Skip to main content
Log in

The inverse problem for power distributions in committees

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Social Choice and Welfare Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Several power indices have been introduced in the literature in order to measure the influence of individual committee members on an aggregated decision. Here we ask the inverse question and aim to design voting rules for a committee such that a given desired power distribution is met as closely as possible. We generalize the approach of Alon and Edelman who studied power distributions for the Banzhaf index, where most of the power is concentrated on few coordinates. It turned out that each Banzhaf vector of an n-member committee that is near to such a desired power distribution, also has to be near to the Banzhaf vector of a k-member committee. We show that such Alon-Edelman type results exist for other power indices like e.g. the Public Good index or the Coleman index to prevent actions, while such results are principally impossible to derive for e.g. the Johnston index.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Arguably, some power indices, like the Banzhaf and the Shapley-Shubik index, are generally more accepted and applied than others. On the other hand, the pros and cons of several power indices are frequently discussed in the older and latest literature.

  2. As an example, we mention Brams et al. (1989) arguing that the Johnston index is best suited for measuring presidential power.

  3. There exists a stream of literature discussing the question of a fair power distribution within a committee, see e.g. Le Breton et al. (2012), Penrose (1946), Laruelle and Widgrén (1998), Shapley and Shubik (1954).

  4. There are several more recent papers using this denomination and trying to algorithmically attack this issue. Considerations about the problem itself date back further, see. e.g. Imrie (1973), Nurmi (1982), Papayanopoulos (1983).

  5. For completeness, we remark that there is also a stream of literature that characterizes the sets of general transferable utility games. These are more general objects than the voting procedures that we will study here. Given a certain solution concept, i.e. a more general object than a power index, their solution exactly coincides with a given vector, see e.g. Dragan (2005), Dragan (2012), Dragan (2013).

  6. Also the website http://powerslave.val.utu.fi/indices.html has served as a source.

  7. Several authors have tried to formalize such a common structure, see e.g. Bertini et al. (2013), Malawski (2004). Our approach is not claimed to be superior and has of course many similarities, but it seems to be more convenient in our situation.

  8. This constructive reformulation was already implicitly contained in the proof of Alon and Edelman (2010).

  9. See also (Taylor and Zwicker 1999, Definition 1.4.4, 1.4.7).

  10. We remark that the set of winning coalitions \(\mathcal {W}\) can be partitioned into the sets \(\mathcal {W}_A\) for all \(A\subseteq [k]\), so that we can implicitly define a game via the definition of the set of reduced games.

  11. The k-rounding operation is indeed a shortening function \(\mathcal {V}_n\times [n]\rightarrow \mathcal {V}_n\) for many of the most meaningful of classes \(\mathcal {V}_n\subseteq \overline{\mathcal {S}_n}\) mildly modified to satisfy a technical condition, see Lemma 4 and Corollary 1.

  12. with respect to the \(\Vert \cdot \Vert _1\)-norm.

  13. see Definition 7.(4).

  14. See also (Dubey and Shapley 1979, Corollary 1).

  15. We remark that the differences in the upper bounds are due to the tighter estimate of \(\left| \widehat{{\text {Bz}}}_i(v,2^{[n]})-\widehat{{\text {Bz}}}_i(v',2^{[n]})\right| \) in the second part of the proof of Theorem 2 compared to the estimation in Alon and Edelman (2010). The generalized bound would have been \(\Vert \widehat{P}(v')-\widehat{P}(v)\Vert _1\le \frac{(2kf_1(k)+1)\varepsilon '}{1-(kf_1(k)+1)\varepsilon '}+\varepsilon '\) using the original proof.

  16. Exceptions are power indices based on somewhat global properties like, e.g., the nucleolus, see Schmeidler (1969), and the minimum sum representation index, see Freixas and Kaniovski (2014).

  17. See Freixas and Kurz (2014) and Gvozdeva et al. (2013), where three hierarchies of simple games have been introduced.

References

  • Alon N, Edelman P (2010) The inverse Banzhaf problem. Soc Choice Welf 34(3):371–377

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alonso-Meijide J, Freixas J (2010) A new power index based on minimal winning coalitions without any surplus. Decis Support Syst 49(1):70–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alonso-Meijide J, Freixas J, Molinero X (2012) Computation of several power indices by generating functions. Appl Math Comput 219(8):3395–3402

    Google Scholar 

  • Banzhaf J (1965) Weighted voting doesn’t work: a mathematical analysis. Rutgers Law Rev 19:317–343

    Google Scholar 

  • Bertini C, Freixas J, Gambarelli G, Stach I (2013) Comparing power indices. Int. Game Theory Rev 15(2)

  • Bertini C, Gambarelli G, Stach I (2008) A public help index. In: Braham M, Steffen F (eds) Power, freedom, and voting. Springer, Berlin, pp 83–98

  • Bolger E (1986) Power indices for multicandidate voting games. Internat J Game Theory 15(3):175–186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Braham Me, Steffen Fe (2008) Power, freedom, and voting. In: Essays in honour of Manfred J. Holler. Papers presented at the Festschrift conference, Hamburg, August 17–20, 2006. Springer, Berlin, p 438 (xiv)

  • Brams S, Kilgour D, Affuso P (1989) Presidential power: a game-theoretic analysis. In: Brace P, Harrington C, King G (eds) The presidency in american politics. New York University Press, pp 55–74

  • Chang P-L, Chua V, Machover M (2006) LS Penrose’s limit theorem: tests by simulation. Math Soc Sci 51(1):90–106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coleman J (1971) Control of collectivities and the power of a collectivity to act. In: Lieberman B (ed) Social Choice. Gordon and Breach, pp 269–300

  • De A, Diakonikolas I, Feldman V, Servedio R (2012a) Nearly optimal solutions for the chow parameters problem and low-weight approximation of halfspaces. In: Proceedings of the 44th symposium on theory of computing, STOC ’12, pp 729–746. ACM, New York

  • De A, Diakonikolas I, Servedio R (2012b) The inverse Shapley value problem. In: Automata, Languages, and Programming, pp 266–277. Springer

  • de Keijzer B, Klos T, Zhang Y (2010) Enumeration and exact design of weighted voting games. In: Proceedings of the 9th international conference on autonomous agents and multiagent systems, vol 1, pp 391–398. International Foundation for Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems

  • de Keijzer B, Klos T, Zhang Y (2014) Finding optimal solutions for voting game design problems. J Artif Intell Res 50:105–140

    Google Scholar 

  • Deegan J Jr, Packel E (1978) A new index of power for simple \(n\)-person games. Internat J Game Theory 7(2):113–123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dragan I (2005) On the inverse problem for semivalues of cooperative TU games. Int J Pure Appl Math 22(4):545–561

    Google Scholar 

  • Dragan I (2012) On the inverse problem for multiweighted Shapley values of cooperative TU games. Int J Pure Appl Math 75(3):279–287

    Google Scholar 

  • Dragan I (2013) The inverse problem for binomial semivalues of cooperative TU games. In: Petrosyan LA, Zenkevich NA (eds) Game theory and management. Proceedings of the seventh international conference game theory and management. SPb.: Graduate School of Management SPbU, 2013, p 274, vol 26, p 72

  • Dubey P, Neyman A, Weber R (1981) Value theory without efficiency. Math Oper Res 6(1):122–128

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dubey P, Shapley L (1979) Mathematical properties of the Banzhaf power index. Math Oper Res 4(2):99–131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Felsenthal D, Machover M (1998) The measurement of voting power: Theory and practice, problems and paradoxes, vol xviii, p 322. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

  • Felsenthal D, Machover M (2005) Voting power measurement: a story of misreinvention. Soc Choice Welf 25(2–3):485–506

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freixas J, Kaniovski S (2014) The minimum sum representation as an index of voting power. Eur J Oper Res 233(3):739–748

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freixas J, Kurz S (2014) On \(\alpha \)-roughly weighted games. Internat J Game Theory 43(3):659–692

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freixas J, Zwicker W (2003) Weighted voting, abstention, and multiple levels of approval. Soc Choice Welf 21(3):399–431

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freixas J, Zwicker W (2009) Anonymous yes-no voting with abstention and multiple levels of approval. Games Econ Behav 67(2):428–444

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gvozdeva T, Hemaspaandra L, Slinko A (2013) Three hierarchies of simple games parameterized by “resource” parameters. Internat J Game Theory 42(1):1–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holler M (1982) Forming coalitions and measuring voting power. Polit Stud 30(2):262–271

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Imrie R (1973) The impact of the weighted vote on representation in municipal governing bodies of New York State. Ann New York Acad Sci 219(1):192–199

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Isbell J (1958) A class of simple games. Duke Math J 25:423–439

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnston R (1978) On the measurement of power: some reactions to Laver. Environ Plann A 10(8):907–914

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • König T, Bräuninger T (2001) Decisiveness and inclusiveness: Intergovernmental choice of European decision rules. In: Holler MJ, Owen G (eds) Power indices and coalition formation. Kluwer, pp 273–290

  • Kurz S (2012a) On minimum sum representations for weighted voting games. Ann Oper Res 196(1):361–369

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurz S (2012b) On the inverse power index problem. Optimization 61(8):989–1011

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurz S (2014) Measuring voting power in convex policy spaces. Economies 2(1):45–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurz S, Napel S (2014) Heuristic and exact solutions to the inverse power index problem for small voting bodies. Ann Oper Res 215(1):137–163

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurz S, Napel S, Nohn A (2014) The nucleolus of large majority games. Econ Lett 123(3):139–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laruelle A, Valenciano F (2011) Voting and collective decision-making. Bargaining and power. Reprint of the 2008 hardback ed., vol xvii, p 184. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

  • Laruelle A, Valenciano F (2013) Voting and power. In: Power, Voting, and voting power: 30 years after, pp 137–149. Springer

  • Laruelle A, Widgrén M (1998) Is the allocation of voting power among EU states fair? Public Choice 94(3–4):317–339

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Le Breton M, Montero M, Zaporozhets V (2012) Voting power in the EU Council of Ministers and fair decision making in distributive politics. Math Soc Sci 63(2):159–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindner I, Machover M (2004) LS Penrose’s limit theorem: proof of some special cases. Math Soc Sci 47(1):37–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindner I, Owen G (2007) Cases where the Penrose limit theorem does not hold. Math Soc Sci 53(3):232–238

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malawski M (2004) “Counting” power indices for games with a priori unions. Theory Decis 56(1–2):125–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milnor J, Shapley L (1978) Values of large games II: oceanic games. Math Oper Res 3(4):290–307

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neyman A (1982) Renewal theory for sampling without replacement. Ann Prob, pp 464–481

  • Nurmi H (1980) Game theory and power indices. Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 40(1–2):35–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nurmi H (1982) The problem of the right distribution of voting power. In: Power, voting, and voting power, pp 203–212. Springer

  • O’Donnell R, Servedio R (2011) The chow parameters problem. SIAM J Comput 40(1):165–199

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Papayanopoulos L (1983) On the partial construction of the semi-infinite Banzhaf polyhedron. In: Fiacco A, Kortanek K (eds) Semi-infinite programming and applications, lecture notes in economics and mathematical systems, vol 215, pp 208–218. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Penrose L (1946) The elementary statistics of majority voting. J R Stat Soc 109:53–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmeidler D (1969) The nucleolus of a characteristic function game. SIAM J Appl Math 17:1163–1170

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro N, Shapley L (1978) Values of large games, I: a limit theorem. Math Oper Res 3(1):1–9

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapley L (1953) A value for \(n\)-person games. Contrib. Theory of Games. Ann Math Stud

  • Shapley L, Shubik M (1954) A method for evaluating the distribution of power in a committee system. Am Polit Sci Rev 48(03):787–792

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Straffin P (1977) Homogeneity, independence, and power indices. Public Choice 30(1):107–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor A, Zwicker W (1999) Simple games, desirability relations, trading, pseudoweightings. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank two anonymous referees for their very valuable and extensive comments on an earlier draft of this paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sascha Kurz.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Details for quality function results

In this section we want to prove the missing details for the quality function results announced in Table 1. Since we have started with the proof for the Public Good Index, in Sect. 4.2, we want to continue with the Deegan-Packel index, which arises as the equal division of the \({\text {PGI}}\), see Definition 13.

We can exploit this relation by setting \(\widehat{C}^{{\text {DP}}}=\sum _{i=k+1}^n C_i^{{\text {DP}}}\) and denoting the number of minimal winning coalitions that contain at least one member of (kn] by \(\widehat{M}^{{\text {PGI}}}\). With this we have:

Lemma 13

$$\begin{aligned} \widehat{M}^{{\text {PGI}}}\le \widehat{C}^{{\text {DP}}}\cdot (k+1) \end{aligned}$$

Proof

Let S be a minimal winning coalition that contains at least one player from (kn]. We set \(a:=\left| S\cap [1,k]\right| \) and \(b:=\left| S\cap (k,n]\right| \), so that \(a+b=|S|\), \(0\le a\le k\), and \(1\le b\le n-k\). Thus, the stated inequality follows from \(\sum \nolimits _{i=k+1}^n C_i^{{\text {DP}}}(v,S)=\frac{b}{a+b}\ge \frac{1}{k+1}\), where \(v\) denotes the respective game.

Corollary 3

For the Deegan-Packel index we can choose \(f_1(k)=(k+1)^2\).

Lemma 14

Let \(v\) be a complete simple game with player set \([n]\) and \(S\subseteq [n]\) be a coalition. The number of direct left-shifts of S is bounded by \(|S|+1\) and \(\left\lfloor \frac{n+1}{2}\right\rfloor \).

Proof

W.l.o.g. we assume \(1\succeq 2\succeq \cdots \succeq n\). A direct left-shift of S arises either by shifting a player of S one place to the left or by adding the weakest player n. For the other bound we observe that player i can only be shifted to position \(i-1\) if \(i-1\notin S\) and \(i\ne 1\). Thus only \(\left\lfloor \frac{n}{2}\right\rfloor \) players can be shifted one position to the left, where equality is only possible if either n is odd or n is even and \(n\in S\). Considering the possible addition of player n given at most \(\left\lfloor \frac{n+1}{2}\right\rfloor \) cases.

Lemma 15

For the Shift index we can choose \(f_1(k)=\frac{k+3}{2}\).

Proof

Let \(v=(\mathcal {W},[n])\) be an arbitrary simple game. As defined before, \(C_i^{{\text {Shift}}}(v,2^{[n]})\) counts the number of shift-minimal winning coalitions in \(v\) containing player i and we have \(\overline{C}^{{\text {Shift}}}(v,2^{[n]})=\sum _{i=1}^n C_i^{{\text {Shift}}}(v,2^{[n]})\). For brevity we just write \(C_i\) and \(\overline{C}\). As further abbreviations we use \(v'=(\mathcal {W}',[n])\) for the k-rounding of \(v\), \(\widehat{C}=\sum _{i=k+1}^n C_i\), i.e. the restriction of \(\overline{C}\) to the players in (kn], and by \(\widehat{M}\) we denote the number of shift-minimal winning coalitions in \(v\) that contain at least one player from (kn]. With this we have \(\widehat{M}\le \widehat{C}\).

Now we want to study the changes in the \(C_i\) by going from \(v\) to \(v'\). At first we consider the cases where coalition S is a SMWC (shift-minimal winning coalition) in \(v\) but not in \(v'\).

  1. (1)

    If \(S\cap (k,n]\ne \emptyset \) then removing S from \(v\) results in a decrease of 1 for player i and there is at least one player in (kn]. Thus the negative change of the \(C_i\) of that type is bounded by \(\widehat{M}\le \widehat{C}\).

  2. (2)

    If \(S\subseteq [1,k]\), then S is winning in \(v'\) too. Since S is not a SMWC in \(v'\) (by assumption), there must be a direct right-shift \(S'=S{\backslash } j\cup h\) of S, where \(j\in S\), \(h\in [1,k]{\backslash } S\) or \(h=\emptyset \), such that \(S'\) is winning in \(v'\). According to the rounding procedure, there is a subset \(\emptyset \ne T\subseteq 2^{(k,n]}\) such that \(S'\cup T\) is a SMWC in \(v\). Given \(S'\) there are at most \(\frac{k+1}{2}\) choices for S, see Lemma 14. Thus, we have that the negative change is bounded by \(\frac{k+1}{2}\cdot \widehat{M}\le \frac{k+1}{2}\cdot \widehat{C}\).

Next, we consider the cases where coalition S is not a SMWC in \(v\) but in \(v'\). Since the players in (kn] are null players, we can deduce \(S\in 2^{[1,k]}\).

  1. (3)

    Assume that S is losing in \(v\) but winning in \(v'\). According to the rounding procedure there exists coalition \(\emptyset \ne T\in 2^{(k,n]}\) such that \(S\cup T\) is a SMWC in \(v\). Thus, the total increase for \(C_i\) is bounded by \(\widehat{M}\le \widehat{C}\).

  2. (4)

    If S is winning in \(v\), then there must be a direct right-shift \(S'\) such that \(S'\) is winning in \(v\) but losing in \(v'\). We proceed similarly as in case (2) and deduce an upper bound of \(\frac{k+1}{2}\cdot \widehat{M}\) for the change of \(C_i\).

By proving the bound \(\widehat{M}^{{\text {Shift}}}\le \widehat{C}^{{\text {SDP}}}\cdot (k+1)\), similar to the proof of Lemma 13, we can conclude \(f_1(k)=\frac{k+3}{2}\).

Corollary 4

For the Shift Deegan-Packel index we can choose \(f_1(k)=\frac{(k+1)(k+3)}{2}\).

Lemma 16

For \({\text {ColPrev}}\) we can choose \(f_1(k)=2\).

Proof

Let us write \(\eta _i(v,2^{[n]})=C_i^{{\text {swing}}}(v,2^{[n]})\) for the number of swings for player i and \(\overline{\eta }(v,2^{[n]})=\overline{C}^{{\text {swing}}}(v,2^{[n]})\). By \(v'\) we denote \({\varGamma }(v,k)\), where \({\varGamma }\) is the k-rounding function. From Lemmas 8 and 5 we conclude

$$\begin{aligned} \left| \eta _i(v',2^{[n]})-\eta _i(v,2^{[n]})\right| \le \varepsilon \cdot \overline{\eta }(v,2^{[n]}) \end{aligned}$$
(1)

for all \(1\le i\le k\). By \(\mathcal {W}(v)\) and \(\mathcal {W}(v')\) we denote the set of winning coalitions of \(v\) and \(v'\), respectively. From the proof of Lemma 8 we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \Big \vert |\mathcal {W}(v')|-|\mathcal {W}(v)|\Big \vert \le \varepsilon \cdot \overline{\eta }(v,2^{[n]}). \end{aligned}$$
(2)

With this we conclude

$$\begin{aligned}&\left| \frac{\eta _i(v',2^{[n]})}{|\mathcal {W}(v')|}-\frac{\eta _i(v,2^{[n]})}{|\mathcal {W}(v)|}\right| \\&\quad \le \left| \frac{\eta _i(v',2^{[n]})}{|\mathcal {W}(v)|}-\frac{\eta _i(v,2^{[n]})}{|\mathcal {W}(v)|}\right| +\left| \frac{\eta _i(v',2^{[n]})}{|\mathcal {W}(v')|}-\frac{\eta _i(v',2^{[n]})}{|\mathcal {W}(v)|}\right| \\&\quad = \frac{\left| \eta _i(v',2^{[n]})-\eta _i(v,2^{[n]})\right| }{|\mathcal {W}(v)|} +\frac{\eta _i(v',2^{[n]})}{|\mathcal {W}(v')|}\cdot \frac{\Big \vert |\mathcal {W}(v')|-|\mathcal {W}(v)|\Big \vert }{|\mathcal {W}(v)|}\\&\quad \le \frac{\varepsilon \cdot \overline{\eta }(v,2^{[n]})}{|\mathcal {W}(v)|}+ \frac{\eta _i(v',2^{[n]})}{|\mathcal {W}(v')|}\cdot \frac{\varepsilon \cdot \overline{\eta }(v,2^{[n]})}{|\mathcal {W}(v)|}\\&\quad \le 2\cdot \frac{\varepsilon \cdot \overline{\eta }(v,2^{[n]})}{|\mathcal {W}(v)|} \end{aligned}$$

where we have used the triangle inequality, Inequality (1), Inequality (2), and the fact that the number of swings for player i cannot be larger than the number of winning coalitions. Thus we can choose \(f_1(k)=2\).

Lemma 17

For \({\text {ColIni}}\) we can choose \(f_1(k)=2\).

Proof

As pointed out in e.g. Dubey et al. (1981) \({\text {ColIni}}(v)\) equals \({\text {ColPrev}}(v^\star )\), where \(v^\star \) denotes the dual game of \(v\), see e.g. Taylor and Zwicker (1999) for a definition. Since the class of simple games is closed under taking the dual and \(\widehat{{\text {ColIni}}}=\widehat{{\text {ColPrev}}}\), we can chose the same quality function as in Lemma 16.

Appendix 2: Technical details for the (absolute) Johnston index

In this section we provide the delayed proof from Sect. 4.3. Before going into the details, we provide a useful bound for binomial coefficients:

Lemma 18

For integers \(1\le m\le n\) we have \( {{n-1}\atopwithdelims (){m-1}}\le \frac{2^{n-1}}{\sqrt{n}} \).

Proof

Since the binomial coefficients attain their maximum at the center, it suffices to prove the proposed inequality for \(m-1=\left\lfloor \frac{n-1}{2}\right\rfloor \). For \(t\ge 1\) we have \({{2t}\atopwithdelims ()t}\le \frac{2^{2t}}{\sqrt{3t+1}}\). From \({{2t-1}\atopwithdelims (){t-1}}+{{2t-1}\atopwithdelims (){t}}={{2t}\atopwithdelims (){t}}\) and \({{2t-1}\atopwithdelims (){t-1}}={{2t-1}\atopwithdelims (){t}}\), we conclude \({{2t-1}\atopwithdelims (){t-1}}\le \frac{2^{2t-1}}{\sqrt{3t+1}}\) for all \(t\ge 1\). Thus, we have \({{n-1}\atopwithdelims (){m-1}}\le \frac{2^{n-1}}{\sqrt{n}}\) for all \(n\ge 1\).

Lemma 19

For \(l=1\) and integers kmn satisfying the restrictions from Definition 18 and \(1\le m\le n\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{rll} \displaystyle {\text {JS}}_i(v_{n,m}^{k,l}) &{}= \displaystyle \sum _{j=0}^n {n \atopwithdelims ()j}\cdot 1 +\sum _{j=0}^{m-1}{n \atopwithdelims ()j}\cdot 1 =2^n+\sum _{j=0}^{m-1}{n \atopwithdelims ()j} &{}\quad \forall i\in [1,k) \\ \displaystyle {\text {JS}}_k(v_{n,m}^{k,l}) &{}= \displaystyle \sum _{j=m+1}^{n}{n \atopwithdelims ()j}\cdot 1\,+\,{n \atopwithdelims ()m}\cdot \frac{1}{m+1}&{}\,\\ \displaystyle {\text {JS}}_i(v_{n,m}^{k,l}) &{}= \displaystyle {{n-1} \atopwithdelims (){m-1}}\cdot \frac{1}{m+1}&{} \quad \forall i\in (k,k+n] \\ \displaystyle {\text {JS}}_i(v_{n,n+1}^{k,l}) &{}= \displaystyle \sum _{j=0}^n {n \atopwithdelims ()j}\cdot 1 =2^n&{} \quad \forall i\in [1,k] \\ {\text {JS}}_i(v_{n,n+1}^{k,l}) &{}= 0&{} \quad \forall i\in (k,k+n] \\ \displaystyle {\text {JS}}_i(v_{n,0}^{k,l}) &{}= \displaystyle \sum _{j=0}^{n+1} {n \atopwithdelims ()j}\cdot 1 =2^{n+1}&{} \quad \forall i\in [1,k) \\ {\text {JS}}_i(v_{n,0}^{k,l}) &{}= 0&{} \quad \forall i\in [k,k+n] \\ \xi ^{{\text {JS}}} &{}= \displaystyle n\cdot {{n-1} \atopwithdelims (){m-1}}\cdot \frac{1}{m+1}.&{}\, \end{array} \end{aligned}$$

Proof

We note that all swing coalitions are of the form \(\{i\}\cup T\), \(\{i,k\}\cup T\), and \(\{k\}\cup T\), where \(1\le i\le k-1\) and \(\emptyset \subseteq T\subseteq (k,n+k]\).

Proof

(of Lemma 12) From Lemmas 18 and 19 we conclude \( {\text {JS}}_i(v_{n,m}^{k,l}) = 3\cdot 4^{\tilde{n}}\quad \forall i\in [1,k)\), \({\text {JS}}_k(v_{n,m}^{k,l}) \ge 4^{\tilde{n}} -\frac{\sqrt{2}\cdot 4^{\tilde{n}}}{\sqrt{\tilde{n}+1}}\), \({\text {JS}}_k(v_{n,m}^{k,l}) \le 4^{\tilde{n}}\), and \(\xi ^{{\text {JS}}} \le \frac{\sqrt{2}\cdot 4^{\tilde{n}}}{\sqrt{\tilde{n}}}\). For \(\tilde{n}\ge 1\) we then have

$$\begin{aligned} \Vert {\text {JS}}(v_{n,m}^{k,l})-{\text {JS}}(v_{n,n+1}^{k,l})\Vert _1\ge & {} k\cdot 4^{\tilde{n}}+\xi ^{{\text {JS}}} \ge \left( k\cdot \frac{\sqrt{\tilde{n}}}{\sqrt{2}}+1\right) \xi ^{{\text {JS}}},\\ \Vert {\text {JS}}(v_{n,m}^{k,l})-{\text {JS}}(v_{n,0}^{k,l})\Vert _1\ge & {} k\cdot 4^{\tilde{n}} -\frac{\sqrt{2}\cdot 4^{\tilde{n}}}{\sqrt{\tilde{n}+1}}+\xi ^{{\text {JS}}} \ge (k-1)4^{\tilde{n}}+\xi ^{{\text {JS}}}\\\ge & {} \left( (k-1)\cdot \frac{\sqrt{\tilde{n}}}{\sqrt{2}}+1\right) \xi ^{{\text {JS}}},\text { and }\lim \nolimits _{\tilde{n}\rightarrow \infty } \frac{\xi ^{{\text {JS}}}}{\sum \limits _{i=1}^{n+k} {\text {JS}}_i(v_{n,m}^{k,l})}= 0. \end{aligned}$$

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kurz, S. The inverse problem for power distributions in committees. Soc Choice Welf 47, 65–88 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-015-0946-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-015-0946-8

Mathematics Subject Classification

Navigation