Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Third-person Effect and Financial Contagion in the Context of a Global Game

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper we present a psychological channel of financial contagion. We incorporate this new channel of financial contagion in the global game. Our basic assumption is that agents are overestimating the influence of negative messages they ascribe to others, and are thus acting on the basis of this perception. We resort to the psychological studies on the so-called third-person effect to justify this assumption. We show that the third-person effect is rationalizable. Our model has the feature that a crisis in a foreign country can be transmitted to the domestic country, even though there has been no changes in domestic fundamentals. Our model also provides intuitive explanations to the empirical observations that many governments have lost in a confidence game in the past crisis episodes.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Corsetti et al. (2002, 2004) conclude that available evidence from empirical studies concerning the role of large traders is quite controversial. There is no consensus on the question of whether the manipulative trading practices of large traders played a key role in the 1997 Asian financial crisis.

  2. A recent example is the stock market contagion across the globe in the week after the U.S. Congress passes the debt-ceiling deal on 2nd August 2011. The U.S. fiscal deficit and debt problem are well-known facts to the markets. The same is true for the European sovereign debt problem. They are nothing new to the markets and therefore it is hard to imagine that the stock market contagion (from U.S. to Asia and Europe) has occurred because new information concerning the U.S. debt position is revealed by the U.S. Congress deal or by Standard & Poor’s downgrade of U.S. sovereign debt. Contagion occurs not as a direct reaction to the bad news about U.S. stock market plunge, but rather a reaction to the anticipation of the influence of bad news on other investors. It is this belief of the media impact on others that motivates Asian and European investors to respond in such a way.

  3. Contagion has different interpretations across different studies. For alternative definitions of contagion, please refer to Masson (1999b), Edwards (2000), and Forbes and Rigobon (2001).

  4. The use of uniform distribution is for ease of presentation. Our results hold when general probability distributions are adopted.

  5. \({\rm{Pr}} \left( m_{\!j}\geq m_{i}\right) =\int_{\delta }^{1+\delta }\int_{m_{i}}^{1}dm_{\!j}dm_{i}=\int_{\delta }^{1+\delta }\left[ m_{\!j}|_{m_{i}}^{1}\right] dm_{i}=\int_{\delta }^{1+\delta }dm_{i}-\int_{\delta }^{1+\delta }m_{i}dm_{i}=1/2-\delta .\) \(\Pr \left( m_{\!j}<m_{i}\right) =1-\Pr \left( m_{\!j}>m_{i}\right) =1/2+\delta . \)

  6. The specific context of our model is contagion of banking crisis. However, the model also has implications for other types of financial contagion. As shown by Morris and Shin (1998, 2000), the same framework can be adjusted to address currency crises and debt pricing.

  7. Our results hold even when only a proportion of investors are subject to the third-person effects.

  8. Page 167 of Degroot (1970) provides a comprehensive proof of this result.

  9. Posterior variance does not enter into the expected payoff and therefore is not relevant to the equilibrium.

  10. It is assumed that every investor will follow the switching strategy around k.

  11. The literature does not deliver a definite answer as to whether capital controls during the crisis period can prevent contagion. For instance, Edison and Reinhart (2000) examine two crisis-capital control episodes: Malaysia 1998–1999 and Thailand 1997. They find that capital controls in Thailand did not deliver much of what they were intended. Some policymakers even argue that capital controls may have exacerbated the problem for Thailand. In contrast, capital controls in Malaysia did achieve greater interest rate and exchange rate stability. In the case of Malaysia, capital controls dampened the spillover, but did not eliminate the spillover.

  12. The loss of credibility follows the escape-clause approach initiated by Obstfeld (1997).

  13. This modeling strategy follows the current literature. An example is Dellas and Stockman (1993), who show how the expectation of future capital controls can trigger speculative attacks. The mere existence of such policy instruments proves to be destabilizing. It is conceivable that a rational policymaker who is aware of the possibility of investment withdrawal will try to avert it by employing controls before the withdrawal. Making capital controls endogenous creates considerable difficulties in terms of modeling and we admit the shortcomings of our current simplification.

  14. Like the information channel, our model depends on a Bayesian information update to trigger a contagion. However, the mechanism is different. In the information channel, it is the arrival of new information regarding the fundamentals that causes a reallocation of portfolio and thus spreads the shocks from one country to another. In our case, investors do not gain new information regarding the fundamentals. Here we resort to the tendency of respondent to overestimate the reaction of others to bad news in the financial markets to trigger the contagion. In this sense, it is a psychological channel that is new to the contagion literature.

  15. Calvo and Mendoza (2000) show that the fixed costs involved in gathering and processing country-specific information can lead to herd behavior, because uninformed investors may find it more advantageous to follow the informed investors.

References

  • Banerjee A (1992) A simple model of herd behavior. Q J Econ 107(3):797–818

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bikhchandani S, Hirshliefer D, Welch I (1992) A theory of fads, fashion, custom, and cultural change as informational cascades. J Polit Econ 100(5):992–1026

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bikhchandani S, Hirshliefer D, Welch I (1998) Learning from the behavior of others: conformity, fads, and informational cascades. J Econ Perspect 12(3):151–170

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broner FA, Gelos GR, Reinhart CM (2006) When in peril, retrench: testing the portfolio channel of contagion. J Int Econ 69:203–230

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo S, Reinhart C (1996) Capital flows to Latin America: is there evidence of contagion effect? In: Calvo G, Goldstein M, Hochreiter E (eds) Private capital flows to emerging markets after the Mexican crisis. Institute for International Economics, Washington DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Calvo GA, Mendoza EG (2000) Rational contagion and the globalization of securities markets. J Int Econ 51:79–113

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlsson H, van Damme E (1993) Global games and equilibrium selection. Econometrica 61(5):989–1018

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conners JL (2005) Understanding the third-person effect. Commun Res Trends 24(2):3–22

    Google Scholar 

  • Corsetti G, Pesenti P, Roubini N (1999) What caused the Asian currency and financial crisis? Japan World Econ 11(3):305–373

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corsetti G, Pesenti P, Roubini N (2002) The role of large players in currency crises. In: Edwards S, Frankel J (eds) Preventing currency crises in emerging markets. NBER and Chicago University Press

  • Corsetti G, Dasgupta A, Morris S, Shin HS (2004) Does one soros make a difference? A theory of currency crises with large and small traders. Rev Econ Stud 71:87–113

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costain J (2007) A herding perspective on global games and multiplicity. BE J Theor Econ 7(1):Article 22

    Google Scholar 

  • Davison WP (1983) The third-person effect in communication. Public Opin Q 47:1–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Degroot MH (1970) Optimal statistical decisions. McGraw-Hill Book Company

  • Dellas H, Stockman A (1993) Self-fulfilling expectations, speculative attack, and capital controls. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 25(4):721–730

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duck JM, Mullin B-A (1995) The perceived impact of the mass media: reconsidering the third person effect. Eur J Soc Psychol 25(1):77–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edison HJ, Reinhart CM (2000) Capital controls during financial crises: the case of Malaysia and Thailand. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, International Finance Discussion Papers no 662

  • Edwards S (2000) Contagion. World Econ 23(7):873–900

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forbes K, Rigobon R (2001) Measuring contagion: conceptual and empirical issues. In: Claessens S, Forbes K (eds) International financial contagion. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston, pp 43–66

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerlach S, Smets F (1995) Contagious speculative attacks. Eur J Polit Econ 11:45–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldstein I (2005) Strategic complementarities and the twin crises. Econ J 115:368–390

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gunther AC, Mundy P (1993) Biased optimism and the third-person effect. Journal Q 70:58–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hondroyiannis G, Kelejian HH, Tavlas GS (2009) Spatial aspects of contagion among emerging economies. Spatial Econ Ana 4(2):192–211

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaminsky GL, Reinhart CM (2000) On crises, contagion, and confusion. J Int Econ 51:145–168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaminsky GL, Reinhart CM, Végh CA (2003) The unholy trinity of financial contagion. J Econ Perspect 17(4):51–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keister T (2009) Expectations and contagion in self-fulfilling currency attacks. Int Econ Rev 50(3):991–1012

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kelejian HH, Tavlas GS, Hondroyiannis G (2006) A spatial modelling approach to contagion among emerging economies. Open Econ Rev 17:423–441

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kodres LE, Pritsker M (2002) A rational expectations model of financial contagion. J Finance 57(2):769–799

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lasorsa DL (1992) How media affect policymakers: the third-person effect. In: David Kennamer J (eds) Public opinion, the press and public policy. Praeger, New York, pp 163–175

    Google Scholar 

  • Manz M (2002) Coordination failure and financial contagion. Diskussionsschriften no dp0203. Universitaet Bern, Departement Volkswirtschaft

  • Masson P (1999a) Contagion: macroeconomic models with multiple equilibria. Journal of International Money and Finance 18(4):587–602

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Masson P (1999b) Contagion: monsoonal effects, spillovers and jumps between multiple equilibria. In: Agenor P-R, Marcus M, David V, Axel W (eds) The Asian financial crisis: causes, contagion and consequences. Cambridge University Press

  • Morris S, Shin HS (1998) Unique equilibrium in a model of self-fulfilling currency attacks. Am Econ Rev 88(3):587–597

    Google Scholar 

  • Morris S, Shin HS (2000) Rethinking multiple equilibria in macroeconomic modelling, pp 139–161. NBER Macroeconomics Annual

  • Morris S, Shin HS (2003) Global games: theory and applications. In: Dewatripont M, Hansen L, Turnovsky S (eds) Advances in economics and econometrics (proceedings of the eighth world congress of the econometric society). Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Mutz DC (1989) The influence of perceptions of media influence: third person effects and the public expression of opinions. Int J Public Opin Res 1(1):3–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld M (1996) Models of currency crises with self-fulfilling features. Eur Econ Rev 40(3–5):1037–1047

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld M (1997) Destabilizing effects of exchange-rate escape clauses. J Int Econ 43:61–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paul B, Salwen MB, Dupagne M (2000) The third-person effect: a meta-analysis of the perceptual hypothesis. Mass Commun Soc 3(1):57–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perloff RM (1993) Third-person effect research 1983–1992: a review and synthesis. Int J Public Opin Res 5(2):167–184

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perloff RM (1996) Perceptions and conceptions of political media impact: the third-person effect and beyond. In: Crigler AN (ed) The psychology of political communication. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor, pp 177–191

    Google Scholar 

  • Perloff LS, Fetzer BK (1986) Self-other judgments and perceived vulnerability to victimization. J Pers Soc Psychol 50(3):502–510

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rzepkowski B (2003) The devaluation expectations in Hong Kong and their determinants. J Jpn Int Econ 17:174–191

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sbracia M, Zaghini A (2001) Expectations and information in second generation currency crises models. Econ Model 18(2):203–222

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taketa K (2004) A large speculator in contagious currency crises: a single George Soros makes countries more vulnerable to crises, but mitigates contagion. IMES Discussion Paper no 2004-E-23

  • Vaugirard VE (2004) Informational contagion of sudden stops in a global games framework. Open Econ Rev 15(2):169–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors thank Shyh-fang Ueng, Jen-hung Wang and Kuo-chun Yeh for helpful discussions. The authors thank editor George S. Tavlas and an anonymous referee for their insightful comments and suggestions. Financial support from Taiwan’s National Science Council NSC 96-2415-H-194-006 is acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tai-kuang Ho.

Appendices

Appendix A

The third-person effect, proposed by Davison (1983) and discussed mainly in the mass communication literature, refers to a tendency for people to perceive that the media messages have a greater impact on the beliefs and behaviors of others than on themselves. Examples of third-person effect can be found in voter behavior, fluctuations in the stock market, hoarding of goods when supplies of consumer goods are irregular, and the phenomenon of censorship. The third-person effect is mediated by the nature of the comparison other and the type of media content. The effect is more pronounced when people consider potential impact of negative media content such as violence, sexism, and racism, and when people compare themselves with vague and distant others (Duck and Mullin 1995). We have mentioned in the main text the conditions that facilitate the third-person effect. In this Appendix, we describe the processes through which the third-person effect operates.

The first psychological explanation to the processes that underlie the third-person effect is downward comparison. Perloff and Fetzer (1986) argue that downward comparison makes an individual to perceive himself as invulnerable to negative messages. When confronted by the question of whether negative messages have a greater impact on him or on the others, an individual tends to compare himself to a group of ‘lower than average’ people. The attributes of these people make them more susceptible to the threat of victimization.

What motivates an individual to compare downward? A possible reason is an ego-defensive function, namely, such a comparison helps to reduce self-anxiety and to preserve control and self-esteem. For instance, when asking an individual whether he is more likely to be influenced by violence in the media than others, refusing the idea that he is more vulnerable to the media than others will help to sustain self-esteem and alleviate the pressures that he is a victim of violence in media. Another reason is cognitive. An individual tends to compare himself to a stereotype of people who have a greater risk of becoming the victims of the negative messages. A vivid example is to ask an individual whether he is more likely to get cancer than others. The individual being questioned usually compares his risk of getting cancer to the risk of elders or people addicted to smoking. This phenomenon is more likely to happen when the questioner does not clearly specify who the others are. The same mechanism also makes people judge themselves as less likely than others to get divorced.

The second psychological explanation is based on attribution theory. In general, attribution theory refers to the study of processes people use to infer causes of behavior. It is postulated that there is a widespread tendency for people to attribute their actions to situational (or external) factors and to attribute the same actions of others to dispositional (or internal) factors. Applied to a media message, people assume themselves being aware of situational factors and are less influenced by the message, while others do not take account of situational factors regarding the message and are more likely to be affected by it. The third-person effect arises from this consistent bias in estimating the situational response.

Appendix B

We follow Morris and Shin (2003) to prove the existence of a unique equilibrium. The proof consists of two steps. First, we show that there is a strategy that survives n rounds of iterated elimination of dominated actions. Second, we show that there is only one strategy that solves the model. Following the main text, we assume that the expected payoff function v(x i , k) is continuous in both x i and k. It is monotonically increasing in x i and monotonically decreasing in k. A strategy survives n rounds of iterated elimination of dominated actions if and only if

$$ \begin{array}{ccc} s\left( x_{i}\right) =1 & if & x_{i}\leq \underline{\xi }_{\;n} \\ s\left( x_{i}\right) =0 & if & x_{i}>\overline{\xi }_{n} \end{array} $$

where s(·) indicates investor i’s behavioral action, s = 0 denotes the continuation of the investment and s = 1 denotes investment withdrawal. We define \(\underline{\xi }_{\;n}\) and \(\overline{\xi }_{n}\) recursively as:

$$ \underline{\xi }_{\;n+1}=\min \left\{ x_{i}:v\left( x_{i},\underline{\xi } _{\;n}\right) =0\right\} $$
$$ \overline{\xi }_{n+1}=\max \Big\{ x_{i}:v\Big( x_{i},\overline{\xi } _{n}\Big) =0\Big\} $$

where \(\underline{\xi }_{\;0}=-\infty \) and \(\overline{\xi }_{0}=\infty \). We first show that there is only one value of \(\underline{\xi }_{\;n}\) and \( \overline{\xi }_{n}\), respectively, that survives n rounds of iterated elimination of dominated actions. Let us start from n = 0 and suppose \( \underline{\xi }_{\;0}=-\infty <\underline{\theta }\) and \(v\left( \underline{ \theta },\underline{\xi }_{\;0}\right) <0\). It is possible to find a \( \underline{\xi }_{\;1}\) such that \(v\left( \underline{\xi }_{\;1},\underline{ \xi }_{\;0}\right) =0\). Since \(v\left( x_{i},k\right) \) is increasing in x i and decreasing in k, \(\underline{\xi }_{\;1}\) must satisfy the condition that \(\underline{\xi }_{\;0}<\underline{\theta }<\underline{\xi } _{\;1} \). We can proceed a step further and find a \(\underline{\xi }_{\;2}\) such that \(v\left( \underline{\xi }_{\;2},\underline{\xi }_{\;1}\right) =0\). Since \( v\left( \cdot \right) \) is decreasing in k, it must be the case that \( \underline{\xi }_{\;1}<\underline{\xi }_{\;2}\). We can employ the same argument and start from \(\overline{\xi }_{0}\). Suppose \(\overline{\xi }_{0}=\infty > \overline{\theta } \) and \(v\left( \;\overline{\theta },\overline{\xi } _{0}\right) >0\). It is possible to find a \(\overline{\xi }_{1}\) such that \( \overline{\xi }_{\;0}>\overline{\theta }>\overline{\xi }_{1}\) and \(v\left( \;\overline{\xi }_{1},\overline{\xi }_{0}\right) =0\). And so forth. The above argument demonstrates that \(\underline{\xi }_{\;n}\) is an increasing sequence and \(\overline{\xi }_{n}\) is a decreasing sequence. Thus, as n approaches ∞, \(\underline{\xi }_{\;n}\) will approach \(\underline{\xi }\) and \( \overline{\xi }_{n}\) will approach \(\overline{\xi }\). An equilibrium requires that there exists a fixed point such that \(v\left( \underline{\xi }, \underline{\xi }\right) =0\) and \(v\left(\; \overline{\xi },\overline{\xi } \right) =0\). This completes our first step of proving the existence of equilibrium.

The second step is fairly intuitive in that, we only have to show that there is a single solution to the expected payoff function. This has already been done in Section 3 of our main text. Therefore, \(\underline{\xi }\) is just \( \overline{\xi }\), and there is only one strategy remaining after eliminating all iteratively dominated strategies.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ho, Tk., Wu, My. Third-person Effect and Financial Contagion in the Context of a Global Game. Open Econ Rev 23, 823–846 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-011-9215-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-011-9215-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation