***

(0.026)

0.679***

(0.032)

0.643***

(0.016)

0.744***

(0.020)

0.674***

(0.017)

0.632***

(0.023)

0.698***

(0.021)

0.701***

(0.020)

0.795***

(0.044)

0.707***

(0.027)

0.640***

(0.030)

0.604***

(0.025)

Permanent job

0.319**

(0.056)

0.510***

(0.040)

0.230***

(0.037)

0.451***

(0.061)

0.210***

(0.031)

0.423***

(0.021)

0.378***

(0.104)

0.192**

(0.035)

0.536***

(0.039)

0.308***

(0.025)

0.281***

(0.049)

0.235***

(0.059)

0.505***

(0.079)

Job satisf.Security

0.805***

(0.112)

0.621***

(0.026)

0.913***

(0.061)

0.900***

(0.119)

0.677***

(0.034)

0.803***

(0.023)

0.999**

(0.311)

0.607***

(0.027)

0.610***

(0.022)

0.756***

(0.021)

0.652***

(0.032)

0.692***

(0.035)

0.681***

(0.040)

Job satisf.Overall

0.636***

(0.084)

0.808***

(0.035)

0.579***

(0.045)

0.394***

(0.074)

0.702***

(0.031)

0.619***

(0.021)

0.430*

(0.204)

0.806***

(0.031)

0.815***

(0.031)

0.690***

(0.020)

0.763***

(0.036)

0.762***

(0.038)

0.760***

(0.045)

Health status

0.908***

(0.010)

0.887***

(0.005)

0.907***

(0.007)

0.912***

(0.006)

0.913***

(0.005)

0.856***

(0.013)

0.905***

(0.004)

0.925***

(0.005)

0.921***

(0.010)

0.899***

(0.007)

0.894***

(0.007)

0.912***

(0.007)

0.903***

(0.011)

Satisf.Health

0.774***

(0.011)

0.799***

(0.006)

0.767***

(0.008)

0.746***

(0.006)

0.751***

(0.006)

 

0.754***

(0.005)

0.758***

(0.006)

0.757***

(0.009)

0.767***

(0.008)

0.775***

(0.008)

0.778***

(0.007)

0.771***

(0.011)

Health inhibits activities

0.828***

(0.012)

0.837***

(0.007)

0.818***

(0.009)

0.721***

(0.007)

0.833***

(0.006)

0.902***

(0.014)

0.852***

(0.006)

0.832***

(0.006)

0.571***

(0.018)

0.834***

(0.009)

0.822***

(0.010)

0.831***

(0.010)

0.854***

(0.016)

Feed visitors

0.213***

(0.025)

0.747***

(0.103)

0.240***

(0.025)

0.267***

(0.017)

0.180***

(0.013)

0.193***

0.206***

(0.012)

0.217***

(0.020)

0.143***

(0.016)

0.288***

(0.028)

0.315***

(0.028)

0.340***

(0.039)

0.291***

(0.021)

Talking to neighbors

 

−0.004

(0.019)

0.190***

(0.030)

0.111***

(0.020)

0.090***

(0.012)

(0.017)

0.093***

(0.018)

0.202***

(0.028)

0.238***

(0.025)

0.165***

(0.032)

0.136***

(0.033)

0.163**

(0.047)

0.032

(0.031)

Meeting people

 

0.181***

(0.028)

0.107**

(0.031)

−0.006

(0.021)

0.019

(0.013)

−0.073**

(0.022)

0.009

(0.020)

−0.023

(0.027)

0.054*

(0.024)

0.071*

(0.032)

0.128**

(0.040)

0.165***

(0.041)

0.031

(0.032)

Local group activities

0.500***

(0.079)

0.118***

(0.031)

0.452***

(0.058)

0.673***

(0.043)

0.845***

(0.027)

0.477***

(0.043)

0.536***

(0.040)

0.525***

(0.054)

0.404***

(0.041)

0.615***

(0.061)

0.391***

(0.048)

0.435***

(0.075)

0.726***

(0.051)

Voluntary works

0.641***

(0.084)

0.130**

(0.042)

0.547***

(0.062)

0.374***

(0.039)

0.904***

(0.029)

0.285***

(0.052)

0.549***

(0.041)

0.239**

(0.070)

0.394***

(0.042)

0.394***

(0.060)

0.471***

(0.054)

0.326***

(0.074)

0.419***

(0.038)

Economic resources

0.572***

(0.049)

0.741***

(0.033)

0.773***

(0.052)

0.891***

(0.037)

0.801***

(0.030)

0.886***

(0.022)

0.812***

(0.023)

0.784***

(0.028)

0.860***

(0.029)

0.618***

(0.037)

0.859***

(0.036)

0.669***

(0.045)

0.781***

(0.043)

Employment

0.343***

(0.066)

0.397***

(0.021)

0.219***

(0.054)

0.294***

(0.038)

0.366***

(0.026)

0.289***

(0.021)

0.324***

(0.061)

0.511***

(0.024)

0.430***

(0.025)

0.429***

(0.022)

0.387***

(0.036)

0.392***

(0.033)

0.446***

(0.037)

Health

0.604***

(0.044)

0.522***

(0.022)

0.276***

(0.031)

0.495***

(0.021)

0.477***

(0.019)

0.501***

(0.013)

0.566***

(0.017)

0.497***

(0.016)

0.465***

(0.017)

0.540***

(0.021)

0.493***

(0.027)

0.659***

(0.037)

0.638***

(0.035)

Social capital

0.412***

(0.050)

0.099***

(0.014)

0.317***

(0.032)

0.344***

(0.022)

0.225***

(0.016)

0.430***

(0.039)

0.336***

(0.021)

0.316***

(0.028)

0.362***

(0.035)

0.299***

(0.029)

0.411***

(0.046)

0.318***

(0.041)

0.440***

(0.034)

Durable goods

0.375***

(0.033)

0.358***

(0.015)

0.339***

(0.032)

0.411***

(0.021)

0.205***

(0.021)

0.395***

(0.012)

0.346***

(0.012)

0.355***

(0.014)

0.270***

(0.014)

0.303***

(0.017)

0.426***

(0.026)

0.342***

(0.025)

0.412***

(0.021)

Housing

0.223***

(0.027)

0.217***

(0.017)

0.369***

(0.031)

0.230***

(0.012)

0.320***

(0.013)

0.311***

(0.011)

0.226***

(0.012)

0.233***

(0.014)

0.298***

(0.013)

0.246***

(0.020)

0.264***

(0.018)

0.195***

(0.022)

0.218***

(0.030)

  1. standard errors in parenthesis
  2. *** p < 0.001; ** p < 0.01; * p < 0.05

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kim, SG. What Have We Called as “Poverty”? A Multidimensional and Longitudinal Perspective. Soc Indic Res 129, 229–276 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-015-1101-8

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-015-1101-8

Keywords

Navigation