Skip to main content
Log in

Does trade credit play a signalling role? Some evidence from SMEs microdata

  • Published:
Small Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Using micro-data on small- and medium-sized enterprises, this paper empirically investigates the “signalling hypothesis” formulated on the role of trade credit (Biais and Gollier in Rev Financ Stud 10: 903–937, 1997; Burkart and Ellingsen in Am Econ Rev 94: 569–590, 2004). The research method adopted allows evaluation of the impact of suppliers’ credit on bank debt accounting for the strength (duration) of bank–firm relationships. Our main finding is that trade credit seems to have an information content for banks, especially when the latter do not dispose of adequate (soft) information on firms, which is likely the case at the beginning stages of bank–firm relationships. An implication of our results is that the availability of suppliers credit might be crucial to foster access to institutional funding for new firms entering the market. Our evidence also suggests that banks seem to consider suppliers a reliable source of information on firms’ financial conditions even after several years of lending relationships.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Suppliers would also have a “liquidation advantage” over banks, as the former would be more able, in case of firms’ default, to obtain a greater liquidation value from collateralized inputs (Fabbri and Menichini 2010). On this issue, see also Mian and Smith (1992), Petersen and Rajan (1997), Longhofer and Santos (2003), Frank and Maksimovic (2004), and Atanasova (2012).

  2. On a very close issue see Aktas et al. (2012).

  3. In Italy, like in other OECD countries, the weight of trade debt has been traditionally very important for firms in general (Rajan and Zingales 1995; Demirgüç-Kunt and Maksimovic 2001; Giannetti 2003; De Blasio 2005; Marotta 2005) and for SMEs in particular (De Socio 2010). As reported by De Socio (2010), in the years 2004–2007 trade credit accounted for 25 % of Italian SMEs total assets, compared to an average of 16.8 % for the main European countries. On the importance of trade credit for SMEs see also, among others, Mian and Smith (1992) and Biais and Gollier (1997).

  4. In the following we do not review the “non-financial” theories on trade credit, which provide explanations on the existence and use of suppliers credit based, for instance, on transaction costs minimization (e.g. Ferris 1981), price discrimination (e.g., Schwartz and Whitcomb 1979; Brennan et al. 1988; Mian and Smith 1992), product quality guarantees (e.g., Smith 1987; Lee and Stowe 1993; Long et al. 1993; Emery and Nayar 1998), inventory management (Bougheas et al. 2009), and long-term seller/customer relationships (e.g. Summers and Wilson 2002). We refer to Petersen and Rajan (1997), Ng et al. (1999) and Giannetti et al. (2008) for some reviews on trade credit theories.

  5. In the literature, the Meltzer’s (1960) hypothesis is often referred to as the redistributional view on trade credit.

  6. Some of the earliest contributions providing support to the Meltzer’s (1960) idea are from Brechling and Lipsey (1963), Jaffee and Modigliani (1969), Jaffee (1971), Herbst (1974), and Duca (1986).

  7. Empirical evidence that firms might use more trade credit as bank credit is unavailable emerges also from the cross-country study of Fisman and Love (2003), who use the data and the methodology of Rajan and Zingales (1998). For other cross-country analyses on the role of trade credit (during financial crises), see Love et al. (2007) and Coulibaly et al. (2012). Finally, for studies not supporting the substitution hypothesis we refer to Gertler and Gilchrist (1993), Eichenbaum (1994), and Oliner and Rudebush (1995, 1996).

  8. A similar conclusion is reached by Petersen and Rajan (1994, p. 32): “Clearly, our evidence that trade creditors lend when institutional lenders do not suggests that they have collateral, incentives related to the product they are selling, sources of leverage over the firm, or information that the institutions do not possess.” Petersen and Rajan (1997) also argue that suppliers appear to be more efficient (relative to banks) in liquidating firms’ collateral goods, as vendors may take advantage of their customers’ network to resell, at lower cost, the assets of a defaulted buyer. Furthermore, by lending to credit constrained firms, suppliers can invest in customers relationships aiming at taking advantage of future profitable projects.

  9. Finally, the model offers an interpretation of some stylized facts, such as the heterogeneity of trade credit patterns among countries and across time. For instance, where creditors’ rights are better protected, cash tends to be less diverted, hence trade credit should tend to be less employed, as shown by Demirgüç-Kunt and Maksimovic (2001).

  10. Even though public firms are more transparent than small private firms, Saito and Bandeira (2010) reach a similar conclusion considering Brazilian public companies. Indeed, according to their study, trade credit seems to signal a firm’s good quality, facilitating access to bank credit for public firms. Thus, the reputation hypothesis appears confirmed.

  11. A more dated work, seeking evidence on both the substitution and complementariness hypotheses, is that of Alphonse et al. (2006, unpublished manuscript entitled, When trade credit facilitates access to bank finance: Evidence from US small business data). The authors argue that both hypotheses are verifiable as they apply to different classes of small firms. On one hand, firms that need to acquire reputation on the credit market may use trade credit as a signal of good quality. On the other, firms with established reputation do not need to exploit the informational content of trade credit. Consistently with such considerations, Alphonse et al. found that trade credit seems complementary to bank financing only for firms with a short banking relationship, whereas it appears as substituting bank's loans for the others.

  12. Besides, their model predicts that in most cases, the substitution effect is counter-cyclical, being larger during slow-growth periods than during rapid-growth periods. Using a balanced panel data of listed Chinese companies, and addressing problems of endogeneity, the authors find strong evidence in favor of both the substitution and the counter-cyclicality hypotheses.

  13. Nevertheless, one cannot exclude that banks may still observe the signal conveyed by trade credit even after many years of continuous relation. This could be because, besides the informational advantage mentioned above, suppliers may have more incentives to monitor the financial situation of the firm, since customer concentration is likely higher in the case of suppliers than in the case of banks. Banks could be aware of the aforementioned circumstances and keep trying to take advantage of sellers’ information.

  14. For other analyses concerning the duration of bank relationships see Degryse and Van Cayseele (2000); Lehmann and Neuberger (2001); Ongena and Smith (2001).

  15. As argued by an anonymous referee, the amount of short-term debt used by firms does not necessarily correspond with the debt granted by banks, which, mirroring the firm's creditworthiness, represents the amount likely to be influenced by the trade credit signal. Lacking information on the amount granted, used bank debt can be considered a good proxy for granted debt if their ratio tends to be constant. However, even though the amount of debt granted remains unchanged, bank debt used may vary (together with trade credit) because of an expansion (or contraction) of working capital, and the consequent variation in the firm’s financing need. Analogously, the variation in the average number of days that customers employ to pay invoices (ΔDAYSREC) may affect both trade and bank debt. Indeed, banks and suppliers may consider an increase in days receivables as a negative signal on firms' customer's quality and/or on its credit policy, jeopardizing firm’s creditworthiness. On the other hand, it has to be recognized that an increase in days receivables can imply liquidity problems, resulting in a higher demand of credit. Thus, in our analysis, the sign of this regressor remains an open empirical question.

  16. As a large body of research indicates (e.g., Petersen and Rajan 1995b; Bonaccorsi di Patti and Gobbi 2001), SME's bank financing relies essentially on local credit markets, which in Italy—according to the National Antitrust Authority—corresponds to the existing administrative provinces.

  17. This procedure controls for unobserved heterogeneity by adopting a fixed effects model. Thus, the unobserved components are allowed to be correlated with the explanatory variables. Moreover, the idiosyncratic errors may have serial dependence of unspecified form. In our test, the selection and main equations include the same control variables with the exception of (the log of) population, and the tax incentives dummy (equal to 1 if firms received tax incentives and 0 otherwise). These latter variables are assumed to affect only the selection process, and their exclusion from the main equation allows us to better identify the model. Besides, when we test this assumption by including them in both equations, their estimated coefficients are never statistically significant in the main equation.

  18. That is as variables potentially correlated with past values of the idiosyncratic error, but not correlated to its present and future values.

  19. Moreover, to focus on firms less open in terms of financial information, and therefore more dependent on bank and trade credit, we drop those listed on the Stock Exchange. However, in Sect. 5.1, as a sensitivity check, we re-estimated Eq. (1) without operating this exclusion.

  20. The reason why, in employing this criterion, we considered entry at the end of 2000—instead of entry at the end of each survey—is that in some cases the values of DURAT observed at the end of the three trienniums appeared to be inconsistent. When the 2000 record was missing, we considered the 2003 entry as the base-value, while—when both 2000 and 2003 figures were missing—the 2006 value was employed as the reference point. In all cases, when the value of DURAT became negative, we treated the observation as missing.

  21. As illustrated below, the estimates of Table 3 are obtained by using all available instruments, except in column 3, where, by modifying this choice, we check the robustness of our findings to the set of instruments employed.

  22. Incidentally, in column 2, many control variables appear statistically significant, with signs generally consistent with those expected. For instance, SIZE, PLEDGEASS, ΔWORKCAP and GROWTH are positively related with BANKDEBT, while CASHFLOW, RESERVE and BOND display a negative sign.

  23. Such a discrepancy between individual and joint significance is usually interpreted as a symptom of multicollinearity (see Brambor et al. 2006) induced by the inclusion of an interaction term. As Brambor et al. (2006, p. 70) highlight, “even if there really is high multicollinearity and this leads to large standard errors on the model parameters, it is important to remember that these standard errors are never in any sense ‘too’ large, they are always the ‘correct’ standard errors. High multicollinearity simply means that there is not enough information in the data to estimate the model parameters accurately and the standard errors rightfully reflect this”.

  24. To be precise, in column 3, when considering endogenous regressors, lags 2 through 4 of the levels are used as instruments for the transformed data, and lag 1 of the differences is used for the levels data. When dealing with predetermined variables, lags 1 through 4 of the levels are employed as instruments for the transformed data, and lag 0 of the instrumenting variable in differences is employed for the levels data. Exogenous variables instrument themselves.

  25. By including this proxy we take into account that the use of both bank and trade debt is dependent on the constraints faced by firms on the credit market. In particular, according to the substitution hypothesis, credit-constrained firms tend to use more trade credit than others. Incidentally, the Unicredit surveys provide information also on another indicator of credit rationing, a dummy coded 1 if a firm demanded more credit than it actually obtained, and zero otherwise. However, since this variable is defined only for firms that replied yes to the question used to code RAT, it is available for 2,210 observations of our sample, while the proxy we employ is defined on 14,277 observations.

  26. When this was not the case, the imputation was not carried out. Since we acknowledge that the imputation above described may cause measurement errors, while the criterion followed for DURAT (described in Sect. 3) appears logical, we prefer to omit MAIN and NBAN in our main equation, and use DURAT as proxy for the strength of bank-firm relationships in Eq. (1). For the same reason we omit RAT from the benchmark model, and use it, together with MAIN and NBAN, to carry out the robustness check we are discussing.

  27. For contributions on the role of trade credit during financial crises see, for instance, Love et al. (2007), Yang (2011b), and Bastos and Pindado (2012).

References

  • Agostino, M., Gagliardi, F., & Trivieri, F. (2011). Bank competition, lending relationships and firms’ default risk. An investigation on Italian SMEs. International Small Business Journal. doi:10.1177/0266242611416681.

  • Agostino, M., & Trivieri, F. (2010). Is banking competition beneficial to SMEs? An empirical study based on Italian data. Small Business Economics, 35, 335–355.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aktas, N., de Bodt, E., Lobez, F., & Statnik, J. C. (2012). The information content of trade credit. Journal of Banking & Finance, 36, 1402–1413.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Almeida, H., & Campello, M. (2007). Financial constraints, asset tangibility, and corporate investment. Review of Financial Studies, 20(5), 1429–1460.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altonji, J., & Segal, L. (1994). Small sample bias in GMM estimation of covariance structures. NBER Working Paper, 156.

  • Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies, 58, 277–297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, M., & Bover, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error components models. Journal of Econometrics, 68, 29–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atanasova, C. (2007). Access to institutional finance and the use of trade credit. Financial Management, 36(1), 49–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atanasova, C. (2012). How do firms choose between intermediary and supplier finance. Financial Management, Spring, pp 207–228.

  • Atanasova, C., & Wilson, N. (2004). Disequilibrium in the UK corporate loan market. Journal of Banking & Finance, 28, 595–614.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bastos, R., & Pindado, J. (2012). Trade credit during a financial crisis: A panel data analysis. Journal of Business Research. doi:10.1016/j.jbusres.2012.03.015.

  • Beck, T., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & Maksimovic, V. (2002). Financing patterns around the world: The role of institutions. World Bank Policy Research, Working Paper 2905.

  • Benfratello, L., Schiantarelli, F., & Sembenelli, A. (2008). Banks and innovation: Microeconometric evidence on Italian firms. Journal of Financial Economics, 90, 197–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, A. N., Rosen, R., & Udell, G. F. (2007). Does market size structure affect competition? The case of small business lending. Journal of Banking & Finance, 31, 11–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, A. N., & Udell, G. F. (1995). Relationship lending and lines of credit in small firm finance. Journal of Business, 68(3), 351–381.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, A. N., & Udell, G. F. (2002). Small business credit availability and relationship lending: The importance of bank organizational structure. Economic Journal, 112(477), F32–F53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, A. N., & Udell, G. F. (2006). A more complete conceptual framework for SME finance. Journal of Banking & Finance, 30(11), 2945–2966.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biais, B., & Gollier, C. (1997). Trade credit and credit rationing. Review of Financial Studies, 10, 903–937.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blackwell, D. W., & Winters, D. B. (1997). Banking relationships and the effect of monitoring on loan pricing. Journal of Financial Research, 20, 275–289.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87, 115–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonaccorsi di Patti, E., & Gobbi, G. (2001). The changing structure of local credit markets: Are small businesses special? Journal of Banking & Finance, 25, 2209–2237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bond, S., Temple, J., & Hoeffler, A. (2001) GMM estimation of empirical growth models. Economics Papers, 21, Nuffield College, University of Oxford.

  • Boot, A. W. A. (2000). Relationship banking: What do we know? Journal of Financial Intermediation, 9(1), 7–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boot, A., & Thakor, A. V. (1994). Moral hazard and secured lending in an infinitely repeated credit market game. International Economic Review, 35, 899–920.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bougheas, S., Mateut, S., & Mizen, P. (2009). Corporate trade credit and inventories: New evidence of a trade-off from accounts payable and receivable. Journal of Banking & Finance, 33, 300–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brambor, T., Clarck, W., & Golder, M. (2006). Understanding interaction models: Improving empirical analyses. Political Analysis, 14, 63–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brechling, F., & Lipsey, R. (1963). Trade credit and monetary policy. Economic Journal, 73(4), 618–641.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, M., Maksimovic, V., & Zechner, J. (1988). Vendor financing. Journal of Finance, 43, 1127–1141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burkart, M., & Ellingsen, T. (2004). In-kind finance: A theory of trade credit. American Economic Review, 94, 569–590.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, W. G., & Kim, Y. (2005). Trade credit and the effect of macro-financial shocks: Evidence from U.S. panel data. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 40(4), 897–925.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cole, R. A. (1998). The importance of relationships to the availability of credit. Journal of Banking & Finance, 22(6–8), 959–977.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cole, R. A., Goldberg, L. G., & White, L. J. (2004). Cookie-cutter versus character: The micro structure of small business lending by large and small banks. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 39(2), 227–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cook, L. D. (1999). Trade credit and bank finance: financing small firms in Russia. Journal of Business Venturing, 14, 493–518.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coulibaly, B., Sapriza, H., & Zlate, A. (2012). Financial frictions, trade credit, and the 2008–09 global financial crisis. International Review of Economics and Finance. doi10.1016/j.iref.2012.08.006.

  • Cunat, V. (2007). Trade credit: Suppliers as debt collectors and insurance providers. Review of Financial Studies, 20(2), 491–527.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D’Auria, C., Foglia, A., & Marullo Reedtz, P. (1999). Bank interest rate and credit relationships in Italy. Journal of Banking & Finance, 23, 1067–1093.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Danielson, M. G., & Scott, J. A. (2004). Bank loan availability and trade credit demand. Financial Review, 39, 579–600.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Blasio, G. (2005). Does trade credit substitute for bank credit? Evidence from firm level data. Economic Notes, 34(1), 85–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Socio, A. (2010). La situazione economico-finanziaria delle imprese italiane nel confronto internazionale. Occasional Papers, Bank of Italy, Rome.

  • Degryse, H., & Van Cayseele, P. (2000). Relationship lending within a bank-based system: Evidence from European small business data. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 9, 90–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & Maksimovic, V. (2001). Firms as financial intermediaries: Evidence from trade credit data. World Bank Working Paper 2696.

  • Diamond, D. (1984). Financial intermediation and delegated monitoring. Review of Economic Studies, 51, 393–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duca, J. (1986). Trade credit and credit rationing: a theoretical model. Washington, DC: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eichenbaum, M. (1994). Comment. In N. G. Mankiw (Ed.), Monetary policy (pp. 256–261). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elsas, R., & Krahnen, J. (1998). Is relationship lending special? Evidence from credit-file data in Germany. Journal of Banking & Finance, 22(10–11), 1283–1316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Emery, G. W. (1984). A pure financial explanation for trade credit. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 19, 271–285.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Emery, G., & Nayar, N. (1998). Product quality and payment policy. Review of Finance and Accounting, 10, 269–284.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fabbri, D., & Menichini, A. M. C. (2010). Trade credit, collateral liquidation, and borrowing constraints. Journal of Financial Economics, 96, 413–432.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferris, J. S. (1981). A transaction theory of trade credit use. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 96, 247–270.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisman, R., & Love, I. (2003). Trade credit, financial intermediary development, and industry growth. Journal of Finance, 58, 353–734.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank, M. Z., & Maksimovic, V. (2004). Trade credit, collateral and adverse selection. University of Maryland Working Paper.

  • Freixas, X. (1993). Short-term credit versus accounts receivable financing. Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Economics, Working Paper 27.

  • Gale, D., & Hellwig, M. (1985). The incentive compatible debt contract: The one period problem. Review of Economic Studies, 52, 647–663.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gambini, A., & Zazzaro, A. (2011). Long-lasting bank relationships and growth of firms. Small Business Economics. doi:10.1007/s11187-011-9406-8.

  • Garcia-Appendini, M. E. (2011). Supplier certification and trade credit. Bocconi University-IGIER, Working Paper series.

  • Gertler, M., & Gilchrist, S. (1993). The role of credit market imperfections in the monetary transmission mechanism: Arguments and evidence. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 95(1), 43–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giannetti, M. (2003). Do better institutions mitigate agency problems? Evidence from corporate finance choices. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 38(1), 185–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giannetti, M., Burkart, M., & Ellingsen, T. (2008). What you sell is what you lend? Explaining trade credit contract. Review of Financial Studies, 24, 1261–1298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guariglia, A., & Mateut, S. (2006). Credit channel, trade credit channel, and inventory investment: evidence from a panel of UK firms. Journal of Banking & Finance, 30, 2835–2856.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, G., Hutchinson, P., & Michaelas, N. (2000). Industry effects on the determinants of unquoted SMEs’ capital structure. International Journal of the Economics of Business, 7(3), 297–312.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harhoff, D., & Korting, T. (1998). Lending relationships in Germany: Empirical results from survey data. Journal of Banking & Finance, 22(10–11), 1317–1354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris, M., & Raviv, A. (1991). The theory of capital structure. Journal of Finance, 46, 297–355.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J. (1979). Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica, 47(1), 153–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herbst, A. F. (1974). Some empirical evidence on the determinants of trade credit at the industry level of aggregation. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 9(3), 377–394.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hori, K., & Osano, H. (2002). Financial relationships between banks and firms: New evidence from Japanese data. Kyoto Institute of Economic Research, Discussion Paper 546.

  • Huang, H., Shi, X., & Zhang, S. (2011). Counter-cyclical substitution between trade credit and bank credit. Journal of Banking & Finance, 35(8), 1859–1878.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaffee, D. M. (1971). Credit rationing and the commercial loan market. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffee, D. M., & Modigliani, F. (1969). A theory and test of credit rationing. American Economic Review, 59(5), 850–872.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jain, N. (2001). Monitoring costs and trade credit. Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 41, 89–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, Y. W., & Stowe, J. D. (1993). Product risk, asymmetric information, and trade credit. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 28, 285–300.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lehmann, E., & Neuberger, D. (2001). Do lending relationships matter? Evidence from bank survey data in Germany. Journal of Economic Behaviour & Organization, 45, 339–359.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Long, M. S., Malitz, I. B., & Ravid, S. A. (1993). Trade credit, quality guarantees, and product marketability. Financial Management, 22, 117–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Longhofer, S., & Santos, J. A. C. (2003). The paradox of priority. Financial Management, 32, 69–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Love, I., Preve, L. A., & Sarria-Allende, V. (2007). Trade credit and bank credit: Evidence from recent financial crises. Journal of Financial Economics, 83, 453–469.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marotta, G. (2005). When do trade credit discounts matter? Evidence from Italian firm-level data. Applied Economics, 37, 403–416.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mateut, S., Bougheas, S., & Mizen, P. (2006). Trade credit, bank lending and monetary policy transmission. European Economic Review, 50, 603–629.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matias Gama, A. P., & Mateus, C. (2010). Does trade credit facilitate access to bank finance? An empirical evidence from Portuguese and Spanish small medium size enterprises. International Research Journal of Finance and Economics, 45, 26–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer, A. H. (1960). Mercantile credit, monetary policy, and the size of firms. Review of Economics and Statistics, 42, 429–437.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mian, S. L., & Smith, C. W. (1992). Accounts receivable management policy: Theory and evidence. Journal of Finance, 47, 169–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mian, S. L., & Smith, C. W. (1994). Extending trade credit and financing receivables. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 7(1), 75–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Michaelas, N., Chittenden, F., & Poutziouris, P. (1999). Financial policy and capital structure choice in U.K. SMEs: Empirical evidence from company panel data. Small Business Economics, 12, 113–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miwa, Y., & Ramseyer, J. M. (2008). The implications of trade credit for bank monitoring: Suggestive evidence from Japan. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 17(2), 317–343.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ng, C. K., Smith, J. K., & Smith, R. L. (1999). Evidence on the determinants of credit terms used in interfirm trade. Journal of Finance, 54, 1109–1129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nilsen, J. (2002). Trade credit and the bank lending channel. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 34, 226–253.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ogawa, K., Sterken, E., & Tokutsu, I. (2011). The trade credit channel revisited: evidence from micro data of Japanese small firms. Small Business Economics. doi:10.1007/s11187-011-9344-5.

  • Oliner, S., & Rudebush, G. (1995). Is there a bank lending channel for monetary policy? Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic Review, 2, 3–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oliner, S., & Rudebush, G. (1996). Monetary policy and credit constraints: Evidence from the composition of external finance: Comment. American Economic Review, 86(1), 300–309.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ongena, S., & Smith, D. C. (2001). The duration of bank relationships. Journal of Financial Economics, 61(3), 449–475.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Petersen, M. A., & Rajan, R. G. (1994). The benefits of firm-creditor relationships: Evidence from small business data. Journal of Finance, 49(1), 3–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Petersen, M. A., & Rajan, R. G. (1995a). Trade credit: Theories and evidence. Mimeo: University of Chicago.

    Google Scholar 

  • Petersen, M. A., & Rajan, R. G. (1995b). The effect of credit market competition on lending relationships. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(2), 407–443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Petersen, M. A., & Rajan, R. G. (1997). Trade credit: Theories and evidence. The Review of Financial Studies, 10, 661–691.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rajan, R. G. (1992). Insiders and outsiders: The choice between informed and arm’s-length debt. Journal of Finance, 47(4), 1367–1399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rajan, R. G., & Zingales, L. (1995). What do we know about capital structure? Some evidence from international data. Journal of Finance, 50, 1421–1460.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rajan, R., & Zingales, L. (1998). Financial dependence and growth. American Economic Review, 88, 559–586.

    Google Scholar 

  • Repullo, R., & Suarez, J. (2000). Entrepreneurial moral hazard and bank monitoring: A model of the credit channel. European Economic Review, 44, 1931–1950.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roodman, D. (2006). How to do xtabond2: An introduction to “difference” and “system” GMM in stata. Center for Global Development, Working Paper 103.

  • Saito, R., & Bandeira, M. L. (2010). Empirical evidence of trade credit uses of Brazilian publicly listed companies. Brazilian Administration Review, 7(3), 242–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, R. A. (1974). An economic model of trade credit. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 9, 643–657.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, R. A., & Whitcomb, D. (1978). Implicit transfers in the extension of trade credit. In K. E. Boulding & T. F. Wilson (Eds.), The channels of redistribution through the financial system (pp. 191–208). New York: Praeger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, R. A., & Whitcomb, D. (1979). The trade credit decision. In J. L. Bicksler (Ed.), Handbook of financial economics (pp. 257–273). Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sharpe, S. A. (1990). Asymmetric information, bank lending, and implicit contracts: A stylized model of customer relationships. Journal of Finance, 45(4), 1069–1087.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, J. K. (1987). Trade credit and informational asymmetry. Journal of Finance, 42, 863–872.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stein, J. C. (2002). Information production and capital allocation: Decentralized versus hierarchical firms. Journal of Finance, 57(5), 1891–1921.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Summers, B., & Wilson, N. (2002). Trade credit terms offered by small firms: survey evidence and empirical analysis. Journal of Business and Finance Accounting, 29, 317–335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Titman, S., & Wessels, R. (1988). The determinants of capital structure. Journal of Finance, 43(2), 1–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsuruta, D. (2008). Bank information monopoly and trade credit: Do only banks have information of small businesses? Applied Economics, 40, 981–996.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Valderrama, M. (2003). The role of trade credit and bank lending relationships in the transmission mechanism in Austria. In I. Angeloni, A. Kashyap, & B. Mojon (Eds.), Monetary policy transmission in the Euro Area. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van der Wijst, N., & Thurik, R. (1993). Determinants of small firm debt ratios: An analysis of retail panel data. Small Business Economics, 5, 55–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Von Thadden, E. L. (2004). Asymmetric information, bank lending and implicit contracts: The winner’s curse. Finance Research Letters, 1(1), 11–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilner, B. (2000). The exploitation of relationships in financial distress: The case of trade credit. Journal of Finance, 55, 153–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Windmeijer, F. (2005). A finite sample correction for the variance of linear efficient two-step GMM estimators. Journal of Econometrics, 126, 25–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge, J. (1995). Selection corrections for panel data models under conditional mean independence assumptions. Journal of Econometrics, 68, 115–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, X. (2011a). Trade credit versus bank credit: Evidence from corporate inventory financing. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 51, 419–434.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, X. (2011b). The role of trade credit in the recent subprime financial crisis. Journal of Economics and Business, 63, 517–529.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are indebted to two anonymous reviewers for their valuable comments and suggestions. We also wish to thank Domenico Scalera and Damiano Silipo for helpful discussions, and the Associate Editor Enrico Santarelli. We remain responsible for any errors or omissions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Francesco Trivieri.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Agostino, M., Trivieri, F. Does trade credit play a signalling role? Some evidence from SMEs microdata. Small Bus Econ 42, 131–151 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-013-9478-8

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-013-9478-8

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation