Skip to main content
Log in

Who bears the full cost of children? Evidence from a collective demand system

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper measures how the costs of children are shared between the father and the mother by estimating a gender-specific demand system related to the demand for market goods, household products and leisure within a collective approach. The estimates illustrate how the intra-household distribution of resources varies across households with and without children and how wages and non-labor income affect the allocation rule in both single-earner and double-earner households. In the presence of a child, both parents, but mothers especially, increase their involvement in home production at the expense of the enjoyment of leisure. This commitment decreases as the child gets older. In general, mothers control less than half of the household resources, while they bear more than half of the cost of maintaining a child.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Note that the household technology includes the full set of exogenous characteristics, while the utility function only hosts the demographic characteristics of the household members.

  2. The market approach is plausible when the domestic production is marketable, as it is the case of agricultural households or household–enterprises, or when it can be substituted with goods and services bought on an outside market at a given price. For example, meals can be taken at home or at a restaurant, a home-made cake has its perfect substitute in a pastry shop, a maid can be hired to clean the house, and so on. In this case, the market price of the equivalent service determines the trade-off between internal production and outside trade. This method requires a distinction between different types of domestic work and the evaluation of each one to the corresponding price of market specialists. Because information on the prices of specific household activities was not available, we could not apply this approach to our analysis.

  3. The superscript notation is associated with endogenous variables, while subscripts index exogenous variables.

  4. Because the level of the household product cannot be observed, the assumption of homotheticity (or constant return to scale) is a maintained hypothesis in collective models with household production (Apps and Rees 2002; Rapoport et al. 2011). See also Pollak and Watcher’s (1975) and Pollak (2011) discussion of the issue of constant return to scale in household production.

  5. Rapoport et al. (2011), in analogy with the distribution factors affecting the distribution rule but not preferences, term such production characteristics “pure production factors” because affect the production technology only, leaving preferences unchanged.

  6. It is interesting to note that the indirect utility function with a Gorman polar form implies a unitary model and the pooling of incomes because the aggregate demand behaves as if it were the demand of a single consumer (Bergstrom 1997:10). As pointed out by Bergstrom himself (1997: 10), in the case of a translation, utilities may be different for different people. The indirect utility described in Eq. (3) incorporates both translating and scaling of the income term.

  7. The functional form of the sharing rule is linear in the logarithms as it is implicitly assumed by Chiappori, Fortin and Lacroix (2002, eq. 10). Our functional form does not include interaction terms because not necessary for identification (Menon and Perali 2012) and implements the condition of income independence of the sharing rule also adopted by the identification strategy of Dunbar et al. (2013) and shown to be empirically robust in Menon et al. (2012).

  8. In the present context, the sharing rule can be thought as the analogous of a demographic function that instead of scaling prices as in the Barten (1964) tradition, scales income.

  9. Pollak and Wales (1979) show that equivalence scales suffer from a fundamental identification problem and criticize the possibility of meaningful welfare comparisons. For a recent discussion of these issues in the context of needs based equivalence scales, we refer to the paper by Menon and Perali (2010). Indifference scales introduced by Lewbel (2004) and later further developed also in Dunbar et al. (2013) and Browning et al. (2013) are defined as the lowest cost for, say, a woman living alone to attain the same indifference curve she attained living with the spouse. Indifference scales do solve the identification problem without having to resort to often-untestable assumptions regarding comparability of utility across individuals. Indeed, indifference scales implement interpersonal not inter-household comparisons and are not informative about the cost of children.

  10. See, for example, Apps and Rees (2002).

  11. The absence of comprehensive data sets including information about “who does what and when” and who consumes what in the family poses considerable challenges in terms of extra modeling effort and identifying assumptions. More comprehensive data are indeed to be collected, possibly within the same survey, to obtain more complete and robust answers to the research questions considered here.

  12. The linking procedure may modify the original properties of the source data sets. Because of imputation, measurement errors due to the exclusion of unmatched units or the erroneous match, or overrepresentation of matched units may arise and relevant information may be lost (Chesher and Nesheim 2006). Both the SHIW and the TBS contain information on socio-demographic characteristics of the households—such as household composition, age and level of education of each household member—which are relevant in explaining time use choices. Addabbo and Caiumi (2003) check whether the records drawn from the different data sources with reference to the selected household types, that is, couples with and without children, belong to the same population by testing the distance between different data sources.

  13. In particular, the matching procedure adopted in Addabbo and Caiumi (2003) can be illustrated as follows: To impute the variable of interest, \(y^{\prime }\), into the survey where it is unobserved, the authors take the conditional mean of the regression obtained from the survey where the \(y\) is observed, \({E}(y{\vert }{X}_{1})= \upbeta {X}_{1}\), and substitute the exogenous variables drawn from the survey where it is missing, \({X}_{0}\). The standard error of the regression is added, in order to reproduce as best as possible the unobserved heterogeneity not captured by the conditional mean of the regression. The variable of interest is then computed as \({y}^{\prime }=\upbeta {X}_{0}+\sigma _{\upvarepsilon }\). To test the matching procedure, the authors compare the estimated hours of work—devoted to child care, domestic activities and constrained time—and the observed data for the selected TBS subsample. They show that the simulated distribution is statistically close to the observed one on the basis of the first and second moments.

  14. It is worth noticing that this selection rule may generate a selection bias. However, our major concern was to maintain the comparability of our results with the original work by Apps and Rees. Non-participation, full or part time, is an extension of the collective model that has been treated in contexts without household production (Donni 2003; Blundell et al. 2007) only from a theoretical point of view. To the best of our knowledge, this important aspect has not been empirically implemented yet.

  15. Browning and Bonke (2009) distinguish three items categories: (a) assignable items because bought exclusively for one member, (b) assignable items because bought exclusively for the other member and (c) non-assignable items bought for the household such as food.

  16. We recognize that market wages for women fully employed in household production at best provide a lower bound to the real opportunity cost of their time. We thank a referee for this comment.

  17. As expected, we find that wages for females employed in the labor market, according to the same test, are exogenous.

References

  • Addabbo T, Caiumi A (2003) Extended income and inequality by gender in Italy. In: Picchio A (ed) Unpaid work and the economy: a gender analysis of the standards of living. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Apps P, Rees R (1996) Labor supply, household production and intra-family welfare distribution. J Public Econ 60:199–219

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Apps P, Rees R (1997) Collective labor supply and household production. J Polit Econ 105:178–190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Apps P, Rees R (2002) Household production, full consumption and the costs of children. Labour Econ 8:621–648

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Apps P, Rees R (2009) Public economics and the household. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Arias C, Atella V, Castagnini R, Perali F (2004) Estimation of the sharing rule between adults and children and related equivalence scales within a collective framework. In: Dagum C, Ferrari G (eds) Household behavior, equivalence scales, welfare and poverty. Physica-Verlag, Heidelberg

    Google Scholar 

  • Aronsson TS, Daunfeldt O, Wilkström M (2001) Estimating intra-household allocation in a collective model with household production. J Popul Econ 14:569–584

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barten AP (1964) Family Composition, Prices, and Expenditure Patterns. In: Hart P, Mills G, Whitaker JK (eds) Econometric analysis for national economic planning, 16th symposium of the Colston society. Butterworth, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrom T (1997) A survey of theories of the family. In: Rosenzweig M, Stark O (eds) Handbook of population and family economics. Elsevier, North Holland, Ch.4, pp. 125–187

  • Blackorby C, Donaldson D (1991) Adult equivalence scales, interpersonal comparisons of well-being and applied welfare economics. In: Elster J, Roemer JE (eds) Interpersonal comparisons of well-being. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Chiappori PA, Meghir C (2005) Collective labor supply with children. J Polit Econ 113(6):1277–1306 University of Chicago Press

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Chiappori PA, Magnac T, Meghir C (2007) Collective labour supply: heterogeneity and non-participation. Rev Econ Stud 74:417–445

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bollino A, Perali F, Rossi N (2000) Linear household technologies. J Appl Econom 15:275–287

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bourguignon F (1999) The cost of children: may the collective approach to household behaviour help? J Popul Econ 12:503–521

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bourguignon F, Chiuri MC (2005) Labor market time and home production: a new test for collective models of intra-household allocation. Centre for Studies in Economics and Finance, CSEF working paper no. 131

  • Bradbury B (1994) Measuring the cost of children. Aust Econ Pap 33:120–138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradbury B (2004a) Using time-use data to estimate the full costs of children working paper, Social Policy Research Centre, Sydney, Australia

  • Bradbury B (2004b) The Price, cost, consumption and value of children. Social Policy Research Centre discussion paper no 132

  • Bradbury B (2004c) Consumption and the within-household income distribution: outcomes from an Australian ‘Natural Experiment’. CESifo Econ Stud 50(3):501–540

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradbury B (2008) Time and the cost of children. Rev Income Wealth 54(3):305–323

  • Browning M, Chiappori PA (1998) Efficient intra-household allocations: a general characterization and empirical tests. Econometrica 66:1241–1278

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning M, Chiappori PA, Lewbel A (2013) Estimating consumption economies of scales, adult equivalent scales and household bargaining power. Rev Econ Stud 80:1267–1303

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning M, Bourguignon F, Chiappori PA, Lechene V (1994) Income and outcomes: a structural model of intra-household allocation. J Polit Econ 102(6):1067–1096

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning M, Chiappori PA, Lechene V (2006) Collective and unitary models: a clarification. Rev Econ Househ 4(1):5–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning M, Bonke J (2009) Allocation within the household: direct survey evidence. Economics Series working papers 429, University of Oxford, Department of Economics

  • Browning M, Chiappori PA, Weiss Y (2014) Economics of the family. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Chesher A, Nesheim L (2006) Review of the statistical properties of linked datasets. DTI Occasional Papers series, no. 3. Department of Trade and Industry, UK

  • Chiappori PA (1988) Rational household labor supply. Econometrica 56(1):63–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori PA (1992) Collective labor supply and welfare. J Polit Econ 100(3):437–467

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori PA (1997) Introducing household production in collective models of labor supply. J Polit Econ 105:191–209

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori PA, Fortin B, Lacroix G (2002) Marriage market, divorce legislation, and household labor supply. J Polit Econ 110(1):37–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D’Orazio M, Di Zio M, Scanu M (2006) Statistical matching: theory and practice. Wiley, Chichester

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Donni O (2003) Collective household labor supply: nonparticipation and income taxation. J Public Econ 87:1179–1198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunbar G, Lewbel A, Pendakur K (2013) Children’s resources in collective households: identification, estimation and an application to child poverty in Malawi. Am Econ Rev 103:438–471

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ebert U, Moyes P (2003) Equivalence scales reconsidered. Econometrica 71:319–343

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ebert U, Moyes P (2009) Household decisions and equivalence scales. J Popul Econ 22:1039–1062

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallezzoni S, Romano MC, Corsetti G, Di Zio M, D’Orazio M, Pintaldi F, Scanu M, Torelli N (2008) Time use and labor force: a proposal to integrate the data through statistical matching. In: Romano MC (ed) Time use in daily life. A multidisciplinary approach to the Time Use’s Analysis. Istat, Argomenti, vol 35, pp 297–323

  • Goldberger AS (1972) Maximum-likelihood estimation of regressions containing unobservable independent variables. Int Econ Rev 13(1):1–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham J, Green C (1984) Estimating the parameters of a household production function with joint products. Rev Econ Stat 66(2):277–282

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gronau R (1973) The effect of children on the housewife’s value of time. J Polit Econ 81(2):168–199

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jenkins S, O’Leary NC (1994) Household income plus household production: the distribution of extended income in the U.K. discussion paper 94-14, University of Wales, Swansea

  • Jenkins S, O’Leary NC (1995) Modelling domestic work time. J Popul Econ 8:265–279

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jenkins S, O’Leary NC (1996) Household income plus household production: the distribution of extended income in the UK. Rev Income Wealth 42(4):401–419

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalugina E, Radtchenko N, Sofer C (2009) How do spouses share their full income? Identification of the sharing rule using self-reported income. Rev Income Wealth 55(2):360–391

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kerkhofs M, Kooreman P (2003) Identification and estimation of a class of household production models. J Appl Econom 18(3):337–369

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koulovatianos C, Schröder C, Schmidt U (2009) Nonmarket household time and the cost of children. J Bus Econ Stat 27:42–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewbel A (1985) A unified approach to incorporating demographics or other effects into demand systems. Rev Econ Stud 70:1–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewbel A (1989) Household equivalence scales and welfare comparisons. J Public Econ 39:377–391

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewbel A (1997) Consumer demand systems and household equivalence scales. In: Pesaran MH, Schmidt P (eds) Handbook of applied econometrics. Volume II: microeconomics. Blackwell, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewbel A (2004) Equivalence scales based on collective household ‘models. In: Dagum C, Ferrari G (eds) Household behavior, equivalence scales, welfare and poverty. Physica-Verlag, Heidelberg

    Google Scholar 

  • Lundberg S, Pollak R, Wales T (1997) Do husbands and wives pool their resources? Evidence from U.K. child benefit. J Hum Resour 22:463–480

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Menon M, Perali F (2010) Econometric identification of the cost of maintaining a child. In: Bishop JA (ed) studies in applied welfare analysis: papers from the third ECINEQ meeting (research on economic inequality, volume 18), Emerald Group Publishing Limited, pp 219–255

  • Menon M, Perali F (2012) The Sharing Rule: where is it? Working Paper WP 16/2012, Department of Economics, University of Verona

  • Menon M, Pendakur K, Perali F (2012) On the expenditure-dependence of resource shares. Econ Lett 117:739–742

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perali F (2003) The behavioral and welfare analysis of consumption. Kluwer Academic Publishers, The Netherland

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Phipps SH (1997) What is the income “Cost of a Child”? Exact equivalence scales for Canadian two-parent families. Rev Econ Stat 80:157–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pollak R, Wales T (1979) Welfare comparisons and equivalence scales. Am Econ Rev 69:216–221

    Google Scholar 

  • Pollak R, Wales T (1981) Demographic variables in demand analysis. Econometrica 49(6):1533–1551

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pollak R, Wales T (1992) Demand system specification and estimation. OUP, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Pollak R, Watcher M (1975) The relevance of the household production function and its implications for the allocation of time. J Polit Econ 68:349–359

    Google Scholar 

  • Pollak R (2011) Allocating time: individuals’ technologies, household technologies, perfect substitution and specialization. National Bureau of Economic Research, working paper 17529

  • Prasard ES, Utili F (1998) The Italian Labour Market: Stylised Facts, Institutions and Directions for Reform. IMF working paper/98/42

  • Rapoport B, Sofer C (2004) ”Pure” production factors and the sharing rule: estimating collective models with household production. Communication to the IATUR conference, Rome

  • Rapoport B, Sofer C, Solaz A (2011) Household production in a collective model: some new results. J Popul Econ 24(1):23–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singh A, Mantel H, Kinack M, Rowe G (1993) Statistical matching: use of auxiliary information as an alternative to the conditional independence assumption. Surv Methodol 19:59–79

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors wish to thank Maria Concetta Chiuri, Alessandro Cigno, Panayiota Lyssiotou, Martina Menon, Nathalie Picard, Ray Rees, Daniela Vuri and two anonymous referees for helpful comments. All errors and omissions are the authors’ own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Federico Perali.

Appendix 1: Estimation results

Appendix 1: Estimation results

See Tables 8, 9 and 10

Table 8 Estimation of the potential wage equation for women
Table 9 Estimation of gender-specific demand equations for non-traditional (double-earner) households
Table 10 Estimation of gender-specific demand equations for traditional (single-earner) households

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Caiumi, A., Perali, F. Who bears the full cost of children? Evidence from a collective demand system. Empir Econ 49, 33–64 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-014-0854-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-014-0854-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation