Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Fighting Software Piracy: Some Global Conditional Policy Instruments

  • Published:
Journal of Business Ethics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study examines the efficiency of tools for fighting software piracy in the conditional distributions of software piracy. Our paper examines software piracy in 99 countries over the period 1994–2010, using contemporary and non-contemporary quantile regressions. The intuition for modelling distributions contingent on existing levels of software piracy is that the effectiveness of tools against piracy may consistently decrease or increase simultaneously with the increasing levels of software piracy. Hence, blanket policies against software piracy are unlikely to succeed unless they are contingent on initial levels of software piracy and tailored differently across countries with low, medium and high levels of software piracy. Our findings indicate that GDP per capita, research and development expenditure, main intellectual property laws, multilateral treaties, bilateral treaties, World Intellectual Property Organisation treaties, money supply and respect for the rule of law have negative effects on software piracy. Equitably distributed wealth reduces software piracy, and the tendency not to indulge in software piracy because of equitably distributed wealth increases with the increasing software piracy levels. Hence, the negative degree of responsiveness of software piracy to changes in income levels is an increasing function of software piracy. Moreover, the relationships between policy instruments and software piracy display various patterns: U-shape, Kuznets-shape, S-shape and negative thresholds. A negative threshold represents negative estimates with the increasing negative magnitude throughout the conditional distributions of software piracy. We also discuss the policy implications of our study.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. According to this strand of literature, as nations develop, adoption of more stringent IPRs regimes would, inter alia (i) stimulate exports (Maskus and Penubarti 1995); (ii) favour technology transfers and innovation (Lee and Mansfield 1996); and (iii) increase the possibility of investment from multinational enterprises (Mansfield 1994; Seyoum 1996).

  2. We use the terms ‘software piracy’ and ‘piracy’ interchangeably throughout the paper.

  3. Intuitively, software piracy promotes pro-poor development by making pirated technologies available to less-developed countries but this piracy is harmful for copyright holders because they lose the benefit of having the copyright and they are mainly in the developed countries. The positive impact of piracy on scientific publications is because the scholars in third world countries are able to use the software that is pirated and which they would not be able to use if it was not pirated. Fighting individual piracy can also backfire on copyright holders because (i) commercial piracy can increase the copyright holders’ profits due to a higher population of consumers and (ii) considerable detection and prosecution of individual piracy can also reduce the profits of copyright holders (Tunca and Wu 2012). The last point while counter-intuitive can be partly explained by the fact that the substantial use of a product, even if pirated, could increase publicity and purchase of legal versions of the same product.

  4. If people think piracy is unfair, they are less likely to engage in the use of pirated software.

  5. Also see recent literature focusing on the effects of globalisation, in inter alia (i) trade (Shuaibu 2015); (ii) employment (Anyanwu 2014; Foster-McGregor et al. 2015); (iii) growth (Kummer-Noormamode 2014; Tumwebaze and Ijjo 2015) and (iv) welfare (Makochekanwa 2014).

  6. SIIA stands for Software and Information Industry Association.

  7. Data from the BSA primarily measures commercial software piracy. The interested reader can refer to Traphagan and Griffith (1998) and Png (2008) for more insights into the reliability of piracy data.

  8. These data have been used extensively in the piracy literature (Marron and Steel 2000; Banerjee et al. 2005; Andrés 2006a; Goel and Nelson 2009).

  9. According to the narrative, piracy is strongly associated with poverty or the proportion of the population in the low-income strata. This position is in accordance with the argument made by Moores and Esichaikul (2011, p. 1) that the motivations for software piracy is related with the cultural and economic circumstances of those indulging in software piracy.

  10. http://www.wipo.int/wipolex/en/.

  11. For evidence on how the data are collected, the interested reader can refer to the case of Indonesia: http://www.wipo.int/wipolex/en/profile.jsp?code=ID.

  12. The quantile estimator is disclosed without subscripts in Eq. (1) for the purpose of simplicity and ease of presentation.

  13. In other words, increasing income levels decrease the ability to pirate and the magnitude of the negative relationship increases with increasing piracy levels. For example, ceteris paribus a $500 average income (or GDP per capita) decreases software piracy more in countries where initial levels of software piracy are high compared to countries where initial levels of software piracy are low. Moreover, given that piracy levels are higher in low-income countries, ceteris paribus, the effect of an annual average income of $500 would have a higher decreasing effect in low-income countries than the same effect in high-income countries.

References

  • Abu-Bader, S., & Abu-Qarn, A. S. (2008). Financial development and economic growth: Empirical evidence from six MENA countries. Review of Development Economics, 12(4), 803–817.

    Google Scholar 

  • Adu, M. K., Alese, B. K., & Adetunmbi, A. O. (2014). Design of software user identity module (SUIM) for preventing software piracy. Lecture Notes in Engineering and Computer Science, 2211(1), 525–529.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andrés, A. R. (2006a). The relationship between copyright software protection and piracy: Evidence from Europe. European Journal of Law and Economics, 21(1), 29–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andrés, A. R. (2006b). Software piracy and income inequality. Applied Economic Letters, 13(2), 101–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andrés, A. R., & Asongu, S. A. (2013). Fighting software piracy: Which governance tools matter for Africa? Journal of Business Ethics, 118(3), 667–682.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andrés, A. R., & Goel, R. K. (2011). Corruption and software piracy: A comparative perspective. Policy & Internet, 3(3), 1–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andrés, A. R., & Goel, R. K. (2012). Does software piracy affect economic growth? Evidence across countries. Journal of Policy Modeling, 34(2), 284–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anyanwu, J. C. (2014). Does intra-African trade reduce youth unemployment in Africa? African Development Review, 26(2), 286–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asongu, S. A. (2013). Harmonizing IPRs on software piracy: Empirics of trajectories in Africa. Journal of Business Ethics, 118(1), 45–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asongu, S. A. (2014a). software piracy and scientific publications: Knowledge economy evidence from Africa. African Development Review, 26(4), 572–583.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asongu, S. A. (2014b). Software piracy, inequality and the poor: Evidence from Africa. Journal of Economic Studies, 41(4), 526–553.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asongu, S. A. (2015). Fighting software piracy in Africa: How do legal origins and IPRs protection channels matter? Journal of the Knowledge Economy, 6(4), 682–703.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bagchi, K., Kirs, P., & Cerveny, R. (2006). Global software piracy: Can economic factors alone explain the trend? Communications of the ACM, 49(6), 70–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee, D., Khalid, A. M., & Sturm, J.-E. (2005). Socio-economic development and software piracy: An empirical assessment. Applied Economics, 37(18), 2091–2097.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck, T., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., & Levine, R. (2003). Law and finance: Why does legal origin matter? Journal of Comparative Economics, 31(2003), 653–675.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bessen, J., & Maskin. E. (2000). Sequential innovation, patents, and imitation. Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Working Paper No. 00-01.

  • Bezmen, T. L., & Depken, C. A. (2004). The impact of software piracy on economic development. Working Paper. Francis Marion University.

  • Bezmen, T. L., & Depken, C. A. (2006). Influences on software piracy: Evidence from the various United States. Economics Letters, 90(3), 356–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Billger, S. M., & Goel, R. K. (2009). Do existing corruption levels matter in controlling corruption? Cross-country quantile regression estimates. Journal of Development Economics, 90(2), 299–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Business Software Alliance. (2007). 2006 Piracy study. BSA, New York

  • Business Software Alliance: BSA. (2009). What is software piracy? http://www.bsa.org/Piracy%20Portal.aspx. Accessed May 2012.

  • Douglas, D. E., Cronan, T. P., & Behel, J. D. (2007). Equity perceptions as a deterrent to software piracy behaviour. Information & Management, 44(5), 503–512.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Driouchi, A., Wang, M., & Driouchi, T. (2015). Determinants of software piracy under risk aversion: A model with empirical evidence. European Journal of Information Systems, 24(September), 519–530.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • El-Baily, N., & Gouda, M. (2011). Enforcing IPR through informal institutions: The possible role of religion in fighting software piracy (May 9, 2011). Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1950385 or doi:10.2139/ssrn.1950385. Retrieved October 12, 2015.

  • Falvey, R., Foster, N., & Greenway, D. (2006). Intellectual property rights and economic growth. Review of Development Economics, 10(4), 700–719.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foster-McGregor, N., Isaksson, A., & Kaulich, F. (2015). Foreign ownership and labour in Sub-Saharan African firms. African Development Review, 27(2), 130–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glass, R., & Wood, W. (1996). Situational determinants of software piracy: An equity theory perspective. Journal of Business Ethics, 15(11), 1189–1198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goel, R. K., & Nelson, M. A. (2009). Determinants of software piracy: Economics, institutions, and technology. Journal of Technology Transfer, 34(6), 637–658.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gould, D. M., & Gruben, W. C. (1996). The role of intellectual property rights in economic growth. Journal of Development Economics, 48(2), 323–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1991). Innovation and growth in the global economy. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, E. (1993). Innovation, imitation, and intellectual property rights. Econometrica, 61(6), 1247–1280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henry, P. B. (2007). Capital account liberalization: Theory, evidence and speculation. Journal of Economic Literature, 45(4), 887–935.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holm, H. J. (2003). Can economic theory explain piracy behavior? The B.E Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, 3(1), 1–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holm, P. (2014). Piracy on the simulated seas: The computer games industry’s non-legal approaches to fighting illegal downloads of games. Information & Communications Technology Law, 23(1), 61–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ki, E., Chang, B., & Khang, H. (2006). Exploring influential factors on music piracy across countries. Journal of Communication, 56(2), 406–426.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koenker, R., & Hallock, F. K. (2001). Quantile regression. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15(4), 143–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kose, M. A., Prasad, E. S., & Taylor, A. D. (2011). Threshold in the process of international financial integration. Journal of International Money and Finance, 30(1), 147–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kummer-Noormamode, S. (2014). Does trade with China have an impact on African countries growth? African Development Review, 26(2), 397–415.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lau, E. K.-W. (2006). Factors motivating people toward pirated software. Qualitative Market Research: An International Journal, 9(4), 404–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, J., & Mansfield, E. (1996). Intellectual property protection and U.S. foreign direct investment. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 78(2), 181–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lessig, L. (2001). The future of ideas: The fate of the commons in a connected world. New York: Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Makochekanwa, A. (2014). Welfare implications of COMESA-EAC-SADC tripartite free trade area. African Development Review, 26(1), 186–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. (1994). Intellectual property protection, foreign direct investment, and technology transfer. Washington, DC: International Finance Corporation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marron, D. B., & Steel, D. G. (2000). Which countries protect intellectual property? The case of software piracy. Economic Inquiry, 38(2), 147–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maskus, E. K. (2000). Intellectual property rights and economic development. Boulder: University of Colorado.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maskus, K. E., & Penubarti, M. (1995). How trade related are intellectual property rights? Journal of International Economics, 39(3–4), 227–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mlachila, M., Tapsoba, R., & Tapsoba, S. J. A. (2014). A quality of growth index for developing countries: A proposal. IMF Working Paper No. 14/172, Washington, DC

  • Moores, T. T., & Esichaikul, V. (2011). Socialization and software piracy: A study. Journal of Computer Information Systems, 51(3), 1–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Okada, K., & Samreth, S. (2012). The effect of foreign aid on corruption: A quantile regression approach. Economic Letters, 115(2), 240–243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peitz, M., & Waelbroeck, P. (2006). Piracy of digital products: A critical review of the theoretical literature. Information Economics and Policy, 18(4), 449–476.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piquero, N. L., & Piquero, A. R. (2006). Democracy and intellectual property: Examining trajectories of software piracy. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 1(605), 104–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Png, I. (2008). On the reliability of software piracy statistics. Mimeo: National University of Singapore.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rigobon, R., & Rodrik, D. (2004). Rule of law, democracy, openness and income: Estimating the interrelationships. The Economics of Transition, 13(3), 533–564.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. M. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), 71–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Santillanes, G., & Felder, R. (2015). Software piracy in research: A moral analysis. Science and Engineering Ethics, 21(4), 967–977.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saxegaard, M. (2006). Excess liquidity and effectiveness of monetary policy: Evidence from sub-Saharan Africa. IMF Working Paper No. 06/115, Washington, DC.

  • Seyoum, B. (1996). The impact of intellectual property rights on foreign direct investment. Columbia Journal of World Business, 31(1), 50–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shadlen, K., Schrank, A., & Kurtz, M. (2005). The political economy of intellectual property protection: The case of software. International Studies Quarterly, 49(1), 45–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shuaibu, M. (2015). Trade liberalization and intra-regional trade: A case of selected ECOWAS countries. African Development Review, 27(1), 27–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • SIIA (Software and Information Industry Association). (2000). SIIA report on global software piracy 2000. Washington, DC: Software and Information Industry Association.

  • Todaro, M. P., & Smith, S. C. (2015). Economic development (12th ed.). Harlow: Pearson Education.

    Google Scholar 

  • Traphagan, M., & Griffith, A. (1998). Software piracy and global competitiveness: Report on global software piracy. International Review of Law, Computers & Technology, 12(3), 431–451.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tumwebaze, H. K., & Ijjo, A. T. (2015). Regional economic integration and economic growth in the COMESA region, 1980–2010. African Development Review, 27(1), 67–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tunca, T. I., & Wu, Q. (2012). Fighting fire with fire: Commercial piracy and the role of file sharing on copyright protection policy for digital goods. Information Systems Research, 24(2), 436–453.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Kranenburg, H., & Hogenbirk, A. (2005). Multimedia, entertainment, and business software copyright piracy: A cross-national study. The Journal of Media Economics, 18(2), 109–129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang, G., & Maskus, K. E. (2001). Intellectual property rights, licensing, and innovation in an endogenous product-cycle model. Journal of International Economics, 53(1), 169–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yoo, C.-W., Sanders, G. L., Rhee, C., & Choe, Y.-C. (2011). The effect of deterrence policy in software piracy. Information and Development, 30(4), 342–357.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors are indebted to the editor and reviewers for their constructive comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Simplice A. Asongu.

Appendix

Appendix

See Tables 3, 4, and 5.

Table 3 Definitions of variables
Table 4 Summary statistics (1994–2010)
Table 5 Correlation analysis (uniform sample, n = 486)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Asongu, S.A., Singh, P. & Le Roux, S. Fighting Software Piracy: Some Global Conditional Policy Instruments. J Bus Ethics 152, 175–189 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-016-3291-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-016-3291-7

Keywords

Navigation