Skip to main content
Log in

Zakat: Islam’s missed opportunity to limit predatory taxation

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

One of Islam’s five canonical pillars is a predictable, fixed, and mildly progressive tax system called zakat. It was meant to finance various causes typical of a pre-modern government. Implicit in the entire transfer system was personal property rights as well as constraints on government—two key elements of a liberal order. Those features could have provided the starting point for broadening political liberties under a state with explicitly restricted functions. Instead, just a few decades after the rise of Islam, zakat opened the door to arbitrary political rule and material insecurity. A major reason is that the Quran does not make explicit the underlying principles of governance. It simply outlines the specifics of zakat as they related to conditions in seventh-century Arabia.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. On the Quran’s economic vocabulary and comparative counts of particular usages, see Kuran (2010, pp. 493–494).

  2. For example, 2:177, 2:215, 4:8, 9:60, 24:22. “God’s servants” is a translation for fi sabīllilāh, literally “in the cause of Allah”.

  3. Leviticus 25:10. For a history, see Zuckermann (1857/1974).

  4. For a broader list and variations among schools of law, see Zysow (2002, pp. 410–414). Al-Mawardi (1050/1996, pp. 127–139) provides a medieval account of the diversity in interpretations.

  5. Slave labor, too, was used to build such structures.

  6. Zakat also has anti-avoidance rules. Transactions undertaken specifically to avoid zakat, such as transferring assets to another person right before the tax is due, do not eliminate the legal duty (Askari et al. 1982, p. 81).

  7. Illiteracy can pose a complementary problem. Illiterate persons depend on what literates select to read from the Quran; they cannot browse through it on their own. Even for literate readers, however, understanding the meanings of verses can be challenging. Few modern Arabs understand classical Arabic, the language of the Quran. The challenge is even more serious for non-Arab Muslims, who form three-quarters of the global Muslim population.

  8. Verse 2:261 says that “those who give their wealth for the cause of Allah” will reap rewards; and verse 59:9 that “those who preserve themselves from their own greed shall surely prosper.” Neither requires resource sharing. On that basis, a plausible interpretation of these verses is that payment is voluntary.

  9. See N.J. Dawood’s introduction to his translation of The Koran (1974, 9–14); and Pearson (1986, pp. 414–419).

  10. North and Weingast (1989) provide key insights into the connection between constraints on government takings and government capacity to borrow. For refinements and corrections, see Cox (2012), Stasavage (2002) and Greif and Rubin (2015).

  11. Zysow (2002, p. 410); Sabra (2000, p. 40). Up to the 1280s, the state collected zakat dues from the Karimis, a prosperous community of long-distance merchants, and one pastoral community in Libya. Sultan Al-Mansur Qalawun (reigned 1270–1290) abolished even those collections.

  12. Bravmann (1963); Schacht (1934, pp. 1202–1204). For the logic of redistribution norms in primitive societies and numerous examples similar to those of early Islam, see Posner (1981, chap. 6; Platteau 2000, chap. 5; Henrich and Henrich 2007; Gaus 2015).

  13. Of the 32 Quranic verses that mention zakat, 20 warn believers that punishment awaits those who do not pay. Sixteen of those 20 verses are from the Medina period.

  14. Quran 9:34–35. Hoarding is condemned also in chapters that Quran chronologists date to the Meccan period; see 70:15–18, 104:1–4.

  15. The verse is 9:60. Its usage of sadaqa came to be interpreted as referring to zakat while maintaining the meaning of voluntary almsgiving in other verses. See Benthall (1999, pp, 29–31).

  16. Quran: 9:98. All chronologies of the Quran consider chapter 9 to be among the latest. See Pearson (1986, pp. 414–419).

  17. The available historical sources do not allow modern interpreters to identify the evolution of zakat practices with confidence. We do not know the full range of controversies surrounding the drastic re-interpretation that occurred soon after the Prophet’s death.

  18. Some examples: Mamluk Cairo, 1315, 12.5% (Lapidus 1969, p. 8); Mamluk Syria and Upper Egypt, 1250–1517, 20–30% (Tsugitaka 2007, pp. 23–24). Iran’s Qajar period, 1785–1925, 10–35% (Floor 1998, pp. 320–327); Ottoman Empire, 1601–1700, 10–40% (Coşgel 2006, p. 338).

  19. None of the leading works focusing on the post-1800 period lists zakat in its index. See Issawi (1982), Owen (1993) and Owen and Pamuk (1999).

  20. A similar point is made by Rahman (1974, p. 33).

  21. As of 2018, for the five most populated countries of the Middle East (Egypt, Iran, Turkey, Iraq, Saudi Arabia), the average number of ministries is 23.

  22. In modern times, Twelver Shiis have taken this position. Zakat revenue can be used to cover expenses in the community’s common interest (Tabātabā’i 1983, pp. 25–27).

  23. Mattson (2003, p. 39). These jurists included Malik ibn Anas (711–796), Abu Ubayd (770–838), and Ahmad ibn Hanbal (780–855).

  24. Løkkegaard (1950), who focuses on Iraq’s early Islamic centuries, stresses this point. His work mentions zakat just seven times, which is consistent with its loss of significance. Six of the references define zakat, or point out that rulers preferred other taxes, or report that believers sought to avoid paying zakat.

  25. In a sample of 7724 Istanbul waqf deeds, 2146 name “the poor” (fukarâ) among their initial or subsequent beneficiaries (28.8%), and 1202 name mosque employees or other clerics (15.6%). Moreover, 1399 set aside funds for prayer reading, usually for the soul of the founder (18.1%); typically, those funds accrued to clerics. The deeds in question, catalogued in Aydın et al. (2015), represent about half of the 14,000 waqf deeds that Istanbul courts are thought to have registered from 1600 to the mid-1800s. For complementary evidence, see Hoexter (2003, pp. 150–151) and Ginio (2003, pp. 167–171). Ginio shows that of the 89 new waqfs registered in Salonica between 1694 and 1768, 58 delivered resources directly to clerics; the beneficiaries were “the poor” in 23 cases, with the category defined expansively to include clerics.

  26. The patterns in question are observed also in various modern places, for example, Pahlavi Iran (Jabbari 1981), post-colonial Cairo (Sabry 2010), and post-Ottoman Istanbul (Yılmaz 2008).

  27. World Bank (2016). In 2013, the World Bank defined extreme poverty as living on less than $1.90 a day.

References

  • Abu Yusuf. (790/1969). Taxation in Islam (trans: Ben Shemesh, A.). Leiden: E. J. Brill.

  • Al-Ghazali, A. Ha. (1100/1978). Revival of the religious sciences, issued as Imam Ghazali’s ihya ulum-id-din, vol. 1 (trans: Fazul-ul-Karim). Lahore: Sind Sagar Academy.

  • Al-Mawardi. (1050/1996). The ordinances of government (trans: Wahba, W. H.). Reading: Garnet.

  • Al-Shiekh, A. (1995). Zakāt. Oxford encyclopedia of the modern Islamic world (vol. 4, 366–370). New York: Oxford University Press.

  • Askari, H., Cummings, J. T., & Glover, M. (1982). Taxation and tax policies in the Middle East. London: Butterworth Scientific.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aydın, B., Yurdakul, İ., Işık, A., Kurt, İ., & Yıldız, E. (Eds.). (2015). İstanbul şer’iyye sicilleri vakfiyeler kataloğu. Istanbul: İSAM.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bashear, S. (1993). On the origins and development of the meaning of zakāt in early Islam. Arabica,40(1), 84–113.

    Google Scholar 

  • Belhaj, A. (2019). Bayt al-māl. Oxford encyclopedia of Islam and politics. Oxford Islamic studies online. http://www.oxfordislamicstudies.com/article/opr/t342/e0116. Accessed 4 April 2019.

  • Benhabib, J., & Rustichini, A. (1997). Optimal taxes without commitment. Journal of Economic Theory,77(2), 231–259.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benthall, J. (1999). Financial worship: The Quranic injunction to almsgiving. Journal of the Royal Anthropological Institute,5(1), 27–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bonner, M. (2003). Poverty and charity in the rise of Islam. In M. Bonner, M. Ener, & A. Singer (Eds.), Poverty and charity in Middle Eastern contexts (pp. 13–30). Albany, NY: State University of New York Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bravmann, M. (1963). Surplus of property: An early Arab social concept. Der Islam,38(1), 28–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cahen, C. (1956). La régime des impôts dans le Fayyūm Ayyūbide. Arabica,3(1), 8–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cahen, C. (1986). Bayt al-māl, history. Encyclopaedia of Islam (2nd ed., vol. 1, pp. 1143–1147). Leiden: E. J. Brill.

  • Cansunar, A. (2018). Redistribution by the rich: Information, perceptions, and preferences. Ph.D. dissertation, Duke University.

  • Cansunar, A., & Kuran, T. (2019). Economic harbingers of political modernization: Peaceful explosion of rights in Ottoman Istanbul. Working paper, Duke University.

  • Cantoni, D., Dittmar, J., & Yuchtman, N. (2018). Religious competition and reallocation: The political economy of secularization in the Protestant Reformation. Quarterly Journal of Economics,133(4), 2037–2096.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, M. (2005). Feeding the poor and clothing the naked: The Cairo Geniza. Journal of Interdisciplinary History,35(3), 407–421.

    Google Scholar 

  • Commins, D. D. (1990). Islamic reform: Politics and social change in late Ottoman Syria. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Constable, G. (1964). Monastic tithes: From their origins to the twelfth century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coşgel, M. (2006). Taxes, efficiency, and redistribution: Discriminatory taxation of villages in Ottoman Palestine, Southern Syria, and Transjordan in the sixteenth century. Explorations in Economic History,43(2), 332–356.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coulson, N. (1986). Bayt al-māl. Encyclopaedia of Islam (2nd ed., vol. 1, pp. 1141–1143). Leiden: E. J. Brill.

  • Cox, G. W. (2012). Was the Glorious Revolution a constitutional watershed? Journal of Economic History,72(3), 567–600.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crone, P. (1987). Meccan trade and the rise of Islam. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duri, A. (2011). Early Islamic institutions: Administration and taxation in the Caliphate to the Umayyads and ʿAbbāsids. New York: I. B. Tauris.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ekelund, R. B., Tollison, R. D., Anderson, G. M., Hébert, R. F., & Davidson, A. B. (1994). Sacred trust: The Medieval Church as an economic firm. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Finer, S. E. (1997). The history of government, vol. 1. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Floor, W. (1998). A fiscal history of Iran in the Safavid and Qajar periods, 1500–1925. New York: Bibliotheca Persica Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gaus, G. (2015). The egalitarian species. Social Philosophy and Policy,31(2), 1–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ginio, E. (2003). Living on the margins of charity: Coping with poverty in an Ottoman provincial city. In M. Bonner, M. Ener, & A. Singer (Eds.), Poverty and charity in Middle Eastern contexts (pp. 165–184). Albany, NY: State University of New York Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greif, A. (2006). Institutions and the path to the modern economy: Lessons from medieval trade. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greif, A., & Rubin, J. (2015). Endogenous political legitimacy: The English Reformation and the institutional foundations of limited government. Working paper, Stanford University.

  • Henkelman, W. F. M., & Kleber, K. (2007). Babylonian workers in the Persian heartland: Palace building at Matannan during the reign of Cambyses. In C. Tuplin (Ed.), Persian responses: Political and cultural interaction with(in) the Achaemenid Empire (pp. 163–176). Oxford: Classical Press of Wales.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henrich, N., & Henrich, J. (2007). Why humans cooperate: A cultural and evolutionary explanation. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoexter, M. (2003). Charity, the poor, and distribution of alms in Ottoman Algiers. In M. Bonner, M. Ener, & A. Singer (Eds.), Poverty and charity in Middle Eastern contexts (pp. 145–162). Albany, NY: State University of New York Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmes, G. (1962). The later Middle Ages, 1272–1485. Edinburgh: Thomas Nelson and Sons.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hurgronje, C. S. (1882/1957). La zakāt. In Œuvres choisies, edited by Bousquet, G.-H. & Schacht, J. (pp. 150–170). Leiden: E.J. Brill.

  • Ibrahim, M. (1990). Merchant capital and Islam. Austin: University of Texas Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Issawi, C. (1982). An economic history of the Middle East and North Africa. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jabbari, A. (1981). Economic factors in Iran’s revolution: Poverty, inequality, and inflation. In A. Jabbari & R. Olson (Eds.), Iran: Essays on a revolution in the making (pp. 163–214). Lexington, KY: Mazda Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, N. D., & Koyama, M. (2019). Persecution and toleration: The long road to religious freedom. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuran, T. (2001). The provision of public goods under Islamic law: Origins, impact, and limitations of the waqf system. Law and Society Review,35(4), 841–897.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuran, T. (2003). Islamic redistribution through zakat: Historical record and modern realities. In M. Bonner, M. Ener, & A. Singer (Eds.), Poverty and charity in Middle Eastern contexts (pp. 275–293). Albany, NY: State University of New York Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuran, T. (2010). Modern Islam and the economy. In R. W. Hefner (Ed.), The new Cambridge history of Islam: Volume 6, Muslims and modernity, culture and society since 800 (pp. 473–494). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuran, T. (2011). The long divergence: How Islamic law held back the Middle East. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuran, T. (2016). Legal roots of authoritarian rule in the Middle East: Civic legacies of the Islamic waqf. American Journal of Comparative Law,64(2), 419–454.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lapidus, I. M. (1969). The grain economy of Mamluk Egypt. Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient,12(1), 1–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Løkkegaard, F. (1950). Islamic taxation in the classic period, with special reference to circumstances in Iraq. Copenhagen: Branner and Korch.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marcus, A. (1990). Poverty and poor relief in eighteenth-century Aleppo. Révue du Monde Musulman et de la Méditerranée,55–56(1–2), 171–179.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mattson, I. (2003). Status-based definitions of need in early Islamic zakat and maintenance laws. In M. Bonner, M. Ener, & A. Singer (Eds.), Poverty and charity in Middle Eastern contexts (pp. 31–51). Albany, NY: State University of New York Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mendelsohn, I. (1962). Corvée labor in ancient Canaan and Israel. Bulletin of the American Schools of Oriental Research,167(3), 31–35.

    Google Scholar 

  • Millar, F. (1984). Condemnation to hard labour in the Roman Empire, from the Julio-Claudians to Constantine. Papers in the British School at Rome,52, 124–147.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mirrlees, J. A. (1986). The theory of optimal taxation. In K. J. Arrow & M. Intriligator (Eds.), Handbook of mathematical economics (Vol. 3, pp. 1197–1249). Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C., Wallis, J. J., & Weingast, B. R. (2009). Violence and social orders: A conceptual framework for interpreting recorded history. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C., & Weingast, B. R. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: The evolution of institutions governing public choice in 17th-century England. Journal of Economic History,49(4), 803–832.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oran, A., & Rashid, S. (1989). Fiscal policy in early Islam. Public Finance,44(1), 75–101.

    Google Scholar 

  • Owen, R. (1993). The Middle East in the world economy, 1800–1914 (revised edn). London: I. B. Tauris.

  • Owen, R., & Pamuk, Ş. (1999). A history of Middle East economies in the twentieth century. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Özbek, N. (2009). ‘Beggars’ and ‘vagrants’ in Ottoman state policy and public discourse. Middle Eastern Studies,45(5), 783–801.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pearson, J. D. (1986). Al-Kur’ān. Encyclopaedia of Islam (2nd ed., vol. 5, pp. 400–432). Leiden: Brill.

  • Platteau, J.-P. (2001). Institutions, social norms, and economic development. Amsterdam: Harwood.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R. A. (1981). The economics of justice. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rahman, F. (1974). Islam and problem of economic justice. Pakistan Economist (August 24), 14–39.

  • Rodinson, M. (1966/1972). Islam and capitalism (trans: Pearce, B.). New York: Pantheon.

  • Sabra, A. (2000). Poverty and charity in medieval Islam: Mamluk Egypt, 1250–1517. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sabry, S. (2010). How poverty is underestimated in Greater Cairo, Egypt. Environment and Urbanization,22(2), 523–541.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schacht, J. (1934). Zakāt. Encyclopedia of Islam (vol. 3, pp. 1202–1204). Leiden: E. J. Brill.

  • Scheidel, W. (2017). Slavery and forced labour in early China and the Roman world. In H. J. Kim, F. J. Vervaet, & S. F. Adalı (Eds.), Eurasian empires in Antiquity and the early Middle Ages: Contact and exchange between the Graeco-Roman world, Inner Asia and China (pp. 133–150). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaban, M. A. (1971). Islamic history: A new interpretation, vol. 1. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sijpesteijn, P. M. (2013). Shaping a Muslim state: The world of a mid-eighth-century Egyptian official. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stasavage, D. (2002). Credible commitment in early modern Europe: North and Weingast revisited. Journal of Law Economics and Organization,18(1), 155–186.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stillman, N. A. (1975). Charity and social service in medieval Islam. Societas,5(2), 105–115.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tabātabā’i, H. M. (1983). Kharāj in Islamic law. London: Anchor Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tanner, N., & Watson, S. (2006). Least of the laity: The Minimum requirements for a medieval Christian. Journal of Medieval History,32(4), 395–423.

    Google Scholar 

  • The Koran. (1974). Translated with notes by Dawood, N. J. (4th rev edn). Harmondsworth, Middlesex: Penguin Classics.

  • Tsugitaka, S. (2007). Fiscal administration in Syria during the reign of Sultan al-Nāsir Muhammad. Mamluk Studies Review,11(1), 19–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Webber, C., & Wildavsky, A. (1986). A history of taxation and expenditure in the Western world. New York: Simon and Schuster.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wittfogel, K. A. (1957). Oriental despotism: A comparative study of total power. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2016). Taking on inequality: Poverty and shared prosperity 2016. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yılmaz, B. (2008). Entrapped in multidimensional exclusion: The perpetuation of poverty among conflict-induced migrants in an İstanbul neighborhood. New Perspectives on Turkey,38, 205–234.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zuckermann, B. (1857/1974). A treatise on the sabbatical cycle and the jubilee (trans: Löwy, A.) New York: Hermon Press.

  • Zysow, A. (2002). Zakāt. Encyclopaedia of Islam (2nd ed., vol. 11, p. 406–422). Leiden: E.J. Brill.

Download references

Acknowledgements

Gloria Cheung and Dean Dulay provided excellent assistance, and helpful suggestions came from four anonymous referees. For financial support, I am grateful to the Religious Freedom Project of the Berkley Center for Religion, Peace, and World Affairs at Georgetown University. Funding was provided through Georgetown University’s Grant No. CON-005644.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Timur Kuran.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kuran, T. Zakat: Islam’s missed opportunity to limit predatory taxation. Public Choice 182, 395–416 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00663-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00663-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation