Skip to main content
Log in

Reference pricing in the presence of pseudo-generics

  • Published:
International Journal of Health Economics and Management Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper looks at producers of branded and generic pharmaceuticals’ pricing decisions under two possible reimbursement schemes—reference pricing and fixed percentage reimbursement—and under two settings—one where the branded producer only sells the (off-patent) branded pharmaceutical and another where, in addition, it may also sell its own generic version, a so called pseudo-generic. We find different pricing responses from firms under the two reimbursement schemes and across the two settings analysed (with or without a pseudo-generic), and show that pseudo-generics may have an anticompetitive effect. Our results have important policy implications such as showing that the presence of pseudo-generics reinforces reference pricing’s advantages over alternative reimbursement schemes.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Another strand of the (theoretical) literature focuses on entry-related issues, insofar as the decision to produce pseudo-generics may deter or delay generic entry (Hollis 2003; Kong and Seldon 2004; Reiffen and Ward 2007; Granier and Trinquard 2012). Empirically, the evidence (broadly) appears to confirm these anticompetitive concerns (Hollis 2002, 2003; Hollis and Liang 2007; Aitken et al. 2013; Grootendorst 2007; Berndt et al. 2007a, b; Appelt 2010); Kamien and Zang (1999) are among the few examples of authors finding pseudo-generics to have procompetitive effects. We are particularly interested in understanding competition between producers after generic entry; therefore, our paper explicitly leaves aside the entry decision (pseudo-generic and/or generic) into the market.

  2. Previous literature on reimbursement schemes for health care providers includes, among others, Ellis and McGuire (1986); Rickman and McGuire (1999) and more recently Bardey et al. (2012). In the pharmaceutical market, the classic reference is Mossialos et al. (2004).

  3. Several criteria could be used to cluster pharmaceuticals: chemical, pharmacological or therapeutic (Miraldo 2009).

  4. For a detailed review of reference pricing, see López-Casasnovas and Puig-Junoy (2000).

  5. Note that reference pricing is only different from FPR when generic competition becomes possible, otherwise only one branded pharmaceutical exists and it would automatically be the reference pharmaceutical.

  6. We thank a referee for suggesting this interpretation.

  7. Without a pseudo-generic, such efforts lead to a reduction in the branded price and an increase in the generic price; the latter is the reference price on which reimbursement is based, which thus leads to an increase in government expenditure. With a pseudo-generic, such efforts lead to branded price reductions and the generic price remains unchanged, which thus implies no changes in government expenditure.

  8. Typically, horizontal differentiation is justified because consumers have heterogeneous preferences (different tastes) or, in the standard Hotelling (1929) model, because they are physically located at different distances from the location of the firm they wish to purchase from. In the pharmaceutical market, Brekke et al. (2007) suggest that consumers support ’mismatch costs’ between their ideal treatment—given by their location along the Hotelling interval— and the pharmaceutical variety they actually consume, because, for instance, the latter may have undesirable side-effects or contraindications which reduce a consumer’s utility.

  9. This is plausible, because the branded pharmaceutical, during the patent protection period, will have already established a reputation for its treatment effectiveness.

  10. We assume that the reference pharmaceutical is the generic and that the copayment rate, \(\theta ,\) is similar across schemes. In equilibrium, we find that indeed the generic has the lowest price and would thus be the ideal candidate for the “reference” pharmaceutical.

  11. For instance, under such a more general formulation, Eq. (3) would become \(\hat{p}_{k}^{R}=p_{k}^{R}-\left( 1-\theta \right) \left[ \alpha p_{pg}^{R}+\left( 1-\alpha \right) p_{g}^{R}\right] , k=b,pg,g, \alpha \in \left( 0,1\right) .\)

  12. In particular, under such a general formulation in which the reference price is a weighted average of the pseudo-generic and generic prices, the location of the indifferent consumers does not change (see “The market with no pseudo-generics” and “Reference pricing” sections in Appendix) because the reference price impacts on all effective prices in the same way. That is, given headline prices, a change in the reference price formulation increases or decreases all effective prices (branded, pseudo-generic and generic) in the same amount. Therefore, equilibrium (headline) prices, quantities and firms’ profits are not affected by the reference price formulation (thus, Propositions 1, 2 and 3 hold under this more general formulation). The latter only affects CS and government expenditure. In particular, this more general reference price formulation [(compared to our assumption—see Eq. (3)] would lead to an increase in the reference price, a decrease in all effective prices and, thus, an increase in CS; but this is exactly offset (because quantities are the same) by an increase in government expenditure. Therefore, welfare results are unchanged: both social welfare (SW) and welfare are exactly the same regardless of the reference price formulation (thus, Propositions 4 and 5 also hold under this more general formulation).

  13. Graphically, this is equivalent to saying that the indifferent consumer under RP is located to the right of that represented in Fig. 1.

  14. For a given headline price vector, note that the effective price of the generic under FPR and RP is the same, but the effective price of the branded drug is higher under RP as long as \(p_{b}>p_{g}.\) See Eqs. (2) and (3).

  15. As in the previous section, for both varieties to be sold in equilibrium, restrictions (32) and (33) must be imposed in the parameters. See “The market with no pseudo-generics” section in Appendix for more details.

  16. We assume that this location is fixed, i.e., it is not a decision variable for the BP. Location, in our model is a metaphor for the degree of differentiation perceived by consumers. The pseudo-generic and the generic differ in observable characteristics such as the physical shape of the pharmaceutical, its colour, the package size and shape or the producer identity (often BPs license the production of pseudo-generics to other firms, rather than producing it themselves). Producers can choose these variables, of course (except, maybe, their identity). However, the resulting differentiation effect in consumers’ eyes is difficult, if at all possible, to manipulate strategically with any degree of precision. This is particularly so for the branded producer, who in this type of market is typically a first-mover (pseudo-generics enter the market early, generally before other generics do). Therefore, he has no ability to control the extent to which generics will physically resemble his own product.

  17. This is discussed at more length in Rodrigues et al. (2014).

  18. Equilibrium demand can be seen in Eq. (42).

  19. Again, three conditions must hold for the three varieties of the product to be sold in equilibrium and for these to be equilibrium prices: Eqs. (50), (51) and (52). See “The market with a pseudo-generic” section in Appendix for more details.

  20. We thank an anonymous referee for pointing this out.

  21. We thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this line of analysis.

  22. For a graphical representation of these restrictions, see Rodrigues et al. (2014).

  23. In equilibrium, the marginal consumer is located at \(c_{b.g}^{R}=\frac{t+\alpha -\beta }{3t}.\)

  24. In equilibrium, \(c_{g.pg}^{F}=\frac{f_{BP}}{6}+\frac{1}{3}\) and \(c_{b.pg}^{r,F}=\frac{\left( 1+f_{BP}\right) t-\left( \beta -\gamma \right) }{2t}.\)

  25. All these restrictions are similar to those of Rodrigues et al. (2014), where their graphical representation can also be found.

  26. In equilibrium, \(c_{g.pg}^{R}=\frac{f_{BP}}{6}+\frac{1}{3}\) and \(c_{b.pg}^{r,R}=\frac{\left( 1+f_{BP}\right) t-\left( \beta -\gamma \right) }{2t}.\)

References

  • Aitken, M., Berndt, E., Bosworth, B., Cockburn, I., Frank, R., Kleinrock, M., & Shapiro, B. (2013). The regulation of prescription drug competition and market responses: Patterns in prices and sales following loss of exclusivity. NBER Working Paper 19487.

  • Appelt, S. (2010). Authorized Generic Entry prior to Patent Expiry: Reassessing Incentives for Independent Generic Entry. Discussion Paper No. 2010–23, University of Munich.

  • Bardey, D., Canta, C., & Lozachmeur, J.-M. (2012). The regulation of health care providers’ payments when horizontal and vertical differentiation matter. Journal of Health Economics, 31(5), 691–704.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Berndt, E., Mortimer, R., Bhattacharjya, A., Parece, A., & Tuttle, E. (2007a). Authorized generic drugs, price competition, and consumers welfare. Health Affairs, 26(3), 790–799.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Berndt, E., Mortimer, R., & Parece., A. (2007b). Do Authorized Generic Drugs Deter Paragraph IV Certifications? Recent Evidence, Working Paper. Cambridge: Analysis Group.

  • Brekke, K., Königbauer, I., & Straume, O. (2007). Reference pricing of pharmaceuticals. Journal of Health Economics, 26(3), 613–642.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Ellis, R., & McGuire, T. (1986). Provider behavior under prospective reimbursement. Journal of Health Economics, 5(2), 129–151.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2009). Pharmaceutical Sector Inquiry - final report, retrieved from http://ec.europa.eu/competition/sectors/pharmaceuticals/inquiry/.

  • Ferrándiz, J. (1999). The impact of generic goods in the pharmaceutical industry. Health Economics, 8(7), 599–612.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Garattini, L., Cornago, D., & De Compadri, P. (2007). Pricing and reimbursement of in-patent drugs in seven European countries: A comparative analysis. Health Policy, 82(3), 330–339.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Granier, L., & Trinquard, S. (2012). Predation in off-patent drug markets. Applied Economics, 44(17), 2171–2186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grootendorst, P. (2007). Effects of ‘authorized generics’ on Canadian drug prices, SEDAP Research Paper no. 201, McMaster University.

  • Hollis, A. (2002). The importance of being first: evidence from Canadian generic pharmaceuticals. Health Economics, 11(8), 723–734.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Hollis, A. (2003). The anti-competitive effects of brand-controlled ‘pseudo-generics’ in the Canadian pharmaceutical market. Canadian Public Policy, 29(1), 21–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hollis, A. (2005). How do brands’ “Own Generics” affect pharmaceutical prices? Review of Industrial Organization, 27(4), 329–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hollis, A., & Liang, B. (2007). An assessment of the effect of authorized generics on consumer prices. Journal of Biolaw & Business, 10(1), 10–18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling, H. (1929). Stability in competition. Economic Journal, 39(153), 41–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamien, M., & Zang, I. (1999). Virtual patent extension by cannibalization. Southern Economic Journal, 66(1), 117–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kong, Y., & Seldon, J. (2004). Pseudo-generic products and barriers to entry in pharmaceutical markets. Review of Industrial Organization, 25(1), 71–86.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Löfgren, H. (2009). Generic medicines in Australia: Business dynamics and recent policy reform. Southern Med Review, 2(2), 24–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • López-Casasnovas, & Puig-Junoy, J. (2000). Review of the literature on reference pricing. Health Policy, 54(2), 87–123.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Miraldo, M. (2009). Reference pricing and firms’ pricing strategies. Journal of Health Economics, 28(1), 176–197.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Mossialos, E., Mrazek, M., & Walley, T. (2004). Regulating pharmaceuticals in Europe: Striving for efficiency, equity, and quality. Maidenhead: Open University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reiffen, D., & Ward, M. (2007). Branded generics’ as a strategy to limit cannibalization of pharmaceutical markets. Managerial and Decision Economics, 28(4–5), 251–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rickman, N., & McGuire, A. (1999). Regulating providers’ reimbursement in a mixed market for health care. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 46(1), 53–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrigues, V., Gonçalves, R., & Vasconcelos, H. (2014). Anticompetitive impact of pseudo-generics. Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade, 14(1), 83–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tele, P., & Groot, W. (2009). Cost containment measures for pharmaceuticals expenditure in the EU countries: A comparative analysis. The Open Health Services and Policy Journal, 2, 71–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank two anonymous referees as well as participants in the 5th Meeting of the Portuguese Economic Journal (Aveiro, July 2011) and in the 12th Portuguese National Health Economics Conference (Lisboa, October 2011) for their useful comments and suggestions. Financial support from Funda ção para a Ciência e Tecnologia (Project PTDC/EGE-ECO/100296/2008) is gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ricardo Gonçalves.

Appendix: Detailed pricing calculations

Appendix: Detailed pricing calculations

The market with no pseudo-generics

Fixed percentage reimbursement

Under a FPR scheme, the “marginal consumer”, \(c_{b.g}^{F}\), who is indifferent between buying the branded \((b)\) or generic \((g)\) pharmaceuticals is found by solving \(\gamma -\theta p_{g}^{F}-t\times c_{b.g}^{F}=\beta -\theta p_{b}^{F}\):

$$\begin{aligned} c_{b.g}^{F}=\frac{\theta (p_{b}^{F}-p_{g}^{F})-(\beta -\gamma )}{t} \end{aligned}$$
(23)

Let \(\mathbf {p}^{F}=\left( p_{b}^{F},p_{g}^{F}\right) \) represent the headline price vector. As the total number of consumers is assumed to be equal to 1, the demand functions are given by:

$$\begin{aligned} B\left( \mathbf {p}^{F}\right)&= 1-c_{b.g}^{F}=1-\frac{\theta (p_{b}^{F}-p_{g}^{F})-(\beta -\gamma )}{t} \nonumber \\ G\left( \mathbf {p}^{F}\right)&= c_{b.g}^{F}=\frac{\theta (p_{b}^{F}-p_{g}^{F})-(\beta -\gamma )}{t} \end{aligned}$$
(24)

The profit functions are given by \(\Pi _{BP}\left( \mathbf {p}^{F}\right) =p_{b}^{F}\times B\left( \mathbf {p}^{F}\right) \) and \(\Pi _{GP}\left( \mathbf {p}^{F} \right) =p_{g}^{F}\times G\left( \mathbf {p}^{F}\right) \). Profit maximization with respect to \(p_{b}^{F}\) and \(p_{g}^{F}\) respectively yields the best-response functions:

$$\begin{aligned} p_{b}^{F}&= \frac{1}{2\theta }t+\frac{1}{2\theta }\left( \beta -\gamma \right) +\frac{1}{2}p_{g}^{F}\nonumber \\ p_{g}^{F}&= \frac{1}{2}p_{b}^{F}-\frac{1}{2\theta }\left( \beta -\gamma \right) \end{aligned}$$
(25)

In a Nash equilibrium, we obtain the following equilibrium prices:

$$\begin{aligned} p_{b}^{F}&= \frac{2}{3\theta }t+\frac{1}{3\theta }\left( \beta -\gamma \right) \nonumber \\ p_{g}^{F}&= \frac{1}{3\theta }t-\frac{1}{3\theta }\left( \beta -\gamma \right) \end{aligned}$$
(26)

Therefore, equilibrium quantities are given by:

$$\begin{aligned} B^{F}&= \frac{2}{3}+\frac{1}{3t}\left( \beta -\gamma \right) \nonumber \\ G^{F}&= \frac{1}{3}-\frac{1}{3t}\left( \beta -\gamma \right) \end{aligned}$$
(27)

and equilibrium profits are:

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _{BP}^{F}&= \frac{1}{\theta }\left( \frac{4}{9}t+\frac{4}{9} \left( \beta -\gamma \right) +\frac{\left( \beta -\gamma \right) ^{2}}{9t}\right) \nonumber \\ \Pi _{GP}^{F}&= \frac{1}{\theta }\left( \frac{1}{9}t-\frac{2}{9} \left( \beta -\gamma \right) +\frac{\left( \beta -\gamma \right) ^{2}}{9t}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(28)

Consumer surplus is given by the sum of the surplus of buying the branded and generic pharmaceuticals (in equilibrium, \(c_{b.g}^{F}=\frac{t+\gamma -\beta }{3t})\):

$$\begin{aligned} CS^{F}&= \int _{0}^{\frac{t+\gamma -\beta }{3t}}\left( \gamma -\theta p_{g}^{F}-t\times c\right) dc+\int _{\frac{t+\gamma -\beta }{3t}}^{1}\left( \beta -\theta p_{b}^{F}\right) dc\nonumber \\&= \frac{\left( \beta -\gamma \right) ^{2}-11t^{2}+10\beta t +8\gamma t}{18t} \end{aligned}$$
(29)

Total profits, which are equivalent to total pharmaceutical expenditure, are given by:

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi ^{F}&= \Pi _{BP}^{F}+\Pi _{GP}^{F} \nonumber \\&= \frac{1}{\theta }\left( \frac{5}{9}t+\frac{2}{9}\left( \beta -\gamma \right) +\frac{2}{9}\frac{\left( \beta -\gamma \right) ^{2}}{t} \right) \end{aligned}$$
(30)

Government (or other third-party payers) expenditure with pharmaceuticals is a proportion \(\left( 1-\theta \right) \) of total pharmaceutical expenditure:

$$\begin{aligned} G^{F}&= \left( 1-\theta \right) \Pi ^{F} \nonumber \\&= \frac{1-\theta }{\theta }\left( \frac{5}{9}t+\frac{2}{9} \left( \beta -\gamma \right) +\frac{2}{9}\frac{\left( \beta - \gamma \right) ^{2}}{t}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(31)

Parameter restrictions    Two restrictions must hold for these results to be valid. Firstly, \(0<c_{b.g}^{F}<1,\) i.e., both the branded and the generic varieties are sold in equilibrium. \(c_{b.g}^{F}<1\) is always verified, whilst for \(c_{b.g}^{F}>0\) to be verified, the following condition must hold:

$$\begin{aligned} \beta <t+\gamma \end{aligned}$$
(32)

Secondly, \(\beta \ge \hat{p}_{b}^{F}\), i.e., CS must be positive (in equilibrium) for both product varieties. In order for this to be verified, the following must hold:

$$\begin{aligned} \beta \ge t-\frac{\gamma }{2} \end{aligned}$$
(33)

These restrictions are similar to those of Rodrigues et al. (2014).Footnote 22

Reference pricing

When a reference pricing scheme is in place, the consumer who is indifferent between purchasing a generic or a branded pharmaceutical is found by setting \(\gamma -\hat{p}_{g}^{R}-t\times c_{b.g}^{R}=\beta -\hat{p}_{b}^{R},\) which yields:

$$\begin{aligned} c_{b.g}^{R}=\frac{(p_{b}^{R}-p_{g}^{R})-(\beta -\gamma )}{t} \end{aligned}$$
(34)

Note that \(c_{b.g}^{R}=c_{b.g}^{NR}\), that is, the marginal consumer under reference pricing has the same location as the marginal consumer when no reimbursement scheme exists [found by setting \(\theta =1\) in Eq. (23)]. Therefore, demand, profit functions, equilibrium quantities and prices are equal in these two scenarios: \(p_{k}^{R}=p_{k}^{NR}\), with \(k=b,g\).

Consumer surplus under a RP scheme is given byFootnote 23:

$$\begin{aligned} CS^{R}&= \int _{0}^{\frac{t+\gamma -\beta }{3t}}\left( \gamma -\theta p_{g}^{R}-t\times c\right) dc+\int _{\frac{t+\gamma -\beta }{3t}}^{1} \left( \beta -p_{b}^{R}+\left( 1-\theta \right) p_{g}^{R}\right) dc \nonumber \\&= \frac{\left( \beta -\gamma \right) ^{2}-\left( 5+6\theta \right) t^{2}+\left( 6\theta +4\right) \beta t+\left( 14-6\theta \right) \gamma t}{18t} \end{aligned}$$
(35)

Total profits are given by:

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi ^{R}&= \Pi _{BP}^{R}+\Pi _{GP}^{R} \nonumber \\&= \frac{5}{9}t+\frac{2}{9}\left( \beta -\gamma \right) + \frac{2}{9}\frac{\left( \beta -\gamma \right) ^{2}}{t} \end{aligned}$$
(36)

Government expenditure is a proportion \(\left( 1-\theta \right) \) of the reference price (because the total number of consumers is equal to one):

$$\begin{aligned} G^{R}&= \left( 1-\theta \right) \left( B^{R}+G^{R}\right) p_{g}^{R}\nonumber \\&= \left( 1-\theta \right) p_{g}^{R} \nonumber \\&= \left( 1-\theta \right) \left( \frac{1}{3}t-\frac{1}{3} \left( \beta -\gamma \right) \right) \end{aligned}$$
(37)

Parameter restrictions    As outlined earlier, two conditions must be verified: \(0<c_{b.g}^{R}<1\) and \(\beta \ge \hat{p}_{b}^{R}\). In the first case, the same restriction outlined earlier must also hold: \(\beta <t+\gamma \). As for the second case, the following must hold: \(\beta \ge t-\gamma \frac{\left( 2- \theta \right) }{\left( 1+\theta \right) }\). This latter condition is less restrictive than the previous second restriction given by Eq. (33) for any \(\theta \in \left[ 0,1\right] \); therefore, it is always satisfied when Eq. (33) holds.

The market with a pseudo-generic

Fixed percentage reimbursement

Under FPR and with a pseudo-generic in the market, we assume that it is located sufficiently close to the generic so that consumer \(c_{g.pg}^{F}\) is indifferent between the two. Solving \(\gamma -\hat{p}_{g}^{F}-tc_{g.pg}^{F}=\gamma -\hat{p}_{pg}^{F}-t \left( f_{BP}-c_{g.pg}^{F}\right) \) we find:

$$\begin{aligned} c_{g.pg}^{F}=\frac{f_{BP}}{2}+\frac{\theta \left( p_{pg}^{F}-p_{g}^{F}\right) }{2t} \end{aligned}$$
(38)

In addition, provided the pseudo-generic does not fully cannibalize the sales of the branded variety, consumer \(c_{b.pg}^{r,F}\) will be indifferent between the two (\(r\) indicates that this consumer is located to the right of \(f_{BP}\)). Solving \(\gamma -\hat{p}_{pg}^{F}-t\left( c_{b.pg}^{r,F}-f_{BP}\right) =\beta -\hat{p}_{b}^{F}\) we find:

$$\begin{aligned} c_{b.pg}^{r,F}=f_{BP}-\frac{\beta -\gamma }{t}+\frac{\theta \left( p_{b}^{F}-p_{pg}^{F}\right) }{t} \end{aligned}$$
(39)

Let \(\underline{\mathbf {p}}^{F}=\left( p_{b}^{F}, p_{pg}^{F}, p_{g}^{F}\right) \) be the headline price vector under a FPR scheme. Demand functions are thus given by:

$$\begin{aligned} B\left( \underline{\mathbf {p}}^{F}\right)&= 1-c_{b.pg}^{r,F}= 1-f_{BP}+\frac{\beta -\gamma }{t}-\frac{\theta \left( p_{b}^{F} -p_{pg}^{F}\right) }{t}\nonumber \\ PG\left( \underline{\mathbf {p}}^{F}\right)&= c_{b.pg}^{r,F}- c_{g.pg}^{F}=\frac{f_{BP}}{2}-\frac{\beta -\gamma }{t}+ \frac{\theta \left( p_{b}^{F}-p_{pg}^{F}\right) }{t}- \frac{\theta \left( p_{pg}^{F}-p_{g}^{F}\right) }{2t} \nonumber \\ G\left( \underline{\mathbf {p}}^{F}\right)&= c_{g.pg}^{F}= \frac{f_{BP}}{2}+\frac{\theta \left( p_{pg}^{F}-p_{g}^{F}\right) }{2t} \end{aligned}$$
(40)

In this scenario, the BP produces both the branded and the pseudo-generic products. Hence, its profit function is given by \(\Pi _{BP}\left( \underline{\mathbf {p}}^{F}\right) =p_{b}^{F}\times B\left( \underline{\mathbf {p}}^{F}\right) +p_{pg}^{F}\times PG \left( \underline{\mathbf {p}}^{F}\right) \), whilst the generic producer’s profit function is given by \(\Pi _{GP}\left( \underline{\mathbf {p}}^{F}\right) =p_{g}^{F}\times G\left( \underline{\mathbf {p}}^{F}\right) \). Maximizing the former with respect to \(p_{b}^{F}\) and \(p_{pg}^{F}\) and the latter with respect to \(p_{g}^{F}\), we find the best-response functions which lead to the following Nash equilibrium prices:

$$\begin{aligned} \underline{p}_{b}^{F}&= \frac{11}{6\theta }t-\frac{5}{6\theta } tf_{BP}+\frac{1}{2\theta }\left( \beta -\gamma \right) \nonumber \\ \underline{p}_{pg}^{F}&= \frac{4}{3\theta }t-\frac{1}{3\theta } tf_{BP}\nonumber \\ \underline{p}_{g}^{F}&= \frac{2}{3\theta }t+\frac{1}{3\theta } tf_{BP} \end{aligned}$$
(41)

At these prices, we obtain the equilibrium quantities:

$$\begin{aligned} \underline{B}^{F}&= \frac{1}{2}\left( 1-f_{BP}\right) +\frac{\beta -\gamma }{2t}\nonumber \\ \underline{PG}^{F}&= \frac{1}{6}\left( 1+2f_{BP}\right) -\frac{\beta -\gamma }{2t} \nonumber \\ \underline{G}^{F}&= \frac{1}{3}+\frac{1}{6}f_{BP} \end{aligned}$$
(42)

And the equilibrium profits are:

$$\begin{aligned} \underline{\Pi }_{BP}^{F}&= \frac{1}{36\theta }\left( t \left( 41-f_{BP}\left( 34-11f_{BP}\right) \right) +18\left( 1-f_{BP}\right) \left( \beta -\gamma \right) +\frac{9\left( \beta -\gamma \right) ^{2}}{t}\right) \nonumber \\ \underline{\Pi }_{GP}^{F}&= \frac{1}{18\theta }t\left( 2+ f_{BP}\right) ^{2} \end{aligned}$$
(43)

Consumer surplus is given byFootnote 24:

$$\begin{aligned} \underline{CS}^{F}&= \int _{0}^{\frac{f_{BP}}{6}+\frac{1}{3}} \left( \gamma -\theta \underline{p}_{g}^{F}-t\times c\right) dc+ \int _{\frac{f_{BP}}{6}+\frac{1}{3}}^{f_{BP}}\left( \gamma - \theta \underline{p}_{pg}^{F}-t\times \left( f_{BP}-c\right) \right) dc \nonumber \\&\quad +\int _{f_{BP}}^{\frac{\left( 1+f_{BP}\right) t-\left( \beta -\gamma \right) }{2t}}\left( \gamma -\theta \underline{p}_{pg}^{F}- t\times \left( c-f_{BP}\right) \right) dc+\int _{\frac{\left( 1+ f_{BP}\right) t-\left( \beta -\gamma \right) }{2t}}^{1}\left( \beta -\theta \underline{p}_{b}^{F}\right) dc \nonumber \\&= \frac{9\left( \beta -\gamma \right) ^{2}+\left( 18\beta +54\gamma \right) t-18\left( \beta -\gamma \right) tf_{BP}-\left( 115-86f_{BP}+ 61f_{BP}^{2}\right) t^{2}}{72t} \end{aligned}$$
(44)

Total profits are given by:

$$\begin{aligned} \underline{\Pi }^{F}&= \underline{\Pi }_{BP}^{F}+ \underline{\Pi }_{GP}^{F}\nonumber \\&= \frac{1}{36\theta }\left( t\left( 49-f_{BP}\left( 26-13f_{BP} \right) \right) +18\left( 1-f_{BP}\right) \left( \beta -\gamma \right) +\frac{9\left( \beta -\gamma \right) ^{2}}{t}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(45)

Government expenditure is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} \underline{G}^{F}&= \left( 1-\theta \right) \underline{\Pi }^{F}\nonumber \\&= \frac{\left( 1-\theta \right) }{36\theta }\left( t\left( 49-f_{BP} \left( 26-13f_{BP}\right) \right) +18\left( 1-f_{BP}\right) \left( \beta -\gamma \right) +\frac{9\left( \beta -\gamma \right) ^{2}}{t}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(46)

Parameter restrictions    Five conditions must hold for these results to be valid. Firstly, \(0<c_{b.g}^{r,F}<1,\) which is equivalent to requiring that:

$$\begin{aligned} \gamma +\left( \frac{1}{3}-\frac{7}{3}f_{BP}\right) t<\beta <\gamma +\frac{7}{3}\left( 1-f_{BP}\right) t \end{aligned}$$
(47)

Secondly, \(c_{b.pg}^{r,F}>c_{b.g}^{F}\) and \(\gamma -\underline{\hat{p}}_{pg}^{F}-tf_{BP}<\gamma -\underline{\hat{p}}_{g}^{F}\), i.e., the pseudo-generic is sold in equilibrium. The latter is satisfied provided \(\underline{\hat{p}}_{pg}^{F}>\underline{\hat{p}}_{g}^{F}\), which holds in equilibrium. The former is satisfied provided:

$$\begin{aligned} f_{BP}>2/5 \end{aligned}$$
(48)

If this condition holds, the first inequality in Eq. (47) is always satisfied for any \(\beta >\gamma \).

Thirdly, \(f_{BP}<c_{b.pg}^{r,F}<1,\) so that the branded product is sold in equilibrium. \(c_{b.pg}^{r,F}<1\) is always satisfied, but in order for \(f_{BP}<c_{b.pg}^{r,F}\) the following must hold:

$$\begin{aligned} \beta <\gamma +\left( 1-f_{BP}\right) t \end{aligned}$$
(49)

Fourthly, \(c_{b.g}^{F}>c_{b.pg}^{l,F}\) so that the pseudo-generic is sold in equilibrium. This is equivalent to requiring that:

$$\begin{aligned} \beta <\gamma +\left( \frac{5}{3}-\frac{8}{3}f_{BP}\right) t \end{aligned}$$
(50)

This condition is more restrictive than the second inequality in Eq. (47) and the inequality in Eq. (49). In addition, this condition sets an upper boundary for \(f_{BP},\) because by assumption \(\beta >\gamma \). Hence, for this assumption to hold, \(f_{BP}<5/8\). Together with Eq. (48), this implies that:

$$\begin{aligned} 2/5<f_{BP}<5/8 \end{aligned}$$
(51)

Finally, all product varieties must provide positive surplus, which is equivalent to requiring that \(\beta \ge \underline{\hat{p}}_{b}^{F}\). This is verified provided the following condition holds:

$$\begin{aligned} \beta \ge \frac{t\left( 11-5f_{BP}\right) }{3}-\gamma \end{aligned}$$
(52)

Therefore, Eqs. (50), (51) and (52) must hold for our results to be verified.Footnote 25

Reference pricing

Under RP, the location of the consumer who is indifferent between the branded and pseudo-generic products and between the pseudo-generic and the generic products is equivalent to the NR scenario: solving \(\gamma -\hat{p}_{g}^{R}-tc_{g.pg}^{R}=\gamma -\hat{p}_{pg}^{R}-t\left( f_{BP}-c_{g.pg}^{R}\right) \) we obtain the latter \((c_{g.pg}^{R}=\frac{f_{BP}}{2}+\frac{p_{pg}^{R}- p_{g}^{R}}{2t})\), whilst solving \(\gamma -\hat{p}_{pg}^{R} -t\left( c_{b.pg}^{r,R}-f_{BP}\right) =\beta -\hat{p}_{b}^{R}\) we find the former \((c_{b.pg}^{r,R}=f_{BP}-\frac{\beta -\gamma }{t} +\frac{p_{b}^{R}-p_{pg}^{R}}{t})\). Hence, equilibrium quantities, prices and profits are equal to those in that scenario [in particular, \(\underline{p}_{k}^{R}=\underline{p}_{k}^{NR}\), with \(k=b,pg,g\), and the latter can be found by setting \(\theta =1\) in Eq. (41)].

Consumer surplus is given byFootnote 26:

$$\begin{aligned} \underline{CS}^{R}&= \int _{0}^{\frac{f_{BP}}{6}+\frac{1}{3}} \left( \gamma -\theta \underline{p}_{g}^{R}-t\times c\right) dc+ \int _{\frac{f_{BP}}{6}+\frac{1}{3}}^{f_{BP}}\left( \gamma - \underline{p}_{pg}^{R}+\left( 1-\theta \right) \underline{p}_{g}^{R} -t\times \left( f_{BP}-c\right) \right) dc\nonumber \\&\quad +\int _{f_{BP}}^{\frac{\left( 1+f_{BP}\right) t-\left( \beta -\gamma \right) }{2t}}\left( \gamma -\underline{p}_{pg}^{R}+ \left( 1-\theta \right) \underline{p}_{g}^{R}-t\times \left( c-f_{BP}\right) \right) dc \nonumber \\&\quad +\int _{\frac{\left( 1+f_{BP}\right) t-\left( \beta - \gamma \right) }{2t}}^{1}\left( \beta -\underline{p}_{b}^{R}+ \left( 1-\theta \right) \underline{p}_{g}^{R}\right) dc \nonumber \\&= \frac{9\left( \beta -\gamma \right) ^{2}+\left( 18\beta +54\gamma \right) t-18\left( \beta -\gamma \right) tf_{BP}- \left( 67+48\theta -110f_{BP}+24\theta f_{BP}+61f_{BP}^{2}\right) t^{2}}{72t} \end{aligned}$$
(53)

Total profits are given by:

$$\begin{aligned} \underline{\Pi }^{R}&= \underline{\Pi }_{BP}^{R}+ \underline{\Pi }_{GP}^{R}\nonumber \\&= \frac{1}{36}\left( t\left( 49-f_{BP}\left( 26-13f_{BP}\right) \right) +18\left( 1-f_{BP}\right) \left( \beta -\gamma \right) +\frac{9 \left( \beta -\gamma \right) ^{2}}{t}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(54)

Recall that total profits under a RP scheme are equivalent to total profits under a NR scheme, i.e., \(\underline{\Pi }^{R}=\underline{\Pi }^{NR}\).

Government expenditure is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} \underline{G}^{R}&= \left( 1-\theta \right) \left( \underline{B}^{R} +\underline{PG}^{R}+\underline{G}^{R}\right) \underline{p}_{g}^{R}\nonumber \\&= \left( 1-\theta \right) \underline{p}_{g}^{R} \nonumber \\&= \left( 1-\theta \right) \left( \frac{2}{3}t+\frac{1}{3}tf_{BP}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(55)

Parameter restrictions    As in the FPR scheme case, Eqs. (50), (51) must hold for our results to be verified. In addition, \(\beta \ge \underline{\hat{p}}_{b}^{R},\) which is equivalent to requiring that \(\beta \ge \frac{\left[ \left( 7+4\theta \right) -\left( 7- 2\theta \right) f_{BP}\right] }{3}-\gamma \). This condition is less restrictive than Eq. (52) for any \(\theta \in \left[ 0,1\right] \); therefore, it is always satisfied when Eq. (52) holds.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Gonçalves, R., Rodrigues, V. & Vasconcelos, H. Reference pricing in the presence of pseudo-generics. Int J Health Econ Manag. 15, 281–305 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10754-015-9165-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10754-015-9165-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation