Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Fighting Software Piracy: Which Governance Tools Matter in Africa?

  • Published:
Journal of Business Ethics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This article integrates previously missing components of government quality into the governance-piracy nexus in exploring governance mechanisms by which global obligations for the treatment of IPRs are effectively transmitted from international to the national level in the battle against piracy. It assesses the best governance tools in the fight against piracy and upholding of intellectual property rights (IPRs). The instrumentality of IPR laws (treaties) in tackling piracy through good governance mechanisms is also examined. Findings demonstrate that: (1) while all governance tools under consideration significantly decrease the incidence of piracy, corruption-control is the most effective weapon; (2) but for voice and accountability, political stability and democracy, IPR laws (treaties) are instrumental in tackling piracy through government quality dynamics of rule of law, regulation quality, government effectiveness, corruption-control, and press freedom. Hence, the need for a policy approach most conducive to expanding development is to implement an integrated system of both IPRs and corollary good governance policies. Moreover, our findings support the relevance of good governance measures in developing countries wishing to complement their emerging IPR regimes.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For an excellent introduction to the economics of intellectual property rights (see Besen and Raskind 1991).

  2. Varian (1998) defines an information good as anything can be digitized. Books, records, and computer programs fall into this category. Computer software receives protection under copyright law, though in recent years software developers (particularly in the USA) have been granted patent protection as well. Copyright protects form of expression (e.g., written material and artistic works), while patents protect underlying ideas used for industrial products or processes.

  3. However, it is not necessary for example to endow owners with strong rights to control distribution and restrict use so as to avoid depletion of goods that by their definition are non-excludable. On the contrary, restricting use can freeze ideas and stifle innovation. Indeed, a substantial body of the literature warns of the dangers of too much protection of IPRs. For instance, stronger IPRs may stifle incentives to innovate and introduce new technologies (Helpman 1993; Bessen and Maskin 2000; Maskus 2000; Shadlen et al. 2005). As sustained by Shadlen et al. (2005), with too much protection, the tragedy of the commons may be replaced by the tragedy of the anti-commons (Heller and Eisenberg 1998), since diminished access to upstream ideas can deter downstream innovation.

  4. Theoretically, there are several reasons why piracy will not be damaging to the copyright holders. As piracy enlarges the installed base of users (legal or illegal), it creates network effects that increase the consumers’ willingness to pay for the software, thereby potentially increasing the producers’ profits (Takeyama 1994; Shy and Thisse 1999). Another wave of papers assumes that copies can be made from originals so that producers of information goods can indirectly appropriate part of the consumer surplus (e.g., Johnson 1985; Liebowitz 1985; Besen and Kirby 1989; Varian 2000). Even in the absence of network effects, piracy may be profitable because of indirect appropriation.

  5. Another strand of the formal literature has focused on the fact that, stronger intellectual property rights protection should enhance economic growth by increasing returns to innovation and therefore, the incentives to innovate. At the aggregate level, a broader strand of the literature has investigated the intensity of the protection of the IPRs and its impact on economic growth. This empirical literature has largely documented that, IPRs protection has a positive effect on economic growth, often using cross section data (see for example, Falvey et al. 2006; Park and Ginarte 1997).

  6. “The Board remains ready and willing to support software copyright owners by intensifying enforcement efforts to reduce software piracy in our country and ensure that legitimate businesses reap the fruits of their labor as per the Kenya Copyright Board mandate” (Fripp 2011).

  7. The model assumes the possibility to determine a unique set of appropriate institutional arrangements in advance and then expects convergence towards those arrangements is inherently desirable (El-Bialy 2010). Countries applying the same formal rules will have very different performance characteristics, due to the fact that they have different informal norms and enforcement characteristics (North 1995). Hence, it is very hard to determine a unique set of appropriate formal and external institutional arrangements that could be implemented in all countries without taking the already existing informal or internal institutional set-up of each country into consideration. According to North (1996), this fact can explain the failure of some formal rules from successful Western economies when applied to developing countries.

  8. For instance, some considerable achievements were observed as piracy trends started to decline in North Africa.

  9. Unfortunately, we are unable to include a dummy variable to capture the effect of the methodology change because of issues in degrees of freedom (owing to constraints in data availability).

  10. Refer to BSA (2009) for measurement details. The BSA data primarily measures the piracy of commercial software. We are unaware of any publicly available cross-national data on end user software piracy. See Png (2008) for a discussion about the reliability of piracy data. Also see Traphagan and Griffith (1998).

  11. Among the many researchers that have used this data are Andrés (2006), Banerjee et al. (2005), Goel and Nelson (2009), Andrés and Goel (2012), and Marron and Steel (2000).

  12. See first point on second strand in the “Software piracy, IPRs, and Governance in Africa” section. Also see, first strand depicting stylized facts from selected countries on how governments are fighting software piracy.

  13. An OIR test is only possible in the presence of overidentification. That is, the instruments must be higher than the endogenous explaining variables by at least one degree of freedom. In the cases of exact identification (instruments equal to endogenous explaining variables) and under identification (instruments less than endogenous explaining variables) an OIR test is by definition not possible.

  14. We expect both population growth and economic prosperity to be positively associated with software piracy.

  15. The freedom variable in the analysis is a time-dynamic dummy instrumental variable. It may take the values of 0 or 1 for the same country depending on the state of quality of freedom in a given period. Hence there is a substantial difference between freedom (an instrumental variable) and press freedom quality which an exogenous variable.

  16. See second point on second strand in the “Software piracy, IPRs, and Governance in Africa” section.

  17. Note that measurement error in the dependent variable, the piracy rate, causes inefficiency in the regression analysis. This makes the standard errors in the coefficients on the explanatory variables large and they lose statistical significance. If the measurement error in the dependent variable is systematically related to one or more of the explanatory variables, OLS estimates will be biased. Taking the natural log of the dependent variable lets the bias move into the error term if measurement error is systematic and persistent.

References

  • AFROL. (2009). Egypt’s software piracy rating drops. afrol News. Accessed September 24, 2012, from http://www.afrol.com/articles/33242.

  • Agabi, C. (2012). Nigeria: Firm fights software piracy in Nigeria. Accessed September 24, 2012, from http://allafrica.com/stories/201207030367.html.

  • Agbor, J. A. (2011). How does colonial origin matter for economic performance in Sub-Saharan Africa. World Institute for Development Economics Research Working Paper No. 2011/27.

  • Andrés, A. R. (2006). The relationship between copyright software protection and piracy: Evidence from Europe. European Journal of Law and Economics, 21, 29–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andrés, A. R., & Goel, R. K. (2011). Corruption and software piracy: A comparative perspective. Policy and Internet, 3, Article 2. Accessed June 27, 2012, from http://www.psocommons.org/policyandinternet/vol3/iss3/art2.

  • Andrés, A. R., & Goel, R. K. (2012). Does software piracy affect economic growth? Evidence across countries. Journal of Policy Modeling, 34, 284–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asche, H., & Schüller, M. (2008). China’s engagement in Africa: Opportunities and risks for development. Eschborn: Africa Department, Deutsche Gesellschaft für Technische Zusammenarbeit (GTZ) GmbH.

    Google Scholar 

  • Asongu, S. A. (2011). Law, democracy and the quality of government in Africa. MPRA Paper No. 35502. Accessed December 19, 2012, from http://econpapers.repec.org/paper/pramprapa/35502.htm.

  • Asongu, S. A. (2012a). Harmonizing IPRs on software piracy: Empirics of trajectories in Africa. Journal of Business Ethics. Accessed December 19, 2012, from http://link.springer.com/article/10.1007%2Fs10551-012-1552-7?LI=true#page-1.

  • Asongu, S. A. (2012b). Fighting software piracy in Africa: How do legal origins and IPRs protection channels matter? Journal of the Knowledge Economy. Accessed December 19, 2012, from http://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/s13132-012-0137-0.

  • Asongu, S. A. (2012c). On the effect of foreign aid on corruption. Economics Bulletin, 32(2), 2174–2180.

    Google Scholar 

  • Asongu, S. A. (2012d). Government quality determinants of stock market performance in African countries. Journal of African Business, 13(2), 183–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee, D. S. (2006). Enforcement sharing and commercial piracy. Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 3, 83–97.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee, D., Khalid, A. M., & Sturm, J.-E. (2005). Socio-economic development and software piracy. An empirical assessment. Applied Economics, 37, 2091–2097.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck, T., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & Levine, R. (2003). Law and finance: Why does legal origin matter? Journal of Comparative Economics, 31, 653–675.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besen, S. M., & Kirby, S. N. (1989). Private copying, appropriability, and optimal copying royalties. Journal of Law and Economics, 32, 255–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besen, S. M., & Raskind, L. J. (1991). An introduction to the law and economics of intellectual property. Journal of Economics Perspectives, 5, 3–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bessen, J., & Maskin. E. (2000). Sequential innovation, patents, and imitation. Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology Working Paper No. 00-01.

  • Bezmen, T. L. and Depken, C. A. (2004). The impact of software piracy on economic development, Working Paper. Francis Marion University.

  • Bezmen, T. L., & Depken, C. A. (2006). Influences on software piracy: Evidence from the various United States. Economics Letters, 90, 356–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blakeney, M., & Mengistie, G. (2011). Intellectual property and economic development in Sub-Saharan Africa. The Journal of World Intellectual Property, 3–4, 238–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Business Software Alliance (BSA). (2007). Piracy study, Fifth Annual BSA and IDC Global Software. Accessed October 3, 2012, from http://global.bsa.org/idcglobalstudy2007/studies/2007_global_piracy_study.pdf).

  • Business Software Alliance (BSA). (2009). What is software piracy? Accessed June 27, 2012, from http://www.bsa.org/Piracy%20Portal.aspx.

  • Business Software Alliance (BSA). (2010). Eighth Annual BSA Global Software 2010 Piracy Study.

  • Chen, C., Chen, C., & Yeh, C. (2010). Determinants of software piracy: Evidence from Far East countries. Journal of International and Global Economic Studies, 3(2), 53–62.

    Google Scholar 

  • El-Bialy, N. (2010). The role of institutions within the IPR enforcement context: The case of de facto software protection in Egypt. Discussion Papers on Strategy and Innovation 10-02, Philipps-University Marburg.

  • Falvey, R., Foster, N., & Greenway, D. (2006). Intellectual property rights and economic growth. Review of Development Economics, 10, 700–719.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fripp, C. (2011). Kenya fighting software piracy. IT News Africa. Accessed September 24, 2012, from http://www.itnewsafrica.com/2011/04/kenya-fighting-software-piracy.

  • Gallegos, F. (1999). Software piracy: Some facts, figures, and issues. Information Systems Security, 8, 34–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goel, R. K., & Nelson, M. A. (2009). Determinants of software piracy: Economics, institutions, and technology. Journal of Technology Transfer, 34, 637–658.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gopal, R. D., & Sanders, G. L. (2000). You can’t get blood out of a turnip. Communications of the ACM, 43, 83–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haley, G. T. (2000). Intellectual property rights and foreign direct investment in emerging countries. Marketing Intelligence and Planning, 18(5), 273–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamade, S. N. (2006). The legal and political aspects of software piracy in the Arab World. In ITNG ‘06 Proceedings of the Third International Conference on Information Technology: New Generations, pp. 137–142.

  • Heller, M. A., & Eisenberg, R. S. (1998). Can patents deter innovation? The anticommons in biomedical research. Science, 280, 698–701.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, E. (1993). Innovation, imitation, and intellectual property rights. Econometrica, 61, 1247–1280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holm, H. J. (2003). Can economic theory explain piracy behavior? Topics in Economic Analysis & Policy, 3, article 5.

  • Husted, B. W. (2000). The impact of national culture on software piracy. Journal of Business Ethics, 26, 197–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • IMF. (2005, June). The IMF approach to promoting good governance and combating corruption—a guide, International Monetary Fund.

  • International Development Corporation (IDC). (2009). How to reduce software piracy in the Middle East and Africa: The case of South Africa.

  • Johnson, W. R. (1985). The economics of copying. Journal of Political Economy, 93, 158–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2006). Governance Matters V: Aggregate and Individual Governance Indicators for 1996-2005. Washington, D.C: World Bank.

  • Kim, L. (2004). The multifaceted evolution of Korean technological capabilities and its implications for contemporary policy. Oxford Development Studies, 32(3), 341–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koboldt, C. (1995). Intellectual property and optimal copyright protection. Journal of Cultural Economics, 19, 131–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2008). The economic consequences of legal origins. Journal of Economic Literature, 46(2), 285–332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1998). Law and finance. Journal of Political Economy, 106, 1113–1155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lessig, L. (2001). The future of ideas: The fate of the commons in a connected world. New York: Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liebowitz, S. J. (1985). Copying and indirect appropriability: Photocopying of journals. Journal of Political Economy, 93, 945–957.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Logsdon, J., Thompson, J., & Reid, R. (1994). Software piracy: Is it related to moral judgment? Journal of Business Ethics, 13, 649–857.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marron, D. B., & Steel, D. G. (2000). Which countries protect intellectual property? The case of software piracy. Economic Inquiry, 38, 159–174.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maskus, E. K. (2000). Intellectual property rights and economic development. Boulder: University of Colorado.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maskus, K. E., & Penubarti, M. (1995). How trade related are intellectual property rights? Journal of International Economics, 39, 227–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1995). Five propositions about institutional change. In J. Knight & I. Sened (Eds.), Explaining social institutions (pp. 15–26). Ann Arbor, MI: The University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1996). Where have we been and where are we going?. St. Louis: Washington University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Park, W. G., & Ginarte, J. C. (1997). Intellectual property rights and economic growth. Contemporary Economic Policy, 15, 51–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peitz, M., & Waelbroeck, P. (2006). Piracy of digital products: A critical review of the theoretical literature. Information Economics and Policy, 18, 449–476.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Png, I. (2008). On the reliability of software piracy statistics. Mimeo: National University of Singapore.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robertson, C., Gilley, K. M., & Crittenden, W. F. (2008). Trade liberalization, corruption and software piracy. Journal of Business Ethics, 78, 623–634.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (2008). Second-best institutions. American Economic Review, 98(2), 100–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shadlen, K. C., Schrank, A., & Kurtz, M. J. (2005). The political economy of intellectual property protection: The case of software. International Studies Quarterly, 49, 45–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shy, O., & Thisse, J. F. (1999). A strategic approach to software protection. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 8, 163–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • SIIA. (2000). SIIA report on global software piracy 2000. Washington, DC: Software and Information Industry Association.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stulz, R. M., & Williamson, R. (2003). Culture, openness and finance. Journal of Financial Economics, 70, 313–349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Takeyama, L. N. (1994). The welfare implications of unauthorized reproduction of intellectual property rights in presence of network externalities. Journal of Industrial Economics, 62, 155–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Traphagan, M., & Griffith, A. (1998). Software piracy and global competitiveness: Report on global software piracy. International Review of Law, Computers & Technology, 12, 431–451.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • UNDP. (2002). Giving voice to the voiceless: Good governance.New York: UNDP.

  • Varian, H. R. (1998). Markets for information goods. Mimeo: University of California Berkeley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Varian, H. R. (2000). Buying, sharing and renting information goods. Journal of Industrial Economics, 48, 473–488.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Watt, R. (2001). Prices in cultural markets: A theoretical introduction for beginners. http://www.serci.org/documents/pricing.pdf.

  • Yang, D., Sonmez, M., Bostworth, D., & Fryxell, G. (2009). Global software piracy: Searching for further explanations. Journal of Business Ethics, 87, 269–283.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, D., Sonmez, M., & Bosworth, D. (2004). Intellectual property abuses: How should multinationals respond? Long Range Planning, 37, 459–475.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors are highly indebted to the editor and referees for their very useful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Simplice A. Asongu.

Appendix

Appendix

See Tables 4, 5, and 6.

Table 4 Summary statistics and presentation of countries
Table 5 Correlation matrix of key variables (N = 121)
Table 6 Variable definitions

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Andrés, A.R., Asongu, S.A. Fighting Software Piracy: Which Governance Tools Matter in Africa?. J Bus Ethics 118, 667–682 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-013-1620-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-013-1620-7

Keywords

Navigation