Skip to main content

Ranking Aggregation Techniques

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Rankings and Decisions in Engineering

Abstract

This chapter focuses on ranking aggregation techniques, which are the core of the whole book. The initial part of the chapter suggests a taxonomy based on three characteristic features: (a) input data characteristics, (b) aggregation mechanism, and (c) output data characteristics.

Without any ambition of exhaustiveness, the rest of the chapter offers a varied description of state-of-the-art techniques, ranging from some very popular and well-established ones—such as those from Voting Theory (Borda’s Count, Instant-Runoff Voting, etc.), ELECTRE-II method, Yager’s algorithm (YA), and Thurstone’s Law of Comparative Judgment (LCJ)—to more recent and innovative ones—such as (1) Enhanced Yager’s algorithm (EYA) and (2) ZMII technique. A structured case study application accompanies the description.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 119.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 159.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 159.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In Theoretical Computer Science, the classification and complexity of common problem definitions have two major sets: “Polynomial” time and “Non-deterministic Polynomial” (NP) time. One problem is NP-hard if it can be reducible to an existing NP-hard problem in polynomial time (i.e., at least as hard as an existing NP-problem, although it might be harder) (Laudis et al., 2018).

  2. 2.

    The letter “S” refers to the initial letter of the French term “surclassament” (in English “outranking”), which was originally proposed by Bernard Roy and his colleagues at SEMA consultancy company (Figueira et al., 2005).

  3. 3.

    Isolated objects are “objects that the expert believes should be excluded from the evaluation since they are not know well enough” (cf. definition in Sect. 4.5.1).

  4. 4.

    Cf. Definition 4.3 in Sect. 4.5.2.

  5. 5.

    Cf. Definition 2.1 in Chap. 2 (Vandenbos, 2007).

  6. 6.

    The adjective “variegated” indicates that the stimuli of interest represent different basic concepts, not the same one, just stated in different ways.

  7. 7.

    Cf. Definition 4.3 of “compatibility” (in Sect. 4.5.2). In this case, both the paired-comparison relationships involving incomparability (e.g., “o1||o2”) and those involving anchor objects (e.g., “o1 ≻ oZ”) were excluded from the comparison.

References

  • Arrow, K. J., & Rayanaud, H. (1986). Social choice and multicriterion decision-making. MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J., Sen, A., & Suzumura, K. (2010). Handbook of social choice and welfare (Vol. 2). North Holland, Elsevier. ISBN: 9780444508942.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blais, A. (Ed.). (2008). To keep or to change first past the post?: The politics of electoral reform. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borda, J. C. (1781). Mémoire sur les élections au scrutin, Comptes Rendus de l’Académie des sciences. Translated by Alfred de Grazia as mathematical derivation of an election system. Isis, 44, 42–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyd, T. M., & Markman, S. J. (1983). The 1982 amendments to the voting rights act: A legislative history. Washington and Lee Law Review, 40, 1347.

    Google Scholar 

  • Braha, D., & Reich, Y. (2003). Topological structures for modeling engineering design processes. Research in Engineering Design, 14(4), 185–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brans, J. P., & Mareschal, B. (2005). Multiple criteria decision analysis: State of the art surveys. In J. Figueira, S. Greco & M. Ehrgott (Eds.), Promethee methods (pp. 163–195). Springer – International series in operations research and management science.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruggemann, R., & Carlsen, L. (2011). An improved estimation of averaged ranks of partial orders. MATCH Communications in Mathematical and in Computer Chemistry, 65, 383–414.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, D. T., & Fiske, D. W. (1959). Convergent and discriminant validation by the multitrait-multimethod matrix. Psychological Bulletin, 56(2), 81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caperna, G., & Boccuzzo, G. (2018). Use of poset theory with big datasets: A new proposal applied to the analysis of life satisfaction in Italy. Social Indicators Research, 136(3), 1071–1088.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cash, P., Dekoninck, E. A., & Ahmed-Kristensen, S. (2017). Supporting the development of shared understanding in distributed design teams. Journal of Engineering Design, 28(3), 147–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, S., Liu, J., Wang, H., & Augusto, J. C. (2012). Ordering based decision making–A survey. Information Fusion, 14(4), 521–531.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiclana, F., Herrera, F., & Herrera-Viedma, E. (1998). Integrating three representation models in fuzzy multipurpose decision making based on fuzzy preference relations. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 97(1), 33–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiclana, F., Herrera, F., & Herrera-Viedma, E. (2002). A note on the internal consistency of various preference representations. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 131(1), 75–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiclana, F., Herrera-Viedma, E., Alonso, S., & Herrera, F. (2009). Cardinal consistency of reciprocal preference relations: A characterization of multiplicative transitivity. Fuzzy Systems, IEEE Transactions on, 17(1), 14–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Condorcet M.J.A.N.C. (Marquis de). (1785). Essai sur l’application de l’analyse à la probabilité des décisions redues à la pluralité des voix. Imprimerie Royale.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cook, W. D. (2006). Distance-based and ad hoc consensus models in ordinal preference ranking. European Journal of Operational Research, 172(2), 369–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cook, W. D., & Seiford, L. M. (1978). Priority ranking and consensus formation. Management Science, 24(16), 1721–1732.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cook, W. D., & Seiford, L. M. (1982). On the Borda-Kendall consensus method for priority ranking problems. Management Science, 28(6), 621–637.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Loof, K., De Baets, B., & De Meyer, H. (2011). Approximation of average ranks in posets. Match Communications in Mathematical and in Computer Chemistry, 66, 219–229.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Vellis, R. F. (2016). Scale development: Theory and applications (4th ed.). Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deger, S., & Gibson, L. A. (Eds.). (2007). The book of positive quotations. Fairview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dubois, D., Godo, L., & Prade, H. (2012). Weighted logics for artificial intelligence: An introductory discussion. In Proceedings of the 20th European Conference on Artificial Intellligence (ECAI) Conference, Technical Report-IIIA-2012-04, 1–6, 28th August 2012, Montpellier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duckworth, A. L., & Kern, M. L. (2011). A meta-analysis of the convergent validity of self-control measures. Journal of Research in Personality, 45(3), 259–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dwork, C., Kumar, R., Naor, M., & Sivakumar, D. (2001). Rank aggregation methods for the web. In Proceedings of the 10th international conference on World Wide Web (pp. 613–622).

    Google Scholar 

  • Dym, C. L., Wood, W. H., & Scott, M. J. (2002). Rank ordering engineering designs: Pairwise comparison charts and Borda counts. Research in Engineering Design, 13, 236–242.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edwards, A. L. (1957). Techniques of attitude scale construction. Irvington Publishers.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Emerson, P. (2013). The original Borda count and partial voting. Social Choice and Welfare, 40(2), 353–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Felsenthal, D. S. (2012). Review of paradoxes afflicting procedures for electing a single candidate. In D. S. Felsenthal & M. Machover (Eds.) Electoral systems: Paradoxes, assumptions, and procedures (Chap. 3). Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Felsenthal, D. S., & Nurmi, H. (2018). Voting procedures for electing a single candidate. Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Figueira, J., Greco, S., & Ehrgott, M. (2005). Multiple criteria decision analysis: State of the art surveys. Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Finkelstein, L. (2005). Problems of measurement in soft systems. Measurement, 38(4), 267–274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finkelstein, L. (2009). Widely-defined measurement–an analysis of challenges. Measurement, 42(9), 1270–1277.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn, P. C., & Brams, S. J. (1983). Paradoxes of preferential voting. Mathematics Magazine, 56(4), 207–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franceschini, F., & García-Lapresta, J. L. (2019). Decision-making in semi-democratic contexts. Information Fusion, 52, 281–289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franceschini, F., & Maisano, D. (2015). Checking the consistency of the solution in ordinal semi-democratic decision-making problems. Omega, 57, 188–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franceschini, F., & Maisano, D. (2018). A new proposal to improve the customer competitive benchmarking in QFD. Quality Engineering, 30(4), 730–761.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franceschini, F., & Maisano, D. (2019a). Design decisions: Concordance of designers and effects of the Arrow’s theorem on the collective preference ranking. Research in Engineering Design, 30(3), 425–434.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franceschini, F., & Maisano, D. (2019b). Fusing incomplete preference rankings in design for manufacturing applications through the ZMII-technique. The International Journal of Advanced Manufacturing Technology, 103(9), 3307–3322.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franceschini, F., & Maisano, D. (2020a). Adapting Thurstone’s law of comparative judgment to fuse preference orderings in manufacturing applications. Journal of Intelligent Manufacturing, 31(2), 387–402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franceschini, F., & Maisano, D. (2020b). Aggregation of incomplete preference rankings: Robustness analysis of the ZMII-technique. Journal of Multi-Criteria Decision Analysis, 27(5–6), 337–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franceschini, F., & Maisano, D. (2021a). Aggregating multiple ordinal rankings in engineering design: The best model according to the Kendall’s coefficient of concordance. Research in Engineering Design (To appear).

    Google Scholar 

  • Franceschini, F., & Maisano, D. (2021b). Analysing paradoxes in manufacturing design decisions: The case of “multiple-district” paradox. International Journal of Interactive Design and Manufacturing (To appear).

    Google Scholar 

  • Franceschini, F., Maisano, D., & Mastrogiacomo, L. (2015). A paired-comparison approach for fusing preference orderings from rank-ordered agents. Information Fusion, 26, 84–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franceschini, F., Maisano, D., & Mastrogiacomo, L. (2016). A new proposal for fusing individual preference orderings by rank-ordered agents: A generalization of the Yager’s algorithm. European Journal of Operational Research, 249(1), 209–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franceschini, F., Galetto, M., & Maisano, D. (2019). Designing performance measurement systems: Theory and practice of key performance indicators. Springer Nature.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gibbons, J. D., & Chakraborti, S. (2010). Nonparametric statistical inference (5th ed.). CRC Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gierz, G., Hofmann, K. H., Keimel, K., Mislove, M., & Scott, D. S. (2003). Continuous lattices and domains. Encyclopedia of mathematics and its applications (p. 93). Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Godsil, C. D., & Royle, G. (2001). Algebraic graph theory (Vol. 207). Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gulliksen, H. (1956). A least squares solution for paired comparisons with incomplete data. Psychometrika, 21, 125–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harzing, A. W., Baldueza, J., Barner-Rasmussen, W., Barzantny, C., Canabal, A., Davila, A., Espejo, A., Ferreira, R., Giroud, A., Koester, K., Liang, Y. K., Mockaitis, A., Morley, M. J., Myloni, B., Odusanya, J. O. T., O’Sullivan, S. L., Palaniappan, A. K., Prochno, P., Roy Choudhury, S., … Zander, L. (2009). Rating versus ranking: What is the best way to reduce response and language bias in cross-national research? International Business Review, 18(4), 417–432.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hatchuel, A., Le Masson, P., Reich, Y., & Weil, B. (2011). A systematic approach of design theories using generativeness and robustness. In DS 68-2: Proceedings of the 18th international conference on engineering design (ICED 11), impacting society through engineering design, Vol. 2: Design theory and research methodology, Lyngby/Copenhagen, Denmark, 15–19 August 2011 (pp. 87–97).

    Google Scholar 

  • Hazewinkel, M. (2013). Encyclopaedia of mathematics (Vol. 2, C). An updated and annotated translation of the soviet “mathematical encyclopaedia”. Springer Science & Business Media.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herrera-Viedma, E., Cabrerizo, F. J., Kacprzyk, J., & Pedrycz, W. (2014). A review of soft consensus models in a fuzzy environment. Information Fusion, 17, 4–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jansen, P. G. W. (1984). Relationships between the Thurstone, Coombs, and Rasch approaches to item scaling. Applied Psychological Measurement, 8, 373–383.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • JCGM 100:2008. (2008). Evaluation of measurement data – guide to the expression of uncertainty in measurement. BIPM.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jianqiang, W. (2007). Fusion of multiagent preference orderings with information on agent’s importance being incomplete certain. Journal of Systems Engineering and Electronics, 18(4), 801–805.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kariya, T., & Kurata, H. (2004). Generalized least squares. Wiley.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kelly, J. S. (1991). Social choice bibliography. Social Choice and Welfare, 8, 97–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kemeny, J. G., & Snell, J. L. (1960). Mathematical models in the social sciences. Ginn & Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kendall, M. G. (1945). The treatment of ties in ranking problems. Biometrika, 239–251.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kendall, M. G., & Smith, B. B. (1939). The problem of m-rankings. Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 10, 275–287.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krus, D. J., & Kennedy, P. H. (1977). Normal scaling of dominance matrices: The domain-referenced model. Educational and Psychological Measurement, 37, 189–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lagerspetz, E. (2016). Social choice and democratic values. Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Laudis, L. L., Shyam, S., Suresh, V., & Kumar, A. (2018). A study: Various NP-hard problems in VLSI and the need for biologically inspired heuristics. In Recent findings in intelligent computing techniques (pp. 193–204). Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Lin, S. (2010). Rank aggregation methods. Wiley Interdisciplinary Reviews: Computational Statistics, 2(5), 555–570.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luce, R. D., & Tukey, J. W. (1964). Simultaneous conjoint measurement: A new type of fundamental measurement. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 1(1), 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maisano, D., & Mastrogiacomo, L. (2018). Checking the consistency of solutions in decision-making problems with multiple weighted agents. International Journal of Decision Support System Technology, 10(1), 39–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maisano, D. A., Franceschini, F., & Antonelli, D. (2020). dP-FMEA: An innovative failure mode and effects analysis for distributed manufacturing processes. Quality Engineering, 32(3), 267–285.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martel, J., & Ben Khelifa, S. (2000). Deux propositions d’aide multicritere a la decisions de groupe. In Ben Abdelaziz et al. (Eds.), Optimisations et decisions (pp. 213–228).

    Google Scholar 

  • McComb, C., Goucher-Lambert, K., & Cagan, J. (2017). Impossible by design? Fairness, strategy and Arrow’s impossibility theorem. Design Science, 3, 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McIver, J. P., & Carmines, E. G. (1981). Unidimensional scaling. Sage.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ostanello, A. (1985). Outranking methods. In G. Fandel, J. Spronk, & B. Matarazzo (Eds.), Multiple criteria decision methods and applications: Selected readings of the first International Summer School, Acireale, Sicily, September 1983 (pp. 41–60). Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rasch, G. (1966). An item analysis which takes individual differences into account. British Journal of Mathematical and Statistical Psychology, 19(1), 49–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reich, Y. (2010). My method is better! Research in Engineering Design, 21(3), 137–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robert, H. M., Honemann, D. H., & Balch, T. J. (2011). Robert’s rules of order newly revised in brief. Da Capo Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross, S. M. (2009). Introduction to probability and statistics for engineers and scientists. Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saari, D. G. (2011). Decision and elections. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saaty, T. L. (1980). The analytic hierarchy process: Planning, priority and allocation. McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saltelli, A., Ratto, M., Andres, T., Campolongo, F., Cariboni, J., Gatelli, D., Saisana, M., & Tarantola, S. (2008). Introduction to sensitivity analysis. In Global sensitivity analysis. The primer (pp. 1–51).

    Google Scholar 

  • Slovic, P., Finucane, M. L., Peters, E., & MacGregor, D. G. (2007). The affect heuristic. European Journal of Operational Research, 177(3), 1333–1352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thurstone, L. L. (1927). A law of comparative judgments. Psychological Review, 34, 273–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Urban, G. L., & Hauser, J. R. (1993). Design and marketing of new products (Vol. 2). Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vanacore, A., Marmor, Y. N., & Bashkansky, E. (2019). Some metrological aspects of preferences expressed by prioritization of alternatives. Measurement, 135, 520–526.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vandenbos, G. R. (Ed.). (2007). APA dictionary of psychology. American Psychological Association.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang, B., Liang, J., & Qian, Y. (2014). Determining decision makers’ weights in group ranking: A granular computing method. International Journal of Machine Learning and Cybernetics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yager, R. R. (2001). Fusion of multi-agent preference orderings. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 117(1), 1–12.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young, H. P. (1974). An axiomatization of Borda’s rule. Journal of Economic Theory, 16, 43–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix

Appendix

5.1.1 Further Example

This section integrates Sect. 5.3, showing an additional case study example about the application of five Voting Theory’s aggregation techniques: BoB, BTW, BTH, IRV, and BC.

A hi-tech company, which operates predominantly in the video-projector industry, wants to develop a new model of hand-held projector, also known as a pocket projector, mobile projector, pico-projector, or mini beamer. Four design concepts of pocket projectors (i.e., the objects of the problem: o1 to o4) have been generated by a team of ten engineering designers (i.e., the experts of the problem: e1 to e10), during the conceptual design phase (Franceschini & Maisano, 2021a):

(o1):

Stand-alone projector

(o2):

USB projector

(o3):

Media player projector

(o4):

Embedded-type projector

The objective is to evaluate the aforementioned design concepts in terms of user-friendliness , i.e., a measure of the ease of use of a pocket projector. Some of the factors that can positively influence this attribute are: (1) quick set-up time, (2) intuitive controls, and (3) good user interface.

Given the great difficulty in bringing together all the experts and making them interact to reach shared decisions, management leaned toward a different solution: a collective ranking of the four design concepts can be obtained by merging the individual rankings formulated by the ten engineering designers (in Table 5.37).

Inspired by different design strategies, the team of engineering designers decides to consider five popular aggregation techniques from the scientific literature: BoB, BTW, BTH, IRV, and BC, illustrated in Sects. 5.3.1 to 5.3.4 (Saari, 2011). Table 5.38 contains the results obtained when applying these techniques.

Table 5.37 (Strict linear) rankings of four design concepts (i.e., o1 to o4) formulated by ten engineering designers (i.e., e1 to e10)

While the application of BoB, BTW, and BTH techniques is relatively trivial and therefore left to the reader, the application of the IRV technique deserves more attention. First, it can be noticed that object o2 never appears as the first choice in the initial expert rankings (in Table 5.37); this object can therefore be eliminated in advance, as it can never compete for victory. In the first round, the design concept o1 thus obtains five first choices, o3 obtains two first choices, and o4 obtains three first choices; since no object has obtained more than half of the preferences based on first choices, o3—i.e., the one with fewest first choices—is eliminated. In the second round—which represents the so-called “instant runoff,” in this case—a tie is observed between o1 and o4, both obtaining five first choices.

As for the BC technique (illustrated in Sect. 5.3.4), the cumulative scores—or Borda counts, BC(oi)—of the four design concepts are calculated as:

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}\mathrm{BC}\left({o}_1\right)=1+1+1+1+1+4+4+4+4+4=25\\ {}\mathrm{BC}\left({o}_2\right)=2+2+4+4+4+2+2+2+2+2=26\\ {}\mathrm{BC}\left({o}_3\right)=3+3+2+3+3+1+1+3+3+3=25\\ {}\mathrm{BC}\left({o}_4\right)=4+4+3+2+2+3+3+1+1+1=24\end{array}} $$
(5.41)

Reflecting different design strategies, the five aggregation techniques produce five different collective rankings (see the last column of Table 5.38). Even more surprising is that the best pocket projector design concept (i.e., the object at the top of each collective ranking) is (almost) different for each of the five aggregation models!

Although this plurality of results may at first glance confuse the reader, it is in some measure justified by the low concordance of the expert rankings. Considering that the problem of interest does not include any ranking with ties, the formula in Eq. (4.11) (Sect. 4.4) can be used to determine the Kendall’s concordance coefficient W(m) = 0.004 = 0.4%, which denotes a very low degree of concordance among experts. In view of this remarkable dispersion in the expert rankings, it is not surprising to observe discrepancies between the techniques in designating the winning objects.

Table 5.38 Scores related to the design concepts (i.e., o1 to o4) and corresponding collective ranking, produced by each of the four aggregation techniques (i.e., BoB, BTW, IRV, and BC)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2022 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Franceschini, F., Maisano, D.A., Mastrogiacomo, L. (2022). Ranking Aggregation Techniques. In: Rankings and Decisions in Engineering. International Series in Operations Research & Management Science, vol 319. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-89865-6_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics