Skip to main content
Log in

Patience auctions: the impact of time vs. money bidding on elicited discount rates

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Experimental Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We introduce, test, and compare two auction-based methods for eliciting discount rates. In these “patience auctions”, participants bid the smallest future sum they would prefer -or- the longest time they would wait for a reward, rather than receive a smaller, immediate payoff. The most patient bidder receives the delayed reward; all others receive the immediate payoff. These auctions allow us to compare discounting when participants’ attention is focused on the temporal versus monetary dimension of delayed rewards. We find that the estimated parameters in the three most commonly used discount functions (exponential, hyperbolic, and quasi-hyperbolic) differ across these two bidding methods (time-bids vs. money-bids). Specifically, our participants tend to show more impatience under time-bids. Furthermore, we find that people are more likely to exhibit exponential (as opposed to hyperbolic) discounting and exhibit less present bias under time-bids, compared to money-bids. To our knowledge, this paper is the first to directly compare time versus money preference elicitations, within the same subjects, using an incentive-compatible mechanism.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In fact, there is evidence that consumers may make inconsistent choices across these two normatively equivalent ways of approaching the decision to wait for a discount. Sussman and Olivola (2011; Experiment 2) asked a sample of consumers (N = 351) to indicate both their willingness to wait (in minutes) in line for a 9 % discount on a product, and the smallest discount (in percentage) on that same product for which they would be willing wait 15 min in line. Both sets of preferences were collected using multiple-binary-choice ladders (with waiting times ranging from 5 to 60 min and discounts ranging from 5 to 12 %, respectively), and all participants completed both ladders (with ladders presented in counterbalanced order and usually separated by other, unrelated questions). We reanalyzed the data from that study, focusing on the 339 participants who completed both ladders without multiple switching points and on the equivalent binary-choice question in each ladder (whether they were willing to wait 15 min for a 9 % discount on the product). Our analyses showed that Sussman and Olivola’s participants were significantly more likely to accept waiting 15 min for a 9 % discount (i.e., when the ladder varied the waiting time) than they were to accept a 9 % discount in exchange for a 15 min wait (i.e., when the ladder varied the discount size): likelihood of accepting = 87 vs. 74 %, z = 4.07, p < 0.0001. A closer look at their responses showed that 19 % of the participants reported inconsistent preferences: 16 % accepted to wait 15 min for the 9 % discount but also refused a 9 % discount for the 15 min wait; 3 % exhibited the opposite inconsistency (i.e., refusing to wait 15 min for the 9 % discount but also accepting a 9 % discount for the 15 min wait).

  2. Research comparing decisions about spending (or earning) time versus money (as goods in their own right) has shown that people treat these two commodities very differently (Burmeister-Lamp and Schade unpublished manuscript; De Borger and Fosgerau 2008; Duxbury et al. 2005; Leclerc et al. 1995; Liu and Aaker 2008; Monga and Saini 2009; Okada and Hoch 2004; Saini and Monga 2008; Soman 2001; Soster et al. 2010; Zauberman and Lynch 2005). However, whereas these previous studies compared preferences for two different kinds of goods (money versus time), we are interested in examining how people value the same class of goods (delayed rewards) when they express their preferences along one of two different dimensions (money versus time). The fact that people approach expenditures (or earnings) of money and time differently tells us little about how their patience-levels might vary depending on whether they are focused on the monetary or temporal dimension of delayed rewards.

  3. Originally introduced by Samuelson (1937) in his seminal paper on the discounted utility model, discount rates describe how people trade off consumption in the present vs. future (Frederick et al. 2002). Discount rates can be thought of, essentially, as economic measures of impatience.

  4. Our analyses revealed no order effects within either type of auction (on either the discount rate or the β parameter representing present-bias).

  5. Overbidding has been documented in laboratory second-price auctions (Heyman et al. 2004; Kagel et al. 1987; Kagel and Levin 1993). This phenomenon could be due to a myriad of factors ranging from a failure to understand the dominant bidding strategy to “auction fever” over the possibility of “winning” (Delgado et al. 2008).

  6. Participants could choose from several options to receive their payments: cash payments in person, check payments by mail, or direct bank transfers. Doing so helped minimize the cost to them of receiving their payments and ensured that we could pay them even if they had left campus when their payment deadlines arrived.

  7. For a more extensive discussion of this procedure, see Frederick et al. (2002).

  8. In contrast to the auctions, we do observe order effects with the hypothetical matching task survey. Specifically, we find a marginally significant order effect on the discount rate under money biding (when we estimate exponential and hyperbolic models, but not when we estimate quasi-hyperbolic models), such that discount rates are higher under the time-then-money ordering (compared to the money-then-time ordering). And we find a significant order effect on the discount rate under time biding (for all three discounting models), such that discount rates are again higher under the time-then-money ordering. Finally, when we estimate the quasi-hyperbolic model, we find significant order effects on the β (present-bias) parameter: under money bidding, β is larger in the money-then-time ordering; under time bidding, β is larger in the time-then-money ordering.

  9. While the validity of the random-lottery incentive system (paying all participants according to one randomly selected choice) has received strong empirical support (Beattie and Loomes 1997; Cubitt et al. 1998; Hey and Lee 2005a, b; Lee 2008; Starmer and Sugden 1991), the validity of paying a random subset of participants according to their choices is less well established (see Baltussen et al. 2012). The few tests of this latter method have found that it biases preferences by lowering risk aversion (Baltussen et al. 2012).

  10. Recently, a working paper by David Eil has come to our attention. He utilizes a multiple-choice method (involving a series of binary choices between smaller payoffs today and larger payoffs in the future) to identify switching points in subject’s preferences (in order to estimate their implied discounting parameters). He directly compares time preferences when the delay vs. amount of the future payoff is systematically varied. However, it should be noted that his experiment was conducted in May 2010, whereas ours was carried out in the fall of 2007, our results were first presented (at a major conference) in 2007, and the first complete draft of our manuscript had been written by 2009.

  11. Note that our manipulation is within-bidder, and therefore controls for bidder-specific fixed effects (including risk attitudes and beliefs about the distribution of other bidders’ risk and time preferences).

  12. Testing this assumption is left to future work.

  13. We can also check whether revenue equivalence holds between the first- and second-price money-bid auctions. Here we define “revenue” as the amount given to the “winner” of the money-bid auction at the delayed date instead of $10 in the present. A Mann–Whitney test comparing revenues from the first-price money-bid auctions and revenues from the second-price money-bid auctions yields p value = 0.057. Note that numerous previous experiments have found lack of revenue equivalence between first- and second-price auctions (Kagel 1995). The predicted revenue equivalence hinges on the assumption that bidders are risk-neutral, so any lack of revenue equivalence found here could be attributed to non-risk-neutrality or to a number of other possible factors.

  14. These model parameters were estimated using data from all subjects with estimable parameters, not just those for whom the model represented the best fit according to the BIC.

  15. These results are consistent with those obtained by Eil (unpublished manuscript), who finds that eliciting time preferences through a multiple-choice method in which the delay of the future payoff is systematically varied (to identify a switching point) yields more impatience and less present bias than a multiple-choice method in which the amount of the future payoff is varied instead. However, whereas Eil finds evidence of future bias (i.e., β > 1, see also Takeuchi 2011) under the “time” multiple-choice method, we find lower or no present bias with time bids, but not future bias.

  16. We also fitted a model specification with a free θ (hyperbolicity) parameter (such that θ = 1 produced the exponential and θ = 2 produced the standard hyperbolic function; see Benhabib et al. 2010), and found that the estimated θ is lower and closer to 1 for time bids (compared to money bids) under all three elicitation procedures. Specifically, the θ parameter ranged from 1.1 to 1.8 for time bids, and from 2.5 to 3.4 for money bids. Thus, people seem to be less hyperbolic (i.e., more exponential) when they bid time, whereas they seem to be “supra”-hyperbolic (θ > 2) when they bid money.

References

  • Attema, A. E., Bleichrodt, H., Rohde, K. I. M., & Wakker, P. P. (2010). Time-tradeoff sequences for analyzing discounting and time inconsistency. Management Science, 56(11), 2015–2030.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baltussen, G., Post, T., van den Assem, M. J., & Wakker, P. P. (2012). Random incentive systems in a dynamic choice experiment. Experimental Economics, 15(3), 418–443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartolini, L., & Cottarelli, C. (1997). Treasury bill auctions: Issues and uses. In M. I. Blejer & T. Ter-Minassian (Eds.), Macroeconomic dimensions of public finance: Essays in honour of Vito Tanzi (pp. 267–336). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beattie, J., & Loomes, G. (1997). The impact of incentives upon risky choice experiments. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 14(2), 155–168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib, J., Bisin, A., & Schotter, A. (2010). Present-bias, quasi-hyperbolic discounting, and fixed costs. Games and Economic Behavior, 69(2), 205–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carmon, Z., & Ariely, D. (2000). Focusing on the forgone: Why value can appear so different to buyers and sellers. Journal of Consumer Research, 27, 360–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chesson, H., & Viscusi, W. K. (2000). The heterogeneity of time-risk tradeoffs. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 13, 251–258.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cubitt, R. P., Starmer, C., & Sugden, R. (1998). On the validity of the random lottery incentive system. Experimental Economics, 1(2), 115–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Borger, B., & Fosgerau, M. (2008). The trade-off between money and time: A test of the theory of reference-dependent preferences. Journal of Urban Economics, 64(1), 101–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delgado, M. R., Schotter, A., Ozbay, E. Y., & Phelps, E. A. (2008). Understanding overbidding: Using the neural circuitry of reward to design economic auctions. Science, 321, 1849–1852.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duxbury, D., Keasey, K., Zhang, H., & Chow, S. L. (2005). Mental accounting and decision making: Evidence under reverse conditions where money is spent for time saved. Journal of Economic Psychology, 26, 567–580.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elster, J. (1984). Ulysses and the sirens. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ersner-Hershfield, H., Wimmer, G. E., & Knutson, B. (2009). Saving for the future self: Neural measures of future self-continuity predict temporal discounting. Social Cognitive and Affective Neuroscience, 4(1), 85–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frederick, S., Loewenstein, G., & O’Donoghue, T. (2002). Time discounting and time preference: A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature, 40, 351–401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldstein, W. M., & Einhorn, H. J. (1987). Expression theory and the preference reversal phenomena. Psychological Review, 94(2), 236–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, L., Fristoe, N., & Myerson, J. (1994). Temporal discounting and preference reversals in choice between delayed outcomes. Psychonomic Bulletin & Review, 1, 383–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grether, D. M., & Plott, C. R. (1979). Economic theory of choice and the preference reversal phenomenon. American Economic Review, 69(4), 623–638.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hey, J. D., & Lee, J. (2005a). Do subjects remember the past? Applied Economics, 37(1), 9–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hey, J. D., & Lee, J. (2005b). Do subjects separate (or are they sophisticated)? Experimental Economics, 8, 233–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heyman, J. E., Orhun, Y., & Ariely, D. (2004). Auction fever: The effect of opponents and quasi-endowment on product valuations. Journal of Interactive Marketing, 18, 7–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horowitz, J. K. (1991). Discounting money payoffs: An experimental analysis. In S. Kaish & B. Gilad (Eds.), Handbook of behavioral economics (pp. 309–324). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • James, D. (2011). Incentive compatible elicitation procedures. Modsim Conference Proceedings, 19, 1421–1427.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kagel, J. H. (1995). Auctions: A survey of experimental research. In J. H. Kagel & A. E. Roth (Eds.), Handbook of experimental economics (pp. 501–585). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kagel, J. H., Harstad, R. M., & Levin, D. (1987). Information impact and allocation rules in auctions with affiliated private values: A laboratory study. Econometrica, 55, 1275–1304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kagel, J. H., & Levin, D. (1993). Independent private value auctions: Bidder behavior in first-, second- and third-price auctions with varying numbers of bidders. Economic Journal, 103, 868–879.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., Knetsch J. L., & Thaler R. H. (1990). Experimental tests of the endowment effect and the Coase theorem. Journal of Political Economy, 98, 1325–1348.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47, 263–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Killeen, P. R. (2009). An additive-utility model of delay discounting. Psychological Review, 116(3), 602–619.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirby, K. N. (1997). Bidding on the future: Evidence against normative discounting of delayed rewards. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 126, 54–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirby, K. N., & Marakovic, N. N. (1995). Modeling myopic decisions: Evidence for hyperbolic delay-discounting within subjects and amounts. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 64, 22–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laibson, D. (1997). Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(2), 443–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leclerc, F., Schmitt, B. H., & Dube, L. (1995). Waiting time and decision making: Is time like money? Journal of Consumer Research, 22, 110–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, J. (2008). The effect of the background risk in a simple chance improving decision model. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 36, 19–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, G., & Bajari, P. (2011). Procurement contracting with time incentives: Theory and evidence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126(3), 1173–1211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lichtenstein, S., & Slovic, P. (Eds.). (2006). The construction of preference. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu, W., & Aaker, J. (2008). The happiness of giving: The time-ask effect. Journal of Consumer Research, 35, 543–557.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mazur, J. E. (1987). An adjusting procedure for studying delayed reinforcement. In M. L. Commons, J. E. Mazur, J. A. Nevin, & H. Rachlin (Eds.), Quantitative analyses of behavior, vol. 5: The effect of delay and of intervening events on reinforcement value (pp. 55–73). Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum.

    Google Scholar 

  • McClure, S. M., Laibson, D. I., Loewenstein, G., & Cohen, J. D. (2004). Separate neural systems value immediate and delayed monetary rewards. Science, 306, 503–507.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meier, S., & Sprenger, C. D. (2015). Temporal stability of time preferences. Review of Economics and Statistics, 97(2), 273–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mischel, W., Ebbesen, E. B., & Zeiss, A. R. (1972). Cognitive and attentional mechanisms in delay of gratification. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 35, 204–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mischel, W., Shoda, Y., & Peake, P. K. (1988). The nature of adolescent competencies predicted by preschool delay of gratification. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 54(4), 687–696.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mischel, W., Shoda, Y., & Rodriguez, M. I. (1989). Delay of gratification in children. Science, 244, 933–938.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Monga, A., & Saini, R. (2009). Currency of search: How spending time on search is not the same as spending money. Journal of Retailing, 85(3), 245–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Okada, E. M., & Hoch, S. J. (2004). Spending time versus spending money. Journal of Consumer Research, 31, 313–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olivola, C. Y., & Sagara, N. (2009). Distributions of observed death tolls govern sensitivity to human fatalities. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 106, 22151–22156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parfit, D. (1984). Reasons and persons. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Phelps, E. S., & Pollak, R. A. (1968). On second-best national saving and game-equilibrium growth. Review of Economic Studies, 35, 185–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pronin, E., Olivola, C. Y., & Kennedy, K. A. (2008). Doing unto future selves as you would do unto others: Psychological distance and decision making. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 34(2), 224–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reimers, S., Maylor, E. A., Stewart, N., & Chater, N. (2009). Associations between a one-shot delay discounting measure and age, income, education and real-world impulsive behavior. Personality and Individual Differences, 47, 973–978.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roelofsma, P. H. M. P. (1996). Modelling intertemporal choices: An anomaly approach. Acta Psychologica, 93, 5–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saini, R., & Monga, A. (2008). How I decide depends on what I spend: Use of heuristics is greater for time than for money. Journal of Consumer Research, 34, 914–922.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. (1937). A note on measurement of utility. Review of Economic Studies, 4, 155–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scholten, M., & Read, D. (2010). The psychology of intertemporal tradeoffs. Psychological Review, 117(3), 925–944.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwarz, G. E. (1978). Estimating the dimension of a model. Annals of Statistics, 6, 461–464.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Soman, D. (2001). The mental accounting of sunk time: Why time is not like money. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 14, 169–185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Soster, R. L., Monga, A., & Bearden, W. O. (2010). Tracking costs of time and money: How accounting periods affect mental accounting. Journal of Consumer Research, 37(4), 712–721.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Starmer, C., & Sugden, R. (1991). Does the random-lottery incentive system elicit true preferences? An experimental investigation. American Economic Review, 81(4), 971–978.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stewart, N., Chater, N., & Brown, G. D. A. (2006). Decision by sampling. Cognitive Psychology, 53, 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sussman, A. B., & Olivola, C. Y. (2011). Axe the tax: Taxes are disliked more than equivalent costs. Journal of Marketing Research, 48(SPL), S91–S101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Takeuchi, K. (2011). Non-parametric test of time consistency: Present bias and future bias. Games and Economic Behavior, 71(2), 456–478.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R., & Johnson, E. J. (1990). Gambling with the house money and trying to break even: The effects of prior outcomes on risky choice. Management Science, 36(6), 643–660.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Todorov, A., Goren, A., & Trope, Y. (2007). Probability as a psychological distance: Construal and preferences. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 43(3), 473–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science, 185, 1124–1131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1991). Loss aversion in riskless choice: A reference dependent model. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107, 1039–1061.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., Slovic, P., & Kahneman, D. (1990). The causes of preference reversal. American Economic Review, 80(1), 204–217.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vickrey, W. (1961). Counterspeculation, auctions, and competitive sealed tenders. Journal of Finance, 16, 8–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zauberman, G., & Lynch, J. G. (2005). Resource slack and propensity to discount delayed investments of time versus money. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 134, 23–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank Abhijit Banerji, Roland Benabou, Colin Camerer, John Doyle, Jacob Goeree, Jens Großer, David Hardisty, Joel Huber, Eric J. Johnson, Nobuo Koida, Alexey Kushnir, Graham Loomes, J.V. Meenakshi, Daniel Mochon, C. Dan Myers, Thomas Palfrey, Uliana Popova Makarov, Ganna Pogrebna, Eldar Shafir, Rohini Somanathan, Dean Spears, Peter Wakker, and four anonymous reviewers (including one from the Russell Sage Foundation) for their helpful comments and suggestions. We also received helpful feedback from participants of SJDM 2007, BDRM 2008, Yale Whitebox 2008, ACR 2008, ESA 2008, SJDM 2008, SCP 2009, SPUDM 2009, the DR@W seminar at the University of Warwick, the ECO seminar at the University of East Anglia, and the Center for Development Economics seminar at the Delhi School of Economics. We are especially indebted to Chris Crabbe, who did a spectacular job programming the experiment. This research was generously funded by a grant from the Russell Sage Foundation’s small grants program in Behavioral Economics and an award from the Society for Judgment and Decision Making.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Christopher Y. Olivola.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (DOCX 58 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Olivola, C.Y., Wang, S.W. Patience auctions: the impact of time vs. money bidding on elicited discount rates. Exp Econ 19, 864–885 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-015-9472-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-015-9472-x

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation