Skip to main content
Log in

Dynamic control of a multiproduct monopolist firm’s product and process innovation

  • Published:
Journal of the Operational Research Society

Abstract

In this paper, we develop a dynamic control model of a multiproduct monopolist’s product and process innovation with knowledge accumulation resulting from learning by doing. Our work main features have four aspects: (i) the multiproduct monopolist’s instantaneous cost functions of product and process innovation depend on both the corresponding investments and the accumulations of knowledge through learning by doing in product and process innovation activities, respectively; (ii) the change rates of knowledge accumulations of product and process innovation are state variables; (iii) product innovation is understood as a reduction in product substitutability and process innovation as a lowering of marginal production cost; and (iv) monopolist’s inverse demand function depends jointly on the output level for product varieties and product substitutability. Our main objective is to investigate the optimal decision behavior of a multiproduct monopolist investing in product and process innovation with knowledge accumulation resulting from learning by doing under the monopolist optimum and social planner optimum. Our results show that: (i) there exists a unique saddle stable steady-state equilibrium under the monopolist optimum and social planner optimum, respectively; (ii) the learning rates of product and process innovation affect the monopolist’s investments in product and process innovation under the monopolist optimum and social planner optimum; and (iii) both investments in product and process innovation are lower under the monopolist optimum than that under the social planner optimum. Our results are valuable complements and development to the results drawn from the standard product and process innovation model.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1
Figure 2
Figure 3
Figure 4
Figure 5
Figure 6
Figure 7
Figure 8

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Alvarez F and Cerda E (2003). Learning by doing in aT-period production planning: analytical solution. European Journal of Operational Research 150(2):353–369.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Athey S and Schmutzler A (1995). Product and process flexibility in an innovation environment. The Rand Journal of Economics. 26(4):557–574.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Argotte L and Epple D (1990). Learning curves in manufacturing. Science 247(4945):920–924.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow KJ (1962). The economic implications of learning by doing. Review of Economic Studies 29(3):155–173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P and Howitt P (1992). A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60(3):488–500.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bonanno G and Haworth B (1998). Intensity of competition and the choice between product and process innovation. International Journal of Industrial Organization 16(4):495–510.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bond EW, Jones RW and Wang P (2005). Economic takeoffs in a dynamic process of globalization. Review of International Economics 13(1):1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bond EW and Ma Y (2013). Learning by doing and fragmentation. Pacific Economic Review 18(5):603–627.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chenavaz R (2011). Dynamic pricing rule and R&D. Economics Bulletin 31(3):2229–2236.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chenavaz R (2012). Dynamic pricing, product and process innovation. European Journal of Operational Research 222(3):553–557.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cellini R and Lambertini L (1998). A dynamic model of differentiated oligopoly with capital accumulation. Journal of Economic Theory 83(1):145–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cellini R and Lambertini L (2002). A differential game approach to investment in product differentiation. Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 27(1):51–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cellini R and Lambertini L (2009). Dynamic R&D with spillovers: competition vs. cooperation. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 33(3):568–582.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarke FH, Darrough MN and Heineke JM (1982). Optimal pricing policy in the presence of experience effects. Journal of Business 55(4):517–530.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dorroh JR, Gulledge TR and Womer NK (1994). Investment in knowledge: a generalization of learning by experience. Management Science 40(8):947–958.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dorroh JR, Gulledge TR and Womer NK (1986). A generalization of the learning curve. European Journal of Operational Research 26(2):205–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • El Ouardighi F and Tapiero CS(1998). Quality and the diffusion of innovations. European Journal of Operational Research 106(1):31–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grant RM (1996). Prospering in dynamically-competitive environments: organizational capability as knowledge integration. Organization Science 7(4):375–387.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gopalakrishnan S, Bierly P and Kessle EH (1999). A reexamination of product and process innovations using a knowledge-based view. The Journal of High Technology Management Research 10(1):147–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hatch NW and Mowery DC (1998). Process innovation and learning by doing in semiconductor manufacturing. Management Science 44(11):1461–1477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Imai K (1992). The Japanese pattern of innovation and its evolution. In: Rosenberg N, Laudan R, Mowery D (Eds.) Technology and the Wealth of Nations. Stanford University Press: Stanford.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ishikawa J (1992). Learning by doing, changes in industrial structure and trade patterns, and economic growth in a small open economy. Journal of International Economics 33(3–4):221–244.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kutsoati E and Zábojník J (2005). The effects of learning-by-doing on product innovation by a durable good monopolist. International Journal of Industrial Organization 23(1):83–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klepper S (1996). Entry, exit, growth, and innovation over the product life cycle. American Economic Review 86(3):562–583.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lambertini L (2003). The monopolist’s optimal R&D portfolio. Oxford Economic Papers 55(4):561–578.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lambertini L (2004). Process and product R&D by a multiproduct monopolist: a reply to Lin. Oxford Economic Papers 56(4):745–749.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lambertini L and Mantovani A (2009). Process and product innovation by a multiproduct monopolist: a dynamic approach. International Journal of Industrial Organization 27(4):508–518.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lambertini L and Orsini R (2015). Quality improvement and process innovation in monopoly: a dynamic analysis. Operations Research Letters 43(4):370–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin P and Saggi K (2002). Product differentiation, process R&D, and the nature of market competition. European Economic Review 46(1):201–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin P (2004). Process and product R&D by a multiproduct monopolist. Oxford Economic Papers 56(4):735–743.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levitt SD, List JA and Syverson C (2012). Toward an understanding of learning by doing: Evidence from an automobile assembly plant. Journal of Political Economy 121(4):643–681.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li G and Rajagopalan S (1998). Process improvement, quality, and learning effects. Management Science 44(11-part-1):1517–1532.

  • Mantovani,A (2006). Complementarity between product and process innovation in a monopoly setting. Economics of Innovation and New Technology 15(3):219–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Majerus D (1988). Price vs. quantity competition in oligopoly supergames. Economics Letters 27(3):293–297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pruett M and Thomas H (2008). Experience-based learning in innovation and production. R&D Management 38(2):141–153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pérez CJ and Ponce CJ (2015). Disruption costs, learning by doing, and technology adoption. International Journal of Industrial Organization 41(3):64–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pan XJ and Li SD (2016). Dynamic optimal control of process–product innovation with learning by doing. European Journal of Operational Research 248(1):136–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenkranz S (2003). Simultaneous choice of process and product innovation when consumers have a preference for product variety. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organisation 50(2):183–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saha S (2007). Consumer preferences and product and process R&D. The Rand Journal of Economics 38(1):250–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon H (1991). Bounded rationality and organizational learning. Organization Science 2(1):125–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thompson P (2010). Learning by doing. Handbook of the Economics of Innovation 1(1):429–476.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Utterback JM and Abernathy WJ (1975). A dynamic model of process and product innovation. Omega 3(6):639–656.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Usman U and Batabyal AA (2014). Goods production, learning by doing, and growth in a region with creative and physical capital. International Review of Economics and Finance 33:92–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wright TP (1936). Factors affecting the costs of airplanes. Journal of the Aeronautical Sciences 3(4):122-128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weiss P (2003). Adoption of product and process innovations in differentiated markets: the impact of competition. Review of Industrial Organization 23(3–4):301–314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang X and Borland J (1991). A microeconomic mechanism for economic growth. Journal of Political Economy 99(3):460–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yin X and Zuscovitch E (1998). Is firm size conducive to R&D choice? A strategic analysis of product and process innovations. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 35(2): 243–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author thanks the anonymous referees and the associate editor for their careful reading and their comments on the first version of this paper. This research was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Project No. 71333010).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Shoude Li.

Appendices

Appendix A

Proof of Lemma 1

According to expression (3.12) as well as differential dynamic Eqs. (2.1) and (2.2), one obtains:

$$ \frac{{\partial \lambda_{1} (t)}}{\partial k(t)} = \frac{{\partial \lambda_{1} (t)}}{\partial s(t)}\frac{\partial s(t)}{\partial k(t)} = \frac{n[a - c(t)]}{{4(r - \sigma )[1 + (n - 1)s(t)]^{3} }}[1 - e^{(r - \sigma )(t - T)} ]\frac{\partial s(t)}{\partial k(t)} $$
(A.1a)
$$ \frac{{\partial \lambda_{1} (t)}}{\partial h(t)} = \frac{{\partial \lambda_{1} (t)}}{\partial c(t)}\frac{\partial c(t)}{\partial h(t)} = \frac{n[a - c(t)]}{{2(r - \sigma )[1 + (n - 1)s(t)]^{2} }}[1 - e^{(r - \sigma )(t - T)} ]\frac{\partial c(t)}{\partial h(t)} $$
(A.1b)
$$ \frac{\partial s(t)}{\partial k(t)} = \frac{{\partial \int_{0}^{t} {\dot{s}(\tau )d\tau } }}{\partial k(t)} = - t $$
(A.2a)
$$ \frac{\partial c(t)}{\partial h(t)} = \frac{{\partial \int_{0}^{t} {\dot{c}(\tau )d\tau } }}{\partial h(t)} = - t $$
(A.2b)

Substituting expressions (A.2a), (A.2b) into (A.1a) and (A.1b), respectively, we have

$$ \frac{{\partial \lambda_{1} (t)}}{\partial k(t)} = \frac{{\partial \lambda_{1} (t)}}{\partial s(t)}\frac{\partial s(t)}{\partial k(t)} = - \frac{n[a - c(t)]t}{{4(r - \sigma )[1 + (n - 1)s(t)]^{3} }}[1 - e^{(r - \sigma )(t - T)} ] < 0 $$
(A.3a)
$$ \frac{{\partial \lambda_{1} (t)}}{\partial h(t)} = \frac{{\partial \lambda_{1} (t)}}{\partial c(t)}\frac{\partial c(t)}{\partial h(t)} = - \frac{n[a - c(t)]t}{{2(r - \sigma )[1 + (n - 1)s(t)]^{2} }}[1 - e^{(r - \sigma )(t - T)} ] < 0 $$
(A.3b)

Similar to the case of analyzing expression (3.12), according to expression (3.13) as well as differential dynamic Eqs. (2.1) and (2.2), one gets

$$ \frac{{\partial \lambda_{2} (t)}}{\partial k(t)} = \frac{{\partial \lambda_{2} (t)}}{\partial s(t)}\frac{\partial s(t)}{\partial k(t)} = - \frac{t}{{4(r - \delta )[1 + (n - 1)s(t)\}^{2} }}[1 - e^{(r - \delta )(t - T)} ] < 0 $$
(A.4a)
$$ \frac{{\partial \lambda_{2} (t)}}{\partial h(t)} = \frac{{\partial \lambda_{2} (t)}}{\partial c(t)}\frac{\partial c(t)}{\partial h(t)} = - \frac{t}{2(r - \delta )[1 + (n - 1)s(t)]}[1 - e^{(r - \delta )(t - T)} ] < 0 $$
(A.4b)

Finishing the proof. □

Appendix B

Proof of Proposition 1

  1. (i)

    According to differential dynamic Eqs. (3.20) and (3.21), one can immediately derive

    $$ \frac{{\partial \dot{k}(t)}}{{\partial b_{1} }} = - \frac{\mu }{2\alpha (r + \gamma )}[r - \sigma (1 - e^{(r + \gamma )(t - T)} )] < 0;\;\frac{{\partial \dot{h}(t)}}{{\partial b_{2} }} = - \frac{\xi }{2\beta (r + \theta )}[r - \delta (1 - e^{(r + \theta )(t - T)} )] < 0. $$
  2. (ii)

    The reaction of product innovation investment rate to a change in process innovation investment is given by

    $$ \frac{{\partial \dot{k}(t)}}{\partial h(t)} = \frac{{\partial \dot{k}(t)}}{\partial c(t)}\frac{\partial c(t)}{\partial h(t)} $$
    (B.1)

    Using differential dynamic Eq. (2.2), one obtains:

    $$ \frac{\partial c(t)}{\partial h(t)} = \frac{{\partial \int_{0}^{t} {\dot{c}(s)ds} }}{\partial h(t)} = - t < 0 $$
    (B.2)

    From expression (3.20), one gets \( \frac{{\partial \dot{k}(t)}}{\partial c(t)} = \frac{n[a - c(t)]}{{4\alpha \{ [1 + (n - 1)s(t)]\}^{2} }} > 0 \), so we have \( \frac{{\partial \dot{k}(t)}}{\partial h(t)} < 0 \).

    Likewise, we can write:

    $$ \frac{{\partial \dot{h}(t)}}{\partial k(t)} = \frac{{\partial \dot{h}(t)}}{\partial s(t)}\frac{\partial s(t)}{\partial k(t)} $$
    (B.3)

    From differential dynamic Eq. (2.1), one obtains:

    $$ \frac{\partial s(t)}{\partial k(t)} = \frac{{\partial \int_{0}^{t} {\dot{s}(\tau )d\tau } }}{\partial k(t)} = - t < 0 $$
    (B.4)

    From expression (3.21), one gets \( \frac{{\partial \dot{h}(t)}}{\partial s(t)} = \frac{n(n - 1)[a - c(t)]}{{4\beta [1 + (n - 1)s(t)]^{2} }} > 0 \), so we have \( \frac{{\partial \dot{h}(t)}}{\partial k(t)} < 0. \)

  3. (iii)

    Differentiating expressions (3.20) and (3.21) with respect to c(t) and s(t), respectively, one obtains:

    $$ \frac{{\partial \dot{k}(t)}}{\partial c(t)} = \frac{n(n - 1)[a - c(t)]}{{4\alpha [1 + (n - 1)s(t)]^{2} }} > 0,\quad \frac{{\partial \dot{h}(t)}}{\partial s(t)} = \frac{n(n - 1)[a - c(t)]}{{4\beta [1 + (n - 1)s(t)]^{2} }} > 0. $$

    Finishing the proof. □

Appendix C

Proof of Proposition 3

  1. (i)

    According to differential equation system (4.12), one can derive

    $$ \frac{{\partial \dot{k}(t)}}{{\partial b_{1} }} = - \frac{\mu }{2\alpha (r + \gamma )}[r - \sigma (1 - e^{(r + \gamma )(t - T)} )] < 0;\quad \frac{{\partial \dot{h}(t)}}{{\partial b_{2} }} = - \frac{\xi }{2\beta (r + \theta )}[r - \delta (1 - e^{(r + \theta )(t - T)} )] < 0 $$
  2. (ii)

    The proof is similar to Proposition 1–(ii).

  3. (iii)

    Differentiating \( \dot{k}(t) \) and \( \dot{h}(t) \) differential equation system (4.12) with respect to c(t) and s(t), respectively, one obtains:

    $$ \frac{{\partial \dot{k}(t)}}{\partial c(t)} = \frac{(2n + 1)(n - 1)[a - c(t)]}{{4\alpha [1 + (n - 1)s(t)]^{2} }} > 0,\quad \frac{{\partial \dot{h}(t)}}{\partial s(t)} = \frac{n(n - 1)[a - c(t)]}{{4\beta [1 + (n - 1)s(t)]^{2} }} > 0. $$

    Finishing the proof. □

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Li, S. Dynamic control of a multiproduct monopolist firm’s product and process innovation. J Oper Res Soc (2017). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41274-017-0260-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41274-017-0260-1

Keywords

Navigation