Skip to main content
Log in

Infrastructure Investment and Labor Monopsony Power

  • Research Article
  • Published:
IMF Economic Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we study whether or not transportation infrastructure disrupts local monopsony power in labor markets using an expansion of the national highway system in India. Using panel data on manufacturing firms, we find that monopsony power in labor markets is reduced among firms near newly constructed highways relative to firms that remain far from highways. We estimate that the highways reduce labor markdowns significantly. We use changes in the composition of inputs to identify these effects separately from the reduction in output markups that occurs simultaneously. The impacts of highway construction are therefore pro-competitive in both output and input markets and act to increase the share of income that labor receives by 1.8–2.3 percentage points.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See also Alder (2016) for a study of the aggregate and regional effects of the GQ and counterfactual network designs using a Ricardian spatial trade model.

  2. Brooks et al. (2021) develop this model with an arbitrary number of inputs. Our results extend to this case so long as the firm is a price-taker in at least one of them.

  3. We believe this assumption is reasonable among the Indian manufacturing firms being studied in this paper, but we admit it may not be appropriate in every context. See Morlacco (2019) for a discussion of market power among large French importers.

  4. Alternatively, the model could be extended to include a competitive wholesale sector in each location that buys the local output from the firms, then sells it to many locations based on transportation costs and variation in local demand. The firms internalize that their choice of output affects wholesaler demand so that there are still markups for their output. This case is not presented here for ease of exposition.

  5. In principle, the ratio may also reflect other frictions that can distort the firm’s labor input choice away from the price-taking allocation, but we emphasize that the component associated with market share reflects the exercise of monopsony power.

  6. The expressway was not fully completed until 2013.

  7. The district classification follows the 2011 Census of India. The number of districts has increased from 640 in the year 2011 to 720 as of 2018.

  8. For example, Allen and Arkolakis (2014) find that the impacts of the USA interstate system extend far beyond the actual interstates. Similarly, Caliendo et al. (2019) find extensive indirect impacts of China trade shocks on labor markets throughout the USA.

  9. Moreover, in the appendix we show that our results are largely robust to the inclusion of state*time dummies, which indicates that the identification comes off of within-state, across-district variation.

  10. An additional limitation is that it assumes a production function that is constant across firms (within an industry) and only differs by a factor-neutral productivity parameter.

  11. It is, however, less restrictive along other dimensions. It allows for firm-specific production functions that are time-varying, for example. In this sense, it also allows for more general forms of technological change, including factor augmenting technical change.

  12. The reported averages are not equal because of the winsorizing process.

  13. To be more precise, we start with unnormalized values \({\tilde{\mu }}^L_{nkit} = p_{nkit} y_{nkit} / w^L_{kit} x^L_{nkit}\). We then regress \({\tilde{\mu }}^L_{nkit}/\mu ^M_{nkit}\) on labor share and a constant:

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\tilde{\mu }}_{nkit}^L}{\mu _{nkit}^M}=\chi +\gamma s^L_{nkit}+u_{nkit} \end{aligned}$$

    We then set \({\mu }^L_{nkit}\) equal to \({\tilde{\mu }}^L_{nkit}/{\hat{\chi }}\), effectively assigning \(\theta ^L=1/{\hat{\chi }}\). This guarantees that the predicted value of that ratio is equal to one when the labor share is zero.

  14. If \(s_{i,t}\) is the sampling weight for firm i at time t and \(c_{i,t}\) is the average labor compensation of firm i, then the new sampling weight is:

    $$\begin{aligned} \text {weight}_{i,t} = \frac{s_{i,t} c_{i,t}}{\sum _j s_{j,t} c_{j,t}} \end{aligned}$$

    .

  15. The coefficients on the triple interaction of the firm share with the highway implementation in Table 5 are not inconsistent with the results being weaker for the largest firms. However, if one is concerned that measurement for the smallest firms may be poor, our results are robust to dropping the smallest 20% of firms as shown in Table 12 of the appendix.

  16. To see that this has no impact on aggregate labor’s share, note that \(\theta ^L_{nki}\) in the denominator of the right-hand side in Eq. (22) cancels with the implicit \(\theta ^L\) in the numerator of \(\mu ^L_{nki}/\mu ^M_{nki}.\)

  17. For example, since the sampling-weighted median markdown in Table 1 is 0.5 for the CD benchmark, an alternative normalization in which we rescale so that the median markdown ratio is one would merely imply multiplying markdowns, regression coefficients, and standard errors that follow by 2. This alternative scaling would be consistent with an assumption that measurement error for the median firm is zero and the median firm has a negligible market share. The median market share is just 0.003, and this is nearly identical for firms with markdown ratios near the median.

  18. Moreover, the Brooks et al. (2021) results, and those of Hershbein et al. (2020) for the USA, show that the markdowns are not capturing labor adjustment costs. Hershbein et al. (2020) use a number of other specifications that go beyond Cobb–Douglas and find very similar results across their specifications.

  19. The magnitude of the change in labor’s share is lower than the magnitude of the drop in the markdown, however. Presumably this reflects a negative correlation between increases in labor compensation and increases in material expenditures across firms in connected districts.

  20. The coefficients drop precipitously once we control for log output and the implied elasticities become quite large, 12 and 44, respectively. We view these elasticities as implausibly large, and we therefore interpret the log output control as a second proxy for labor market share.

  21. It is surprising that weighted markdowns are rising over time in Fig. 1, but their impact on labor’s share is falling over time. We conjecture that this is driven by a changing correlation between markdowns and labor’s share.

References

  • Ackerberg, Daniel, Kevin Caves, and Garth Frazer. 2015. Structural Identification of Production Functions. Econometrica 83 (6): 2411–2415.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alder, Simon. 2016. Chinese Roads in India: The Effect of Transport Infrastructure on Economic Development. Working Paper.

  • Alder, Simon, and Illenin Kondo. 2020. Political Distortions and Infrastructure Networks in China: A Quantitative Spatial Equilibrium Analysis. Working Paper.

  • Allen, Treb, and Costas Arkolakis. 2014. Trade and the Topography of the Spatial Economy. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 129 (3): 1085–1140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asher, Sam, and Paul Novosad. 2020. Rural Roads and Local Economic Development. American Economic Review 110 (3): 797–823.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asturias, Jose, Manuel Garcia-Santana, and Roberto Ramos. 2019. Competition and the Welfare Gains from Transportation Infrastructure: Evidence from the Golden Quadrilateral in India. Journal of the European Economic Association 17 (6): 1881–1940.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, David, Kyle Herkenhoff, and Simon Mongey. 2018. Labor Market Power. Society for Economic Dynamics, Meeting Papers 170.

  • Binswanger, Hans P., and Mark R. Rosenzweig, eds. 1984. Contractual Arrangements, Employment, and Wages in Rural Labor Markets in Asia. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Braverman, Avishay, and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 1982. Sharecropping and the Interlinking of Agrarian Markets. American Economic Review 72 (4): 695–715.

    Google Scholar 

  • Braverman, Avishay, and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 1986. Landlords, Tenants, and Technological Innovations. Journal of Development Economics 23: 313–332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brooks, Wyatt, and Kevin Donovan. 2020. Eliminating Uncertainty in Market Access: The Impact of New Bridges in Rural Nicaragua. Econometrica 88 (5): 1965–1997.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brooks, Wyatt J., Joseph P. Kaboski, Yao Amber Li, and Wei Qian. 2021. Exploitation of Labor? Classical Monopsony Power and Labor’s Share. Journal of Development Economics 150: 102627.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brooks, Wyatt, Joseph P. Kaboski, and Amber Yao Li, Agglomeration, Misallocation, and (the Lack of) Competition. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2020. Forthcoming.

  • Caliendo, Lorenzo, Maximiliano Dvorkin, and Fernando Parro. 2019. Trade and Labor Market Dynamics: General Equilibrium Analysis of the China Trade Shock. Econometrica 87 (3): 741–835.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Card, David, Ana Rute Cardoso, Joerg Heining, and Patrick Kline. 2018. Firms and Labor Market Inequality: Evidence and Some Theory. Journal of Labor Economics 36 (S1): S13–S70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Loecker, Jan, and Frederic Warzynski. 2012. Markups and Firm-Level Export Status. American Economic Review 102 (6): 2437–2471.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Loecker, Jan, Pinelopi K. Goldberg, Amit K. Khandelwal, and Nina Pavcnik. 2016. Prices, Markups and Trade Reform. Econometrica 84 (10): 445–510.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Donaldson, Dave. 2018. Railroads of the Raj: Estimating the Impact of Transportation Infrastructure. American Economic Review 108 (4–5): 899–934.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edmond, Chris, Virgiliu Midrigan, and Xu. Daniel. 2015. Competition, Markups and the Gains from International Trade. American Economic Review 105 (10): 3183–3221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Faber, Benjamin. 2014. Trade Integration, Market Size, and Industrialization: Evidence from China’s National Trunk Highway System. Review of Economic Studies 81 (3): 1046–1070.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gandhi, Amit, Salvador Navarro, and David Rivers. 2020. On the Identification of Gross Output Production Functions. Journal of Political Economy 128 (8): 2973–3016.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gouin-Bonenfant, Emilien. 2018. Productivity Dispersion, Between-firm Competition and the Labor Share. Society for Economic Dynamics. Meeting Papers 1171.

  • Hershbein, Brad, Claudia Macaluso, and Chen Yeh. 2020. Monopsony in the U.S. Labor Market. Working Paper.

  • Lamadon, Thibaut, Magne Mogstad, and Bradley Setzler. 2019. Imperfect Competition, Compensating Differentials and Rent Sharing in the U.S. Labor Market. Technical Report w25954, National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Lu, Will Jianyu. 2020. Transport, Infrastructure and Growth: Evidence from Chinese Firms. Working Paper.

  • Morlacco, Monica. 2019. Market Power in Input Markets: Theory and Evidence from French Manufacturing. Working paper.

  • World Bank. 2002. India’s Transport Sector: The Challenges Ahead. World Bank Reports Series 1: 1–65.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Joseph P. Kaboski.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

On behalf of all authors, the corresponding author states that there is no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

This manuscript was submitted as part of a special issue. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, or the Federal Reserve System.

Appendix

Appendix

See Tables 6, 7, 8, 9, 10, 11, and 12.

Table 6 Impact of highway on markdown controlling for state-specific secular trends
Table 7 Impact of highway on markdown controlling for secular trends in coastal areas
Table 8 Impact of highway on markdown controlling for NREGA impact
Table 9 Impact of highway on markdown using alternative distance measure
Table 10 Relationship between markdown and labor market share-first stage
Table 11 Relationship between markdown and labor market share controlling for intermediate input price
Table 12 Relationship between markdown and labor market share dropping small firms

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Brooks, W.J., Kaboski, J.P., Kondo, I.O. et al. Infrastructure Investment and Labor Monopsony Power. IMF Econ Rev 69, 470–504 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41308-021-00144-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41308-021-00144-6

Navigation