1 Introduction

The analysis of public policies and their impact in the citizens’ actual living conditions shows a relevant gap: partial evaluations are usually performed. Sometimes, macroeconomic aggregates -GDP growth, inflation, unemployment rate…- are used to assess if the policies are adequate, neglecting the effects on poverty and inequality. Even, a well-designed macroeconomic policy can raise the level of political or social discontent among the population due to an increasing level of impoverishment. On the other side, some policies aimed at alleviating poverty or reducing inequality can entail harmful effects on the economic dynamics. The aim of this paper is contributing to close this gap by focusing the analysis on the Great Recession, a good example of this dilemma.

This deep crisis, started in the late 2000s, led to an unprecedented increase in public deficit and debt, especially in some European countries. Amongst policymakers, it is widely agreed that fiscal imbalances, illustrated by excessive and longstanding public deficit-to-GDP ratios, are harmful for growth and macroeconomic stability (Coenen et al., 2008). Combinations of spending cuts and tax hikes were undertaken to reduce ratios of public deficit or debt over GDP and, in turn, to sustain the path of debt growth.

The make-up of such consolidation packages matters for the prospect for economic recovery, but also for distributional effects in a context of widening income inequality (IMF, 2015), specifically in the aftermath of the economic and financial crisis (Salotti & Trecroci, 2018). However, there is a lack of common understanding of how austerity measures have interacted with the decisions of national economic agents and how both have led to changes in income levels and distribution. This is especially relevant in the short term since effects of fiscal consolidation are being broadly considered harsher than previously thought (Paulus et al., 2017).

In this context, a growing body of empirical evidence on the macroeconomic effects of austerity has emerged. This literature is mostly focused on interactions between the policy mix and the economic outputFootnote 1 while only a few studies have looked at determining the distributional impacts of such fiscal adjustments. The latter analysed several fiscal consolidation episodes, highlighting that such measures are typically associated with an increase in income inequality mainly as a result of spending cuts rather than tax hikes adjustments (Agnello & Sousa, 2014; Ball et al., 2013; Coenen et al., 2008; Woo et al., 2017).

On the other hand, microsimulation models have also been used to estimate the effects of fiscal reforms on households’ income distribution and living conditions.Footnote 2 These models are based on microdata related to income, expenditures, or tax revenues. Therefore, the impact of economic shocks on income distribution can be evaluated ex ante. EUROMOD model is one of the most important contributions in this literature. Some publications from this project as Avram et al. (2013), Matsaganis and Laventi (2014), Paulus et al. (2017) or Ayala and Paniagua (2019) try to estimate these impacts.Footnote 3

Although these models can estimate very accurately changes on income distribution, tax collection or households’ expenditure caused by reforming or applying new taxes, a partial equilibrium approach is usually followed (Bargain & Callan, 2010; Callan et al., 2011). Therefore, despite of measuring the outcomes in terms of income distribution, not all the effects of these policies are included in the analysis.Footnote 4 All fiscal reforms, though related to a specific economic sector, end up to impact on the whole economy through different channels, so all the second-order effects are ignored in the microsimulation models.

The distributional issues of fiscal policies are also assessed under the general equilibrium framework, which has been gradually enriched to overcome the limitation of the representative agent assumption. Recently, New Keynesian Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (NK-DSGE) models have been employed to study the impact of fiscal policies on inequality by incorporating household heterogeneity by means of two or more types of households, according to the behaviour showed in household-level income-expenditure databases (Kaplan & Violante, 2018; Mc Manus et al., 2021). The main drawback of such models is the use of nontrivial computational techniques for solving them, given the need of tracking the distribution of wealth and the obstacles due to binding borrowing constraints. As a result, their usefulness as an input for policy making may be limited due the difficulties in understanding the mechanism underlying their findings (Debortoli & Galí, 2017).

In the same way, Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) models, which are widely used in policy analysis, have grouped households according to several categories based on socio, economic or geographic criteria. This approach along with the use of the abovementioned household-level databases can be used to perform poverty analysis and capture adequately distributive impacts, but heterogeneity is limited to inter-group changes (Cockburn et al., 2014). In a further step to capture intra-group distributional effects, all individual households from a household survey can be incorporated into the CGE model, which is known as fully integrated approach. The drawbacks of this latter approach have limited their use and have led to integrate microsimulations into CGE models (Cockburn et al., 2014).

In this paper, a static and integrated Computable General Equilibrium – microsimulation modelling approach is used with the aim of assessing the effects of fiscal consolidation on aggregate output, unemployment, inequality, and poverty, differentiating the effects caused by spending cut or tax hikes.Footnote 5 This top-down combination allows incorporating both the general equilibrium effects and the full household heterogeneity. This issue is very relevant to avoid the aggregation bias (Paulus et al., 2017). Since households are different in composition, size, and income sources, such consolidation measures may lead to opposed household-specific inequality and poverty effects.

Figure 1 shows in detail the development of the approach applied in this article where it can be clearly seen how the two empirical models—CGE and microsimulation—are linked. This process starts with the calibration and computation of a static CGE model that outputs the macroeconomic effects of the proposed simulations. Since a top-down approach is used in the CGE-microsimulation link, the changes in labour and capital incomes, obtained in the computation of the CGE model (top), are used as input in the microsimulation of the counterfactual income distribution (down). Specifically, new labour income, capital income and unemployment benefits for each household are recalculated according to the changes computed in the CGE model. Once the "new" counterfactual income distribution is obtained, the usual techniques are applied to obtain the poverty and inequality measures.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Source: Authors’ elaboration

Top-down CGE-microsimulation approach.

Specifically, using Spanish economy in 2014 as the benchmark, two simulations are performed to estimate the effects of a reduction of the public deficit ratio up to 3%: (1) an increase of the value added tax and (2) a decrease of the public spending. Spain becomes relevant as a particular case of study due to several features. This country deeply suffered the Great Recession, failing to meet the commitments on the deficit set out in the European Union Pact of Stability and Growth since 2008 (Fig. 2). As a result, the Spanish government drew up successive stability programmes adopting a series of fiscal consolidation measures to meet the deficit target (Spanish Government, 2021). The first of these was for the period 2009–2011, in which the deficit target was expected to be reached in 2011 (Spanish Government, 2010). However, the evolution of the Spanish economy made it impossible to embark on a path of sustained deficit reduction until 2014, that would culminate in the achievement of the stability target in 2017. In fact, in 2014 employment and output grew in annual terms for the first time since the onset of the crisis (Spanish Government, 2014). The measures to carry out this fiscal consolidation were established by the Spanish government including expenditure and revenue measures, unlike other countries in the European periphery with marked public deficits and mostly expenditure-based fiscal consolidation as imposed by IMF or EU (Bajo-Rubio & Gómez-Plana, 2015). Thus, in addition to a reduction in public expenditure, on the revenue side, the economic recovery led to an improvement in the components of the revenue structure, including private consumption, which boosted VAT revenues among others.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Main aggregates of Spanish economy. Source: Bank of Spain (2021) and National Statistical institute (2021a, b). Note: Deficit General Government (%GDP); GDP and employment (annual rate of change); unemployment (rate)

However, none of these programmes analyse the impact of such fiscal consolidation measures on poverty and inequality, especially in this context of economic recovery, which is particularly relevant as the Spanish data report a slight increasing trend due to the decreasing poverty thresholds.Footnote 6 At the same time, income inequality rose from the beginning of the economic crisis (Amuedo-Dorantes & Borra, 2018).

Therefore, the process undertaken attempts to simulate the counterfactual situation of not really adopted policies, taking the real situation as a starting point. In other words, it attempts to reflect what would have happened if, in addition to the economic and financial crisis, the policies simulated in the article had been adopted.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 briefly presents the CGE model, while Sect. 3 is devoted to the microsimulation model. Section 4 describes the databases employed in the study and Sect. 5 depicts the main results. Finally, Sect. 6 offers the conclusions.

2 The CGE model

In general terms, a CGE model encompasses all the economic interactions within a given economy, depicting the circular flow of income. Specifically, these models provide a complete representation of the different economic agents, assuming an optimization behaviour for them. The model equilibrium is determined by a price levels vector and an activity levels vector that clear markets and allow agents to reach their optimizations plans. Therefore, the model can be mathematically represented as a set of equations containing such equilibrium conditions.

In this work, a static intersectoral CGE model is employed.The model follows the concept of Walrasian competitive equilibrium enlarged to the public and foreign sector, that is, supply and demand should be equal in all non-labour markets.Footnote 7 In particular, the model includes one representative firm in each sector, a single representative consumer, one public sector and one foreign or rest of the world sector.Footnote 8

Starting with the structure of production block, producers combine intermediate inputs (domestic and non-domestic) and primary factors to obtain homogeneous product at least cost subject to technological constrains. Such constrains are described through a nested constant-returns-to-scale technology, so that there will be no excess profits. At the first nested level, total production for each sector is obtained by combining domestic output and equivalent imports, according to a Cobb-Douglass technology function (Armington, 1969). At the second level, the domestic production is a Leontief combination of intermediate inputs and value added. Finally, at the third level, the value added is a Cobb–Douglas aggregate of the primary factors (labour and capital).

Regarding consumers, the CGE model includes a representative household that maximizes the utility derived from consumption and savings by means of a Cobb–Douglas function subject to its disposable income. Households gain income basically as result of the sale of their endowments of labour and capital, but they also receive unemployment benefits, net transfers from the government and transfers from the rest of the world. Disposable income equals households’ gross income minus personal income tax and social contributions paid by employees.

Regarding the government, it collects taxes on production, value added tax, tariffs, personal income tax and payments to the Social Security System made by employers and employees. These public revenues are used to pay transfers to the private sector, unemployment benefits and public consumption of good and services. The difference between its revenues and payments represents the public surplus, which is endogenously determined. On the other hand, the government’s activity level remains fixed at the base year, although government expenditure may vary due to changes in prices.

Finally, the foreign sector is a simplified agent that includes two trading partners: the European Union and all other countries. Imports, exports, and transfers are exogenously fixed at the base year-level but the current account balance and the aggregate price index for the traded commodities are endogenously determined.

Two additional comments about the model should be pointed out. First, the investment activity is modelled following a fixed-coefficients technology, whose inputs are the sales of the productive sectors to the investment sector and whose output level is driven by the total savings in the economy. Therefore, the closure rule guarantees the macroeconomic equality between the total investment of the economy and savings at the aggregated level. Second, the aggregate labour supply follows the real-wage unemployment equation (Kehoe et al., 1995) that captures the feedback effects between the real wage and the unemployment rate. This feedback represents the frictions in the labour market that cause unemployment (Oswald, 1982).

3 Microsimulation model

As it is stated in the introduction, this paper proposes the combination of a CGE model with a microsimulation model to simulate the effects on the households’ living conditions, especially on the income distribution. Thus, the outcomes of the computation of the CGE model -the macroeconomic scenarios- are linked to the actual chances of households to face this economic situation.

Before reporting the linking procedure of CGE and microsimulation models, some comments about income should be raised. The income definition considered in this paper is the adjusted or equivalized disposable household income. This variable comes from the total disposable household income, which comprises all the incomes earned by the household members from labour, capital (self-employment, and financial and real estate yields), public transfers or benefits, unemployment benefits and inter-households or private transfers. After adding all those income sources, taxes must be subtracted to obtain net income.

$$H{\text{Income}}_{0} = {\text{WAGES}}_{0} + {\text{CAPITAL}}_{0} + {\text{BENEFITS}}_{0} + {\text{UNEMPLOYMENT}}_{0} + {\text{OTHER}}_{0} - {\text{TAXES}}_{0}$$
(1)

Later, differences in needs are considered because different households -in size and composition- with the same net income will have different living conditions. Therefore, the total household income is adjusted by using an equivalence scale, which reports the influence of household size and composition. Among the wide range of options in the literature, the modified OECD equivalence scaleFootnote 9 is chosen. Once the household equivalent size is computed, the adjusted household income is determined by dividing the total disposable income by this equivalent size. Finally, the adjusted household income is allocated to each household member before performing inequality and poverty analyses.

Once every individual in the microdata has his/her own equivalent household income, the impact of macroeconomic changes on household incomes can be measured. The procedure is reported in Eq. 2 where the former expression is re-written by including some coefficients of change, built after computing the CGE model.

$$H{\text{Income}}_{1} = {\text{WAGES}}_{1} + {\text{CAPITAL}}_{1} + {\text{BENEFITS}}_{1} + {\text{UNEMPLOYMENT}}_{1} + {\text{OTHER}}_{1} - {\text{TAXES}}_{1}$$
(2)

where each variable at time 1 (after computation) is expressed as \({X}_{i1}={\gamma }_{i}{X}_{i0}\), being i the coefficients that reflect the changes in income for each variable. These coefficients are calculated so that the increases or decreases of the total income by source in the microdata database are the variations obtained in the macroeconomic model for those income sources.

Since two values of income, actual equivalent income and simulated equivalent income, are computed, the effects of macroeconomic shocks on the households’ earnings could be measured for the whole income distribution and not only in terms of mean incomes. Moreover, the most usual indicators of inequality and poverty can be also applied to estimate and measure the impact on living conditions and well-being.

Among the wide range of indicators proposed in the literature to measure inequality, Gini index and Theil or Generalized Entropy Index will be used. Gini and Theil index have the advantage of summarizing all the information contained in the distribution in a single scalar because they are functions that assign a real number to each income distribution. However, since both follow different aggregation procedures, they report different figures.

The former is the most usually found in the official reports as well as the academic papers. It is defined by the following expression:

$$G = \frac{{1}}{{\upmu }}{\text{Cov}}\left( {x,F\left( x \right)} \right)$$
(3)

Meanwhile, the Theil index is based on the concept of entropy and, therefore, belongs to the general class of entropy measures (Cowell, 1995). Depending on c parameter,Footnote 10 it can be expressed as:

$$\begin{array}{*{20}c} {T_{c} = \frac{1}{n}\frac{1}{{c\left( {c - 1} \right)}}\mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^{n} \left[ {\left( {\frac{{y_{i} }}{\mu }} \right)^{c} - 1} \right], c \ne 0,1} \\ {T_{0} = \frac{1}{n}\mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^{n} ln\left( {\frac{\mu }{{y_{i} }}} \right),c = 0} \\ \end{array}$$
(4)

The second equation will be used in this paper because of its simplicity. Besides, this index shows a very relevant advantage: it is the only one that satisfies the whole range of desirable properties for an inequality index. No index, excepting Theil, is additively decomposable so that, the general level of inequality measured with a Theil index can be expressed as the sum of partial index weighted by the share of each group in the population.

Finally, the effects on poverty are also analysed in this paper as an outcome of the microsimulation model. Since a relative approach is assumed, the poverty line is fixed at the 60% of the median equivalent income.Footnote 11 Once the threshold is fixed, a poverty indicator must be selected. Due to their properties, the Foster-Greer-Thorbecke (Foster et al., 1984) -henceforth, FGT- family of poverty measures is chosen to perform the poverty analysis:

$${\text{FGT}}\left( \alpha \right) = \frac{1}{n}\mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^{q} \left( {\frac{{z - y_{i} }}{z}} \right)^{\alpha }$$
(5)

where n is the population, q the poor population, yi i-th individual’s income and z the poverty line. This expression includes different definitions of poverty depending on the α parameter. It expresses the individual' sensitivity to poverty gap regarding to poverty threshold (i.e., distance from the poverty line). The greater the value of this parameter, people with a greater poverty gap will be the more important in the analysis. Therefore, it can be viewed as the degree of aversion to poverty in the population.

In particular, if α = 0 the FGT index is merely the share of poor people in the population, the so-called “headcount index” or the widely known “poverty rate”. It measures the poverty incidence so that there is no information about how much poor are the poor people. This issue, poverty depth, can be observed by the FGT index when α is equal to 1.Footnote 12

4 Databases

The database employed to calibrate the CGE model and determine their parameter valuesFootnote 13 is a Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) for Spain with 2014 data (SAMSPA-14).Footnote 14 Overall, a SAM is a square matrix that shows a disaggregated representation of the circular flow of income, recording information about all the economic transactions within a given economy and period of time. Specifically, the SAMSPA-14 consists of 31 accounts, including 19 productive sectors, 2 inputs (labour and capital), a representative consumer, an aggregate capital account or saving/investment account, a government account, the taxes accounts according to the disaggregation required by the model, and a foreign sector account.

To calibrate the CGE model, the SAMSPA-14 is reproduced by model as a benchmark equilibrium in which all the prices and the activity levels are unitary at initial time. From this initial condition we introduce an exogenous shock (the reduction of the public deficit), obtaining the changes by comparing the benchmark and the simulated equilibriums.

Regarding the microsimulation model, it is based on the 2015Footnote 15 Spanish subset of the EU-SILC (European Union Survey on Income and Living Conditions) microdata. This survey, coordinated by EUROSTAT, aims at allowing the comparability of results across the European Union. Besides, it is specially designed to analyse income and living conditions, so that it is the best database to develop an analysis about microsimulation, inequality, and poverty. Each wave contains four files: D (general information about households), H (specific information about households), R (general information about persons) and P (specific information about adult people). Since the individual is used as the unit of analysis and not all the income sources appear in all files, it is required to combine the files H and P as well as R to estimate the household income.

After an analysis of prior validation to eliminate extreme values or outliers, the sample employed in the study comprises 31,403 observations. In addition to income, background information such as labour market status, age, sex, household size and type or region are used to perform the proposed analysis.

5 Simulations and results

As a first step, the CGE model outlined in the above section is used to simulate the reduction of public deficit until the 3% of GDP, as established in the Stability and Growth Pact. Simulations have been performed under two scenarios, recalling measures adopted by the Spanish government, as well as other European countries, as an important part of its consolidation package (Paulus et al., 2017). First, the target of deficit could be reached by increasing 2.7 pp the effective value-added tax (VAT). This tax hike does not influence households’ disposable income, but it directly impacts on their consumption potential leading a path of changes that may results in changes in income. Second, it is assumed a reduction in government consumption of 14.5%, that is, a decrease in the demand of goods and services by the public sector.

Table 1 reports the results from the two above simulations on the main macroeconomic variables, both as level of the corresponding variable and as percentage change from its benchmark value. As it is shown, both measures have contractionary effects since GDP falls in both scenarios, but such effects are larger for VAT hike than for government spending cut. In both scenarios unemployment increases with a remarkably higher rise under the tax increase compared to the spending cut measure. Regarding prices, the results show an increase in consumer price index and a drop in real wage for both scenarios, especially for VAT based measure.

Table 1 Change in macroeconomic variables

With respect to the households’ sources of income, labour income decreases because of the fall in both employment and real wages, corresponding again the worse result to the tax-based measure. On the other hand, capital income decreases in the VAT hike scenario but improves when spending cut is done. Moreover, the increase in public transfers is mostly paired with the increase in the consumer prices under both scenarios, whereas the rise in unemployment benefits, following the path of the unemployment, is higher in the first than in the second one. Finally, total government revenue exhibits a large rise to achieve the deficit target while it slightly falls when spending cut is performed.

To sum up, all these findings point out that both scenarios show unfavourable results for households, that is, higher unemployment and labour income fall, but the VAT hike scenario results are shockingly worse.

This impression is confirmed by the results of the microsimulation model (Table 2). The impacts on household and personal incomes of the VAT rate increase are significantly higher than those corresponding to the reduction in government spending. Since labour and capital incomes fall together with the rising unemployment, the equivalent income mean suffers a noticeable drop, despite of the rise in public benefits. On the contrary, the scenario 2 reports a situation in terms of income means relatively close to the benchmark.

Table 2 Inequality and poverty after microeconomic simulation

Although the microsimulation results will be analysed below, the relevance of the linking procedure proposed in this paper should be pointed out. Stopping the analysis in computing average incomes provides the same description obtained with the CGE model in a macroeconomic framework. If the effects of any policy reform were limited to average terms -even when equivalent income is used instead of per capita figures- the actual impact would be underestimated. It would be a new application of the well-known aphorism “a rising tide lifts all boats”. However, one can wonder if “actually are all the boats lifting?”. The answer is found in the analysis of inequality and poverty. The more unequal a society is, the harder spilling the benefits of economic growth over the whole society is, especially for the poorest people.

The last four rows in Table 2 broaden the picture described by per capita and equivalent income means.

First, scenario 1 shows some unexpected outcomes. Despite of considerably declining means, inequality in scenario 1 is slightly lower than benchmark, whichever index is used. Its explanation is found in Table 1: while public benefits show some growth, capital and labour incomes fall. These income sources, especially public benefits, and capital, report different patterns depending on the economic trend.

While the formers are mainly earned by the lower tail of the distribution, the latter are much further away from the mean in economic booms and especially related to the high-income part of the distribution.Footnote 16 Therefore, inequality drops in this scenario due to a “general process of worsening”: an increase of the VAT would end up in a situation which poorest people would converge because richer people would live worse, instead of improving their income and living conditions.

Even more, this conclusion is reinforced by the poverty indicators. The decrease of incomes along with the rise in unemployment make poverty grows in terms of incidence –more people are expected to live at risk of poverty- and depth –poor people are even poorer. Although the public transfers increase in this scenario and they aim especially at the poorest people, the fall in income means and the evolution of unemployment cause a drop in well-being so dramatic that benefits cannot cope with it.

These implications of the first policy reform would be more significant if the ability of meeting household ends was the variable used to measure the impact. When the VAT rate rises, prices grow so that the households’ actual living conditions and consumption will become worse with the consequent fall in household capacity to face future income shocks.

Regarding the scenario 2, their results apparently show that the goal -reducing public deficit- could be reached with only slight decreases in income means. Nevertheless, inequality and poverty stand out because they are clearly higher than benchmark and even higher than the bad results estimated in scenario 1. Again, Table 1 includes the required information to enlighten these figures.

The general reduction of public expenditure would end up in a reduction of labour incomes combined with an increase of capital incomes. This divergence worsens one of the main factors that drive inequality: the shift between capital and labour incomes. The disparity between both income sources in favour of the former has been observed along last decades in most of the OECD countries and it is identified as one of the sources of the rising income inequality in them. Therefore, a reduction of labour incomes combined with an increase of capital incomes make that disparity becoming higher.

Poverty shows the same pattern as inequality. In this case, reducing the public expenditure would make the poverty more spread and deeper. Despite of the rise of public transfers, this growth cannot outweigh the forces supporting poverty and inequality.

The last simulation clearly shows the adequacy of the proposal of this paper. By linking the microsimulation model to the CGE model it is possible to measure the distributional impacts and, therefore, go beyond the apparently good results in income means.

Once the simulation results are considered, an additional analysis is put forward to assess to what extent estimated changes in poverty are due to changes in average terms or changes in inequality. Datt and Ravaillon (1992) propose to decompose poverty changes along time in two components, one related to economic growth and the other one to inequality. This decomposition is performed by the following expression:

$$P_{1} - P_{0} = \left[ {P\left( {{\upmu }^{{t_{1} }} ,{\uppi }^{{t_{0} }} } \right) - P\left( {{\upmu }^{{t_{0} }} ,{\uppi }^{{t_{0} }} } \right)} \right] + \left[ {P\left( {{\upmu }^{{t_{0} }} ,{\uppi }^{{t_{1} }} } \right) - P\left( {{\upmu }^{{t_{0} }} ,{\uppi }^{{t_{0} }} } \right)} \right] + R$$
(6)

where \(\mu\) and \(\pi\) stand for the average income and an inequality measure, respectively; \(P({\mu }^{{t}_{0}},{\pi }^{{t}_{0}})\) is the FGT index before reforms;; \(P({\mu }^{{t}_{1}},{\pi }^{{t}_{0}})\) the FGT index before reforms when all the pre-reform incomes are multiplied by \({\mu }^{{t}_{1}}/{\mu }^{{t}_{0}}\); and finally \(P({\mu }^{{t}_{0}},{\pi }^{{t}_{1}})\) the FGT index after reforms when all the pre-reform incomes are multiplied by \({\mu }^{{t}_{0}}/{\mu }^{{t}_{1}}\). In this expression, the first term gathers all the components related to growth, the second the ones related to inequality and R is a residual term that collects all the changes not explained by the others.

This residual component can be ruled out by using the Shapley value, so that poverty changes can also be expressed as the addition of only two components related to growth and redistribution:

$$\begin{gathered} P_{1} - P_{0} = C_{1} + C_{2} \hfill \\ C_{1} = \frac{1}{2}\left( {\left[ {P\left( {{\upmu }^{{t_{1} }} ,{\uppi }^{{t_{0} }} } \right) - P\left( {{\upmu }^{{t_{0} }} ,{\uppi }^{{t_{0} }} } \right)} \right] + \left[ {P\left( {{\upmu }^{{t_{1} }} ,{\uppi }^{{t_{1} }} } \right) - P\left( {{\upmu }^{{t_{0} }} ,{\uppi }^{{t_{1} }} } \right)} \right]} \right) \hfill \\ C_{2} = \frac{1}{2}\left( {\left[ {P\left( {{\upmu }^{{t_{0} }} ,{\uppi }^{{t_{1} }} } \right) - P\left( {{\upmu }^{{t_{0} }} ,{\uppi }^{{t_{0} }} } \right)} \right] + \left[ {P\left( {{\upmu }^{{t_{1} }} ,{\uppi }^{{t_{1} }} } \right) - P\left( {{\upmu }^{{t_{1} }} ,{\uppi }^{{t_{0} }} } \right)} \right]} \right) \hfill \\ \end{gathered}$$
(7)

Besides, this methodology requires using absolute measures of poverty or, at least, only one poverty line in both periods with relative measures. Thus, the statistical disturbance in the decomposition coming from different thresholds in time can be avoided. Although any of both poverty lines can be used, the poverty measure anchored at the before-reform period is chosen.Footnote 17

Figures in Table 3 deeply support the conclusions obtained from the previous microsimulation analysis. Decomposing the poverty increase derived from rising the VAT rate shows that almost all this increase is caused by drops in average income (growth component). If the rising taxes had not been changed the income, inequality would have not affected on poverty. Therefore, lower values of inequality coexist with increases in poverty.

Table 3 Poverty changes decomposition

Whereas, the outcomes related to Scenario 2 also confirm the microsimulation results. Inequality appears as the main driving factor to poverty increases. Even if income means had not decreased, the poverty difference would have been almost the same. The drop in labour incomes as well as the rise of capital incomes would have driven to uneven impacts on income distribution. Furthermore, despite of the former, poverty would rise because of the evolution of income means, even when no inequality changes.

In sum, the microsimulation model completes the CGE results by allowing one to estimate the distributional impacts. The decision between both policy reforms is between a general worsening of living conditions or keeping the income means at the expense of higher levels of inequality and poverty. Although the models do not provide the best solution, both give enough information to assess the effects of a decision taken by the society.

6 Conclusions

The Great Recession has renewed the interest on the relationship between macroeconomic conditions and actual household living conditions. In Europe, as well as other advanced economies, welfare states are on the spotlight. They face an increasing demand for social protection as result of the rising unemployment and the falls in household income. However, at the same time, their capacity to provide such protection is constrained due to the austerity measures undertaken to deal with deficit and promote growth in the medium and long-term.

Besides, the increasing trend of inequality in OECD countries from the 70’s decade focuses the political and economic debate on this issue. Questions as which is the path of transmitting economic booms or crises to living conditions, or if macroeconomic recovery always means people’s wellbeing recovery are key to understand and explain the current and future society.

Given the dramatic drop in GDP, but also in household incomes, the need of exploring this relationship becomes even more important. In addition, this kind of analysis can help one comprehend why so often, political decisions are not understood by public opinion. In this sense, an evaluation of the whole effects of policy changes should be carried out before applying them.

On the other hand, the combination of a CGE model and a microsimulation model represents an appropriate tool for this kind of analysis. Specifically, for our study it offers relevant insights about the impact of austerity measures to achieve Stability and Growth Pact on income inequality. The macroeconomic results point out that the VAT hike has a worse impact on the different sources of households’ income compared to the public spending cut. However, in terms of inequality, the increase of VAT rate leads to a less unequal situation compared to the reduction of public expenditure, but also poorer living conditions. That very slight reduction of inequality combined with a noticeable decrease of household income mean depict an impoverished society, as poverty indicators confirm. This result fits well with the existing evidence on the redistributive effects of austerity measures, which mostly points out that spending cuts have more detrimental effects than tax hikes.

These findings also highlight the nexus between income inequality and the distribution of the different income sources in a society. Therefore, the analysis performed in this paper can help the policy designers to choose the best strategies to achieve the socially desirable goals of reducing inequality and poverty, which considered as the defining challenge of our time by the most international institutions.