Skip to main content
Log in

On the value and determinants of the interest tax shields

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We use a dynamic model of the firm to ascertain both the value and the determinants of the debt tax shields. For a representative U.S. firm, we find that the value of the interest tax shields represents less than 5 % of firm value, and it varies considerably across U.S. industries. Our results also show that this component of firm value behaves counter-cyclically over the business cycle. Finally, besides the interest rate on debt and the corporate income tax rate, we find that the curvature of the production function is one of the main determinants of the tax advantage of debt.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In related papers, van Binsbergen et al. (2010) and Korteweg (2010) report that the net benefits of debt account for 3.5 and 5.5 % of firm value, respectively.

  2. Cordes and Sheffrin (1983) also suggest that the tax benefits of debt vary considerably across industries.

  3. See, e.g., Ackerberg et al. (2007), and the references therein.

  4. The list of important papers in this literature is vast, including, but not limited to, Harris and Raviv (1991), Shyam-Sunder and Myers (1999), Hovakimian et al. (2001), Graham and Harvey (2001), Fama and French (2002), Flannery and Rangan (2006), Lemmon et al. (2008), Frank and Goyal (2009), Moosa and Li (2012), and Sarkar (2014).

  5. Lazzati and Menichini (2015a) show that these assumptions about debt produce leverage predictions that are in line with several important findings reported by the literature on capital structure, such as the negative relation between profitability and leverage, as well as the existence of zero-debt firms and their observed characteristics.

  6. This factor is used in a required normalization of growing variables that we describe in Appendix 1.

  7. With a Cobb-Douglass specification of the production function, parameter \(\alpha\) represents the output elasticity of capital, and it thereby relates to the share of total output attributable to this input factor. It is well-documented in the economics literature that some industries are more capital intensive than others—e.g., telecommunications, airlines, and drilling operations. Variations of \(\alpha\) across industries follow from this observation.

  8. In addition, Lazzati and Menichini (2015c) describe how to decompose the stock price in its fundamental components: the book value of equity plus the future excess profits stemming from current assets, real options, and long-run growth.

  9. Graham (2000) computes the interest tax shields assuming profits follow a random walk, and divides them by the market value of the firm (which we suppose is determined by the market assuming mean-reverting profits). For that reason, we vary the interest tax shields while we keep firm value constant.

  10. Koziol (2014) suggests an alternative way to introduce default risk and bankruptcy costs to the model of the firm.

  11. Similar to Moyen (2004) and Hennessy and Whited (2007), we assume that bond-holders are risk-neutral.

  12. To avoid negative interest rates in the simulations, we use the following equation

    $$\begin{aligned} r_{B_{t}}=\max \left[ 0,r_{B_{t-1}}+\kappa \left( \theta -r_{B_{t-1}}\right) +\sigma _{r}\sqrt{r_{B_{t-1}}}\epsilon _{t}\right] . \end{aligned}$$
    (24)
  13. In untabulated results, we find that all our other results are very similar in both cases.

  14. The same result is true if we define risk-free debt using the market value of equity as opposed to the book value of equity. That is, in both cases we arrive at Eq. (25) as the maximum level of book leverage consistent with risk-free debt. To simplify notation, we use the book value of equity.

  15. The restriction \(\left( f+\delta \right) \left( 1-\tau \right) \le 1\) described in Sect. 2 also guarantees that \(\ell ^{*}\ge 0\) .

  16. This is a standard procedure in the empirical economics literature (see, e.g., Balistreri, McDaniel, and Wong 2003; Fox and Smeets 2011; Young 2013).

  17. This normalization is common in the corporate finance literature. See, e.g., Moyen (2004), Hennessy and Whited (2005, 2007), and DeAngelo et al. (2011).

References

  • Ackerberg DA, Benkard CL, Berry S, Pakes A (2007) Econometric tools for analyzing market outcomes. Handb Economet 6A:4171–4276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aït-Sahalia Y (2002) Maximum likelihood estimation of discretely sampled diffusions: a closed-form approximation approach. Econometrica 70:223–262

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altinkilic O, Hansen RS (2000) Are there economies of scale in underwriting fees? evidence of rising external financing costs. Rev Financ Stud 13:191–218

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andrade G, Kaplan SN (1998) How costly is financial (not economic) distress? evidence from highly leveraged transactions that became distressed. J Finance 53:1443–1493

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balistreri EJ, McDaniel CA, Wong EV (2003) An estimation of US industry-level capital-labor substitution elasticities: support for Cobb-Douglas. N Am J Econ Financ 14:343–356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhamra HS, Lars-Alexander K, Strebulaev IA (2010) The aggregate dynamics of capital structure and macroeconomic risk. Rev Financ Stud 23:4187–4241

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blouin J, Core JE, Guay W (2010) Have the tax benefits of debt been overestimated? J Financ Econ 98:195–213

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradley M, Jarrell GA, Kim EH (1984) On the existence of an optimal capital structure: theory and evidence. J Finance 39:857–878

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown LD (1993) Earnings forecasting research: its implications for capital markets research. Int J Forecast 9:295–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cordes JJ, Sheffrin SM (1983) Estimating the tax advantage of corporate debt. J Finance 38:95–105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper IA, Davydenko SA (2007) Estimating the cost of risky debt. J App Corp Finance 19:90–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox JC, Ingersoll JE, Ross SA (1985) A theory of the term structure of interest rates. Econometrica 53:385–407

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeAngelo H, DeAngelo L, Whited TM (2011) Capital structure dynamics and transitory debt. J Financ Econ 99:235–261

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeAngelo H, Masulis RW (1980) Optimal capital structure under corporate and personal taxation. J Financ Econ 8:3–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durham GB, Gallant AR (2002) Numerical techniques for maximum likelihood estimation of continuous-time diffusion processes. J Bus Econ Stat 20:297–316

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF, French KR (1997) Industry costs of equity. J Financ Econ 43:153–193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF, French KR (2002) Testing trade-off and pecking order predictions about dividends and debt. Rev Financ Stud 15:1–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flannery MJ, Rangan KP (2006) Partial adjustment toward target capital structure. J Financ Econ 79:469–506

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fox JT, Smeets V (2011) Does input quality drive measured differences in firm productivity? Int Econ Rev 52:961–989

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank MZ, Goyal VK (2009) Capital structure decisions: Which factors are reliably important? Financ Manage 38:1–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman RN, Ohlson JA, Penman SH (1982) Book rate-of-return and prediction of earnings changes: An empirical investigation. J Account Res 20:639–653

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon MJ (1962) The savings investment and valuation of a corporation. Rev Econ Stat 44:37–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham JR (2000) How big are the tax benefits of debt? J Finance 55:1901–1941

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham JR, Harvey CR (2001) The theory and practice of corporate finance: evidence from the field. J Financ Econ 60:187–243

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris M, Raviv A (1991) The theory of capital structure. J Finance 46:297–355

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayn C (1995) The information content of losses. J Account Econ 20:125–153

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hennessy CA, Whited TM (2005) Debt dynamics. J Finance 60:1129–1165

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hennessy CA, Whited TM (2007) How costly is external financing? Evidence from a structural estimation. J Finance 62:1705–1745

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hodrick RJ, Prescott EC (1997) Postwar U.S. business cycles: an empirical investigation. J Money Credit Bank 29:1–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hovakimian A, Opler T, Titman S (2001) The debt-equity choice. J Financ Quant Anal 36:1–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hull J, White A (1990) Valuing derivative securities using the explicit finite difference method. J Financ Quant Anal 25:87–100

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson DW, Stiroh KJ (2000) U.S. economic growth at the industry level. Am Econ Rev 90:161–167

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan SN, Stein JC (1990) How risky is the debt in highly leveraged transactions? J Financ Econ 27:215–245

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King RG, Watson MW (1996) Money, prices, interest rates and the business cycle. Rev Econ Stat 78:35–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Korajczyk RA, Levy A (2003) Capital structure choice: macroeconomic conditions and financial constraints. J Financ Econ 68:75–109

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Korteweg A (2010) The net benefits to leverage. J Finance 65:2137–2170

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koziol C (2014) A simple correction of the WACC discount rate for default risk and bankruptcy costs. Rev Quant Financ Acc 42:653–666

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lazzati N, Menichini AA (2015a) A dynamic model of the firm: structural explanations of key empirical findings. Financ Rev 50:341–361

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lazzati N, Menichini AA (2015b) Dynamic model of firm valuation: A new methodology and its empirical validity. Working Paper, University of California Santa Cruz

  • Lazzati N, Menichini AA (2015c) A dynamic approach to the dividend discount model. Rev Pac Basin Financ Mark Pol 18:1–36

    Google Scholar 

  • Leland HE (1994) Corporate debt value, bond covenants, and optimal capital structure. J Finance 49:1213–1252

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lemmon ML, Roberts MR, Zender JF (2008) Back to the beginning: persistence and the cross-section of corporate capital structure. J Finance 63:1575–1608

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lipe R, Kormendi R (1994) Mean reversion in annual earnings and its implications for security valuation. Rev Quant Financ Account 4:27–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Long MS, Malitz IB (1985) Investment patterns and financial leverage. In: Friedman BJ (ed) Corporate capital structures in the United States. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 325–352

    Google Scholar 

  • Longstaff FA, Schwartz ES (1992) Interest Rate Volatility and the term structure: a two-factor general equilibrium model. J Finance 47:1259–1282

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani F, Miller MH (1958) The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment. Am Econ Rev 48:261–297

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani F, Miller MH (1963) Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital: a correction. Am Econ Rev 53:433–443

    Google Scholar 

  • Moosa I, Li L (2012) Firm-specific factors as determinants of capital structure: evidence from Indonesia. Rev Pac Basin Finan Mark Pol 15:1–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moyen N (2004) Investment-cash flow sensitivities: constrained versus unconstrained firms. J Finance 59:2061–2092

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myers SC (1974) Interactions of corporate financing and investment decisions-implications for capital budgeting. J Finance 29:1–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pearson ND, Sun TS (1994) Exploiting the conditional density in estimating the term structure: an application to the Cox, Ingersoll, and Ross model. J Finance 49:1279–1304

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rajan RG, Zingales L (1995) What do we know about capital structure? some evidence from international data. J Finance 50:1421–1460

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramakrishnan RTS, Thomas JK (1998) Valuation of permanent, transitory, and price-irrelevant components of reported earnings. J Account Audit Financ 13:301–336

    Google Scholar 

  • Sarkar S (2014) Valuation of tax loss carryforwards. Rev Quant Financ Account 43:803–828

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shyam-Sunder L, Myers SC (1999) Testing static tradeoff against pecking order models of capital structure. J Financ Econ 51:219–244

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Titman S, Wessels R (1988) The determinants of capital structure choice. J Finance 43:1–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Binsbergen JH, Graham JR, Yang J (2010) The cost of debt. J Finance 65:2089–2136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young AT (2013) U.S. elasticities of substitution and factor augmentation at the industry level. Macroecon Dyn 17:861–897

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Amilcar A. Menichini.

Additional information

I thank Natalia Lazzati for her helpful comments.

Appendices

Appendix 1: proofs

The proof of Proposition 1 requires an intermediate result that we present next.

Lemma 2

Restricting debt to be risk-free, the maximum level of book leverage in each period is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \ell ^{*}=\frac{1-\left( f+\delta \right) \left( 1-\tau \right) }{ 1+r_{B}\left( 1-\tau \right) }. \end{aligned}$$
(25)

Proof

We say debt is risk-free if, in every period, the following inequality is true for all \(z^{\prime }\)

$$\begin{aligned} \left( z^{\prime }K^{\prime ^{\alpha }}-fK^{\prime }-\delta K^{\prime }-r_{B}\ell K^{\prime }\right) \left( 1-\tau \right) +K^{\prime }-\ell K^{\prime }\ge 0. \end{aligned}$$
(26)

That is, risk-free debt implies that next-period, after-shock book value of equity must be weakly positive for all \(z^{\prime }\).Footnote 14 In other words, net profits, \(\left( z^{\prime }K^{\prime ^{\alpha }}-fK^{\prime }-\delta K^{\prime }-r_{B}\ell K^{\prime }\right) \left( 1-\tau \right)\), plus the value of assets, \(K^{\prime }\), must be sufficient to cover debt, \(\ell K^{\prime }\).

Given that the worst-case scenario is \(z^{\prime }=0\), the maximum book leverage ratio consistent with risk-free debt, \(\ell ^{*}\), satisfies

$$\begin{aligned} \left( -fK^{\prime }-\delta K^{\prime }-r_{B}\ell ^{*}K^{\prime }\right) \left( 1-\tau \right) +K^{\prime }-\ell ^{*}K^{\prime }=0. \end{aligned}$$
(27)

Working on the previous expression, we can derive the maximum level of book leverage as

$$\begin{aligned} \ell ^{*}=\frac{1-\left( f+\delta \right) \left( 1-\tau \right) }{1+r_{B}\left( 1-\tau \right) } \end{aligned}$$
(28)

which completes the proof.Footnote 15 \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 1

The maximization in Eq. (4) requires a normalization of growing variables that keeps the expectation of the payoff function in the future periods bounded. This normalization is equivalent to the one used to find the solution of the canonical Gordon Growth Model. Let vector \(\widetilde{X}_{t}=\left\{ \widetilde{K}_{t},\widetilde{B}_{t}, \widetilde{N}_{t},\widetilde{L}_{t},\widetilde{S}_{t}\right\} \) contain the growing variables of the model. We then transform vector \(\widetilde{X}_{t}\) in the following way: \(X_{t}=\widetilde{X}_{t}/(1+g)^{t}\). Using the normalized variables and modifying the payoff function accordingly, the market value of equity can be expressed as

$$\begin{aligned} S_{0}\left( K_{0},B_{0},z_{0}\right) =\max _{\left\{ K_{t+1},B_{t+1}\right\} _{t=0}^{\infty }}E_{0}\sum \limits _{t=0}^{\infty }\frac{\left( 1+g\right) ^{t}}{\prod \nolimits _{j=0}^{t}\left( 1+r_{S_{j}}\right) }L_{t} \end{aligned}$$
(29)

subject to keeping debt risk-free. Because we use the Adjusted Present Value method of firm valuation, we solve the problem of the firm in Eq. (29) in three steps. First, we determine the value of the unlevered firm, \(S_{u_{0}}\left( K_{0},z_{0}\right)\). Second, we solve for optimal debt and compute the present value of the financing side effects. Finally, we obtain the value of the levered firm in Eq. (29).

The market value of equity for the unlevered firm can be expressed as

$$\begin{aligned} S_{u_{0}}\left( K_{0},z_{0}\right) =\max _{\left\{ K_{t+1}\right\} _{t=0}^{\infty }}E_{0}\sum \limits _{t=0}^{\infty }\left( \frac{1+g}{1+r_{A}}\right) ^{t}L_{u_{t}} \end{aligned}$$
(30)

where \(L_{u_{t}}=N_{u_{t}}-\left( K_{t+1}-K_{t}\right)\) and \(N_{u_{t}}=\left( z_{t}K_{t}^{\alpha }-fK_{t}-\delta K_{t}\right) \left( 1-\tau \right)\). We let normalized variables with primes indicate values in the next period and normalized variables with no primes denote current values. Then, the Bellman equation for the problem of the firm in Eq. (30) is given by

$$\begin{aligned} S_{u}\left( K,z\right) =\underset{K^{\prime }}{\max }\left\{ \left( zK^{\alpha }-fK-\delta K\right) \left( 1-\tau \right) -\left( 1+g\right) K^{\prime }+K+\frac{\left( 1+g\right) }{\left( 1+r_{A}\right) }E\left[ S_{u}\left( K^{\prime },z^{\prime }\right) |z\right] \right\} . \end{aligned}$$
(31)

We use the guess and verify method as the proof strategy. Thus, we start by guessing that the solution is given by

$$\begin{aligned} S_{u}\left( K,z\right) =\left( zK^{\alpha }-fK-\delta K\right) \left( 1-\tau \right) +K+M\left( z\right) P_{u}^{*} \end{aligned}$$
(32)

where

$$\begin{aligned} M\left( z\right)= & {} e^{-\frac{1}{2}\sigma ^{2}\frac{\alpha }{\left( 1-\alpha \right) ^{2}}}\sum _{n=1}^{\infty }\left\{ \left( \frac{1+g}{1+r_{A}}\right) ^{n}\left( c^{\frac{1-\rho ^{n}}{1-\rho }}z^{\rho ^{n}}e^{\frac{1}{2}\sigma ^{2}\frac{\left( 1-\rho ^{2n}\right) }{\left( 1-\rho ^{2}\right) }\frac{1}{\left( 1-\alpha \right) }}\right) ^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha }}\right\} , \end{aligned}$$
(33)
$$\begin{aligned} P_{u}^{*}= & {} \left( W^{*^{\alpha }}-fW^{*}-\delta W^{*}\right) \left( 1-\tau \right) -r_{A}W^{*}, \end{aligned}$$
(34)
$$\begin{aligned} W^{*}= & {} \left( \frac{\alpha }{\frac{r_{A}}{1-\tau }+f+\delta }\right) ^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha }}. \end{aligned}$$
(35)

We obtained this initial guess as the solution of Eq. (31) by the backward induction method.

We now verify our guess. To this end, let us write

$$\begin{aligned} S_{u}\left( K,z\right) =\underset{K^{\prime }}{\max }\left\{ F\left( K^{\prime },K,z\right) \right\} \end{aligned}$$
(36)

with F defined as the objective function in Eq. (31).

The FOC for this problem is

$$\begin{aligned} \partial F\left( K^{\prime },K,z\right) /\partial K^{\prime }=-\left( 1+g\right) +\frac{\left( 1+g\right) }{\left( 1+r_{A}\right) }\left[ \left( E \left[ z^{\prime }|z\right] \alpha K^{*\alpha -1}-f-\delta \right) \left( 1-\tau \right) +1\right] =0 \end{aligned}$$
(37)

and optimal capital turns out to be

$$\begin{aligned} K^{*}=E\left[ z^{\prime }|z\right] ^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha }}W^{*} \end{aligned}$$
(38)

where \(W^{*}\) is as in Eq. (35).

Finally, the market value of equity for the unlevered firm becomes

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{ll} S_{u}(K,z) &{}=\left( zK^{\alpha }-fK-\delta K\right) ( 1-\tau ) -( 1+g) K^{*}+K \\ &{}\quad +\,\frac{\left( 1+g\right) }{\left( 1+r_{A}\right) }\left[ \left( E\left[ z^{\prime }|z\right] K^{*\alpha }-fK^{*}-\delta K^{*}\right) \left( 1-\tau \right) +K^{*}\right. \\ &{}\quad +\,\left. E\left[ M\left( z^{\prime }\right) |z\right] P_{u}^{*}\right] \\ &{}=\left( zK^{\alpha }-fK-\delta K\right) \left( 1-\tau \right) +K-\left( 1+g\right) E\left[ z^{\prime }|z\right] ^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha }}W^{*} \\ &{}\quad +\,\frac{\left( 1+g\right) }{\left( 1+r_{A}\right) }\left\{ E\left[ z^{\prime }|z\right] ^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha }}\left[ \left( W^{*^{\alpha }}-fW^{*}-\delta W^{*}\right) \left( 1-\tau \right) +W^{*}\right] \right. \\ &{}\quad +\,\left. E\left[ M\left( z^{\prime }\right) |z\right] P_{u}^{*}\right\} \\ &{}=\left( zK^{\alpha }-fK-\delta K\right) \left( 1-\tau \right) +K \\ &{}\quad +\,\frac{\left( 1+g\right) }{\left( 1+r_{A}\right) }\left( e^{-\frac{1}{2}\sigma ^{2}\frac{\alpha }{\left( 1-\alpha \right) ^{2}}}E\left[ z^{\prime \frac{1}{1-\alpha }}|z\right] +E\left[ M\left( z^{\prime }\right) |z\right] \right) P_{u}^{*} \\ &{}=\left( zK^{\alpha }-fK-\delta K\right) \left( 1-\tau \right) +K+M\left( z\right) P_{u}^{*} \end{array} \end{aligned}$$
(39)

which is equivalent to our initial guess in Eq. (32).

Next, we obtain optimal debt. In each period, the firm solves the following problem

$$\begin{aligned} B^{*}=\max _{B^{\prime }}\left\{ B^{\prime }-\frac{1}{\left( 1+r_{B}\right) }B^{\prime }\left[ 1+r_{B}\left( 1-\tau \right) \right] \right\} \end{aligned}$$
(40)

subject to the restriction of risk-free debt. Because \(\tau >0\), the firm increases debt as much as possible (as long as it remains risk-free) to maximize the tax benefits of debt. Then, optimal debt is \(B^{*}=\ell ^{*}K^{*}\) where

$$\begin{aligned} \ell ^{*}=\frac{1-\left( f+\delta \right) \left( 1-\tau \right) }{ 1+r_{B}\left( 1-\tau \right) }, \end{aligned}$$
(41)

as shown in Lemma 2. The present value of the financing side effects turns out to be

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{l} Q\left( z\right) =\left( \frac{1+g}{1+r_{A}}\right) \left\{ \left( \frac{ 1+r_{A}}{1+r_{B}}\right) r_{B}\tau B^{*}+E\left[ Q\left( z^{\prime }\right) |z\right] \right\} \\\qquad\; =M\left( z\right) \left( \frac{1+r_{A}}{1+r_{B}}\right) r_{B}\tau \ell ^{*}W^{*} \end{array} \end{aligned}$$
(42)

where \(M\left( z\right)\) is as in Eq. (33). Under this financial policy, the amount of debt and interest payments will vary with the future asset cash flows (i.e., they depend on future firm performance). Then, because future interest tax shields will have a level of risk in line with that of the firm cash flows, we use the cost of capital, \(r_{A}\), as the discount rate.

The third step consists in obtaining the market value of equity for the levered firm. If we assume the firm used debt B in the previous period, and now has to pay interest \(r_{B}B\left( 1-\tau \right)\), then the stock price for the levered firm is

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{ll} S\left( K,B,z\right) &{}=S_{u}\left( K,z\right) +M\left( z\right) \left( \frac{ 1+r_{A}}{1+r_{B}}\right) r_{B}\tau \ell ^{*}W^{*}-B-r_{B}B\left( 1-\tau \right) \\ \quad &{}=\left( zK^{\alpha }-fK-\delta K-r_{B}B\right) \left( 1-\tau \right) +K-B+M\left( z\right) P^{*} \end{array} \end{aligned}$$
(43)

where variable \(P^{*}\) takes the form

$$\begin{aligned} P^{*}=\left( W^{*^{\alpha }}-fW^{*}-\delta W^{*}\right) \left( 1-\tau \right) -r_{A}W^{*}+\left( \frac{1+r_{A}}{1+r_{B}}\right) r_{B}\tau \ell ^{*}W^{*}. \end{aligned}$$
(44)

The last part of the proof consists in transforming normalized variables back into growing variables. For this step, we return to the initial notation with growing variables, where next-period assets are \(\widetilde{K}_{t+1}\) and current-period assets are \(\widetilde{K}_{t}\). Then, the required transformation is: \(\widetilde{X}_{t}=(1+g)^{t}X_{t}\), where vector \(X_{t}=\left\{ K_{t},B_{t},N_{t},L_{t},S_{t}\right\}\) contains the normalized variables of the model. Finally, the optimal decisions of the firm with growing variables are given by

$$\begin{aligned} \widetilde{K}_{t+1}^{*}\left( z_{t}\right) =\left( 1+g\right) ^{t+1}E \left[ z_{t+1}|z_{t}\right] ^{\frac{1}{1-\alpha }}W^{*}\text { and }\widetilde{B}_{t+1}^{*}\left( z_{t}\right) =\ell ^{*}\widetilde{K} _{t+1}^{*}\left( z_{t}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(45)

and the growing market value of equity is

$$\begin{aligned} \widetilde{S}_{t}\left( \widetilde{K}_{t},\widetilde{B}_{t},z_{t}\right) = \left[ \left( 1+g\right) ^{t\left( 1-\alpha \right) }z_{t}\widetilde{K} _{t}^{\alpha }-f\widetilde{K}_{t}-\delta \widetilde{K}_{t}-r_{B}\widetilde{B} _{t}\right] \left( 1-\tau \right) +\widetilde{K}_{t}-\widetilde{B}_{t}+ \widetilde{M}_{t}\left( z_{t}\right) P^{*} \end{aligned}$$
(46)

as shown in Proposition 1. \(\square\)

Appendix 2: calibration of model parameters

We need to find parameter values for \(c,\rho ,\sigma ,\alpha ,f,\delta ,\tau ,r_{B},r_{A},\) and g for a representative firm in the U.S. and for each SIC industry at the division level. We do the calibration of model parameters using Compustat annual data. We exclude financial firms (i.e., SIC codes between 6000 and 6999) as well as public administration organizations (i.e., SIC codes greater than 9000). The sample covers the period 1990–2015 and includes a total of 58,596 firm-year observations. For the representative firm in the U.S. we use all firms in the sample while for the representative firm in each industry we use only the firms in the corresponding industry.

In order to obtain parameter \(\delta\), we average the ratio Depreciation and Amortization (DP)/Assets \(-\) Total (AT) for all firm-years. We follow the same procedure to get \(\tau\) as the fraction Income Taxes \(-\) Total (TXT)/Pretax Income (PI). We trim these ratios at the lower and upper one-percentiles to reduce the effect of outliers and errors in the data. We calibrate parameter f so that optimal book leverage, \(\ell ^{*}\), matches the median value of book leverage observed in the sample.

Following Moyen (2004), we obtain parameters \(\rho ,\sigma ,\) and \(\alpha\) using the firm’s autoregressive profit shock process of Eq. (1) and the gross profits function in Eq. (2), \(\widetilde{G}_{t}=\left( 1+g\right) ^{t\left( 1-\alpha \right) }z_{t}\widetilde{K}_{t}^{\alpha }\). The data we use with these equations are Gross Profit (GP) and Assets \(-\) Total (AT). We first log-linearize the gross profits function and obtain parameter \(\alpha\) by doing an OLS regression.Footnote 16 We then use the error term from that regression with the firm’s autoregressive profit shock process to obtain parameters \(\rho\) and \(\sigma\).

Given that we are interested in evaluating representative firms, we normalize parameter c to 1.Footnote 17 We assume that the market cost of debt \(r_{B}\) is 0.06, which is consistent with the empirical evidence on the cost of debt (e.g., Kaplan and Stein 1990; Cooper and Davydenko 2007). We derive \(r_{A}\) using CAPM with the corresponding (unlevered) industry betas estimated by Fama and French (1997) and assuming an expected market return \(\left( r_{M}\right)\) of 0.08. Finally, we obtain g for each industry following Jorgenson and Stiroh (2000).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Menichini, A.A. On the value and determinants of the interest tax shields. Rev Quant Finan Acc 48, 725–748 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-016-0566-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-016-0566-0

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation