Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Measuring the evolution of Korea’s material living standards 1980–2012

  • Published:
Journal of Productivity Analysis Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Based on a production-theoretic framework, we measure the effects of real output prices, primary inputs, and multi-factor productivity growth on Korea’s real income growth over the past 30 years. The empirical analysis is based on a new dataset for Korea with detailed information on labor and capital inputs, including series on land and inventories assets. We find that while over the entire period, capital and labor inputs explain the bulk of Korean real income growth, productivity growth has come to play an increasingly important role since the mid-1990s, providing some evidence of a transition from ‘input-led’ to ‘productivity-led’ growth. Terms of trade and other price effects were modest over the longer period, but had significant real income effects over sub-periods.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For a broader discussion on the merits and shortcomings of GDP as a measure of welfare, see Stiglitz et al. (2009).

  2. Another step is to consider national rather than domestic income. Some of the income generated by residents is paid to non-residents, while residents receive some income from production in other countries. Domestic income can thus be augmented by the income flows received and reduced by the income flows leaving the country to arrive at the concept of national income, which is more relevant for the material well-being of residents of a country. For the majority of OECD countries there is little difference between the levels of GDP and GNI. There are however exceptions, most notably Ireland and Luxembourg; differences are also likely to be significant for many developing and emerging countries characterised by a significant presence of multinational enterprises in their territory (whose profits are then transferred abroad) and of immigrants working abroad (who transfer part of their income to their country of origin in the form of remittances). In the mid-1980s and late-1990s, Korean GDP was about 1 % smaller than GNI and the gap became smaller in later years. The present analysis therefore only deals with GDP and the associated income flows.

  3. We shall follow the convention in the System of National Accounts and use real in the sense that a value has been expressed in equivalents of consumption units by deflating it with a price index of private consumption. Real values do not necessarily correspond to quantities. For example, there are no quantities and prices making up flows of nominal income. We shall use volume to designate the quantity component that, along with a price component, makes up the value of an economic transaction. Volumes are in particular relevant in the computation of productivity, the ratio of the volume of outputs to the volume of inputs. The theory of productivity measurement is based on production functions or production possibility frontiers as in Jorgenson (1966).

  4. As pointed out by one of the referees, as the production-theoretic approach used here assumes that all imports are intermediate products and exports are distinct from final goods and services intended for domestic use, the price of domestic absorption can be viewed as the price of nontradables, whereas the price of imports and exports is the price of tradables. This facilitates the identification of terms of trade and real exchange rate effects.

  5. One standard method is to compute a nominal rate of return, given depreciation and asset price changes—see Jorgenson and Landefeld (2006). We compute a ‘balancing real rate of return’ following Diewert et al. (2009).

  6. The GDP function was introduced by Samuelson (1953). Alternative presentations include in particular Diewert’s (1973) variable profit function and McFadden’s (1978) restricted profit function.

  7. Note that \((\partial {\text{g}}/\partial {\text{t}})/{\text{g}} = (\partial ({\text{G}}/{\text{P}}_{\text{C}} )/\partial {\text{t}})/{\text{g}} = (\partial {\text{G}}/\partial {\text{t}})/{\text{gP}}_{\text{C}} = \uppi\) and \(\partial {\text{g}}/\partial {\text{p}}_{\text{i}} = \partial {\text{G}}/\partial {\text{P}}_{\text{i}}\).

  8. Below, we shall further break down trading gains into a terms of trade effect and a real exchange rate effect.

  9. It is of course possible to compute the real income contribution of sub-items of private final consumption expenditure as real prices of these sub-components may change over time. However, the sum of contributions of these sub-items will always equal zero if index numbers have been computed consistently.

  10. While output data is already available by industry and institutional sector, capital input data has not yet been compiled at this level. This has been scheduled by the Bank of Korea for 2014 in accordance with 2008 SNA. The dataset underlying the present analysis is available on demand. It will also be posted on the BOK’s website in 2014 as part of the revised set of national accounts.

  11. See http://ecos.bok.or.kr/EIndex_en.jsp for national accounts data. The BOK uses a chain Laspeyres index in the construction of its volume measures.

  12. As with expression (10), the theoretical measure of volume output growth, \({\text{d}}\ln {\text{q}}/{\text{dt}} = \sum\limits_{{{\text{i}} = {\text{C}},{\text{GV}},{\text{I}},{\text{X}},{\text{M}}}} {\frac{{{\text{P}}_{\text{i}} {\text{q}}_{\text{i}} }}{{{\text{P}} \cdot {\text{q}}}}} {\text{d}}\ln {\text{q}}_{\text{i}} /{\text{dt}}\) has been approximated by averaging two discrete measures of output growth, ∆lnq tP  ≡ ln(Pt·qt) − ln(Pt·qt−1) and ∆lnq tL  ≡ ln(Pt−1·qt) − ln(Pt−1·qt−1). Making use of the nominal relationship Pt·qt = ∑i P ti q ti , approximating ∆lnq tP and ∆lnq tL with a first-order Taylor series, and taking averages, one obtains the Törnqvist index of output growth used for our calculations.

  13. For more details on the KIP database, visit www.kpc.or.kr/eng or http://asiaklems.net.

  14. The KIP database provides data on labour and capital inputs as well as on productivity growth. Only labour measures are used here, however, whereas capital input measures rely on new data that is directly compatible with Korea’s national balance sheets and national accounts.

  15. This issue has been raised in Diewert et al. (2009), in the case of Japan, especially for land. Similar patterns for land prices have prevailed in Korea and would lead to negative user costs of land for a number of periods if the observed revaluation term were used in the user cost equation.

  16. For an industry-level examination of user costs and rates of return in Korea, see Pyo et al. (2009).

  17. Changes in land value estimates are the most significant departure from Cho et al. (2012). In previous work, land value estimates were based on the publicly appraised value of land which has been extrapolated backward with a rate of land price indexes, whereas in the current work land values reflect (approximately) market prices. This change resulted in a significantly higher value of land since the mid-1990s and a significantly lower value before that time.

  18. For the entire period at hand, this figure seems to confirm the East Asian miracle as ‘input-led’ growth, as argued by Krugman (1994), Young (1994) and Lau and Kim (1994). If we focus on more recent years, however, the observation would be different.

  19. Hahn and Ryu (2010) identify factors that are external, rather than internal to Korea as the main reasons for the decline in terms of trade during this period. In particular, they observe that China’s trade expansion raised import prices for oil and raw materials while lowering the export prices of manufactured products.

  20. 2012 seems to mark a departure from this trend but it was mentioned earlier that labour input growth figures for 2012 are preliminary and may be revised.

  21. It remains open how the eventual implementation of the 2008 SNA with its capitalisation of R&D expenditure and military assets will bear on the results. Some caution is also in place with regard to the period 2009–2012 because of the preliminary nature of labour and capital input data.

References

  • Bank of Korea (2011) Korean system of national accounts—concepts, sources and methods. The Bank of Korea, Seoul

    Google Scholar 

  • Cho T, Kim J, Schreyer P (2012) Measuring the evolution of Korea’s material living standards 1980–2010. OECD StatisticsWorking papers, 2012/02. OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5k9bdcd29b5d-en

  • Diewert WE (1973) Functional forms for profit and transformation functions. J Econ Theory 6:284–316

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert WE (1974) Intertemporal consumer theory and demand for durables. Econometrica 42:497–516

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert WE, Lawrence D (2006) Measuring the contributions of productivity and terms of trade to Australia’s economic welfare. Report by Meyrick and Associates to the Productivity Commission, Canberra

  • Diewert WE, Morrison CJ (1986) Adjusting output and productivity indexes for changes in the terms of trade. Econ J 96:659–679

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert WE, Mizobuchi H, Nomura K (2009) On measuring the productivity and the standard of living in Japan, 1955-2006. KEO discussion paper no. 115

  • Hahn CH, Ryu S (2010) Causes of the decline of terms of trade in Korea since the mid-1990s (in Korean). KDI J Econ Policy 32(3). Korean Development Institute

  • Hall RE, Jorgenson DW (1967) Tax policy and investment behavior. Am Econ Rev 91(3):341–414

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamada K, Iwata (1984) National income, terms of trade and economic welfare. Econ J 94:752–771

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hulten CH, Schreyer P (2010) GDP, technical change, and the measurement of net income: the Weitzman model revisited. NBER working paper no 16010

  • Jorgenson DW (1963) Capital theory and investment behavior. Am Econ Rev 53(2):247–259

    Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson DW (1966) The embodiment hypothesis. J Polit Econ 74(1):1–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jorgenson DW, Landefeld JS (2006) Blueprint for expanded and integrated US accounts: review, assessment, and next steps. In Jorgenson L, Nordhaus (eds) A new architecture for the US national accounts. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 13–112

  • Kohli U (1990) Growth accounting in the open economy: parametric and nonparametric estimates. J Econ Soc Meas 16:125–136

    Google Scholar 

  • Kohli U (2004) Real GDP, real domestic income and terms of trade changes. J Int Econ 62:83–106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kohli U (2006) Real GDP, real GDI, and trading gains: Canada, 1981–2005. Int Prod Monit 13:46–56

    Google Scholar 

  • Kohli U (2007) Terms-of-trade changes, real GDP, and real value added in the open economy: reassessing Hong Kong’s growth performance. Asia Pac J Account Econ 14:87–109

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kohli U, Werner A (1998) Accounting for South Korean GDP growth: index-number and econometric estimates. Pac Econ Rev 3(2):133–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1994) The myth of Asia’s miracle. Foreign affairs. November/December

  • Lau LJ, Kim J-I (1994) The sources of growth of East Asian newly industrialized countries. J Jpn Int Econ 8:235–271

  • McFadden D (1978) Cost, revenue and profit functions. In: Fuss M, McFadden D (eds) Production economics: a dual approach to theory and applications, vol 1. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 3–109

    Google Scholar 

  • Morrison CJ, Diewert WE (1990) Productivity growth and changes in the terms of trade in Japan and the United States. Productivity growth in Japan and the United States. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 201–227

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2008) Economic Survey of Korea 2008. Paris

  • OECD (2009) Measuring capital—OECD manual, 2nd edn. OECD, Paris

  • OECD (2010) Economic Survey of Korea 2010. Paris

  • Pyo HK, Nam K (2001) Chapter 3 international comparison of rates of capital and test of convergence theorem. The limit and potential in growth of the Korean Economy, Korea Economic Research Institute, August

  • Pyo HK, Chun H, Rhee KH (2008) Total factor productivity by 72 industries in Korea and international comparison (1970–2005). BOK working papers no. 324. Economic Research Institute, The Bank of Korea

  • Pyo HK, Kim W, Jeon E (2009) The estimation of user costs by industries in Korea (1970–2006). Korea Institute of Public Finance

  • Samuelson PA (1953) Prices of factors and goods in general equilibrium. Rev Econ Stud 2(1):1–20

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schreyer P (2010) Measuring multi-factor productivity when rates of return are exogenous. In: Diewert WE, Balk BM, Fixler D, Fox KJ, Nakamura AO (eds) Price and productivity measurement, vols 1 and 2. Trafford Press

  • Sefton JA, Weale MR (2006) The concept of income in a general equilibrium. Rev Econ Stud 73:219–249

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz J, Sen A, Fitoussi J-P (2009) Report by the commission on the measurement of economic performance and social progress. http://www.stiglitz-sen-fitoussi.fr/documents/rapport_anglais.pdf

  • Weitzman ML (1976) On the welfare significance of national product in a dynamic economy. Q J Econ 90:156–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young A (1994) Lessons from the East Asian NICs: a contrarian view. European economic review papers and proceedings

Download references

Acknowledgments

Views expressed in this document are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Bank of Korea, the OECD or its Member countries. Financial and in-kind support by the Bank of Korea to this work is acknowledged. The authors are grateful to Seung-Hee Koh for excellent research assistance provided during the project and thank participants in the 2012 EMG Workshop in Sydney, Australia, for helpful comments. Very helpful comments and suggestions from two anonymous referees are gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Paul Schreyer.

Appendix

Appendix

See Tables 3 and 4.

Table 3 Sensitivity of results to choice of remuneration rates of self-employed persons
Table 4 Fixed asset types, service lives and DBRs used for a geometric approach

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Cho, T., Kim, J. & Schreyer, P. Measuring the evolution of Korea’s material living standards 1980–2012. J Prod Anal 44, 157–173 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-014-0404-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-014-0404-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation