Skip to main content
Log in

The past and future of evolutionary economics: some reflections based on new bibliometric evidence

  • Article
  • Published:
Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The modern wave of ‘evolutionary economics’ was launched in 1982 with the classic study by Nelson and Winter. This paper reports a broad bibliometric analysis of ‘evolutionary’ research in the disciplines of management, business, economics, and sociology over 25 years from 1986 to 2010. It confirms that Nelson and Winter's book (An evolutionary theory of economic change, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA, 1982) is an enduring nodal reference point for this broad field. The bibliometric evidence suggests that ‘evolutionary economics’ has benefitted from the rise of business schools and other interdisciplinary institutions, which have provided a home for evolutionary terminology, but it has failed to nurture a strong unifying core narrative or theory, which, in turn, could provide superior answers to important questions. This bibliometric evidence also shows that no strong cluster of general theoretical research immediately around Nelson and Winter's classic book has subsequently emerged. It identifies developmental problems in a partly successful but fragmented field. Future research in ‘evolutionary economics’ needs a more integrated research community with shared conceptual narratives and common research questions, to promote conversation and synergy between diverse clusters of research.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Winter (2014) depicted evolutionary economics as occupying a ‘beachhead’ within economics. But Stoelhorst (2014) pointed out that the bibliometric and other evidence shows its greater presence within management and business.

  2. The widening our focus of research to additional disciplines (such as politics and history) would have limited our ability to study the structure of the field effectively. Increased heterogeneity would have made the identification of different research streams trickier. Also, our software restricts the number of articles and the number of cited pieces of work. With about 350,000 potential citation objects, we are already near the current performance limits of the Sitkis software. As shown in Fig. 1, by a good margin, the most important areas using ‘evolutionary’ terminology are management, business and economics.

  3. Bhupatiraju et al. (2012) found that citations between the fields of (1) entrepreneurship, (2) innovation studies, and (3) studies in science and technology are scarcer than citations within the fields. Although the three fields share research topics and themes, they have developed largely on their own and in relative isolation from one another. This further confirms the problem of spanning different research communities.

  4. In the US, for example, the number of graduate degrees (masters and doctorates) in business increased from 55,775 in 1980 to 77,769 in 1990, 112,726 in 2000, and 170,498 in 2009. By comparison, the number of US graduate degrees in ‘social sciences and history’ was 15,406, 14,644, 18,161 and 23,474 in those same years (US Census Bureau 2012). The Economist (1996, p. 54) reported that ‘the number of business schools in Britain has risen from 20 in the early 1980s to 120’ by 1996.

  5. In Figs. 2, 3 and 4, the size of the node represents the relative citing frequency of the document. The thickness of the line connecting two documents indicates the strength of the link between the documents.

  6. But further evidence suggests an even deeper divergence. The three journals citing Nelson and Winter most often since 1983, which are listed under ‘economics’ in the Thomson Reuters’ database, are Industrial and Corporate Change [accounting for 3.0 % of all citations to Nelson and Winter (1982)], the Journal of Evolutionary Economics (2.6 %), and the Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization (2.2 %): none of these is, by any account, a mainstream journal of economics. In the top ten, the seven other journals citing Nelson and Winter most since 1983 are Research Policy (5.7 %), the Strategic Management Journal (5.7 %), Organization Science (3.7 %), Management Science (2.1 %), the International Journal of Technology Management (1.9 %), and the Journal of Management Studies (1.8 %).

  7. Murmann et al. (2003) is a symptomatic millennial reflection on the state and future of ‘evolutionary’ research in management and organization theory. This article illustrates the problems as well as the potentialities. Its authors mention the concept of ‘selection’ many times but fail to give it a sufficiently clear meaning. There is little elaboration of what is being selected, what are the selection mechanisms, and what kind of selection outcomes need to be identified. While pointing to the importance of empirical work, the key concepts to be deployed in analyzing reality remain vague. Immersion in empirics itself cannot serve as a research program, especially if it is conceptually blind.

  8. Bibliometric methodology has been employed in strategic management (Martinsons et al. 2001; Ramos-Rodriguez and Ruiz-Navarro 2004); economics (Cahlik 2000; Pieters and Baumgartner 2002); entrepreneurship (Ratnatunga and Romano 1997; Busenitz et al. 2003); organization studies (Usdiken and Pasadeos 1995); inter-organizational relationships (Sobrero and Schrader 1998; Parvinen 2003); marketing (Hoffman and Holbrook 1993; Pasadeos et al. 1998); management information systems studies (Culnan 1986); and research and development studies (Tijssen and Van Raan 1994).

  9. Data and charts for the 1991–1995, 1996–2000 and 2001–2005 sub-periods are available from the authors.

  10. The respective figures for the first sub-period were 5,700 with 384 discarded; for the second period, 27,184 and 2,963; for the third period, 45,774 and 2,974; for the fourth period, 62,460 and 4,315, and for the fifth period, 232,730 and 13,462.

  11. In the database covering the first 5-year period, the 512 documents that received at least 29 citations were checked and corrected. The level in the sub-database for the second 5-year period was set to 5 citations (top 463 documents), 7 for the third period (top 575 documents), 9 for the fourth (top 568 documents), and 12 for the fifth period (top 512 documents).

  12. Following Small and Greenlee (1980), we set thresholds with regard to the popularity of references contained in the analysis, omitting information on cited documents that have a lower impact. Consequently, for the whole period, articles or books with at least 90 references were included in the analyses. For the first sub-period, the threshold level was set to 5 references, for the second to 15 references, for the third to 24 references, for the fourth to 28 references, and for the fifth to 40 references. The networks resulting from these analyses are available from the authors upon request.

  13. There are many different cluster methods and algorithms (Jain et al. 1999). The two most popular clustering approaches are ‘hierarchical agglomerative’ and ‘iterative partitioning’ (McCain 1990).

  14. The cut-off level was set to 0.1 in the whole period, and in the two sub-periods discussed in the text.

  15. This procedure produced five clusters at a similarity level of 0.063 for the period 1986–1990. We divided two clusters into four sub-clusters, excluding four documents. For the period 2006–2010, we identified 11 clusters at a similarity level of 0.045, and 5 of them we divided into 12 sub-clusters. Three documents were excluded. For the whole period 1986–2010, we identified ten clusters at a similarity level of 0.04, and three of them were further divided into nine sub-clusters. Six documents were excluded.

References

  • Alchian AA (1950) Uncertainty, evolution, and economic theory. J Political Econ 58(3):211–221

    Google Scholar 

  • Aldrich HE (1999) Organizations evolving. Sage Publications, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Aldrich HE, Ruef M (2006) Organizations evolving. Sage Publications, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Aldrich HE, Hodgson GM, Hull DL, Knudsen T, Mokyr J, Vanberg VJ (2008) In defence of generalized Darwinism. J Evol Econ 18(5):577–596

    Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod R (1984) The evolution of cooperation. Basic Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhupatiraju S, Nomaler Ö, Triulzi G, Verspagen B (2012) Knowledge flows—analyzing the core literature of innovation, entrepreneurship and science and technology studies. Res Policy 41(7):1205–1218

    Google Scholar 

  • Blau PJ (1994) The organization of academic work. Transaction, New Brunswick

    Google Scholar 

  • Borgatti SP, Everett MG, Freeman LC (2002) UCINET 6.0 version 1.00. Analytic Technologies, Natick

    Google Scholar 

  • Boulding KE (1981) Evolutionary economics. Sage Publications, Beverly Hills

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles S, Gintis H (2011) A cooperative species: human reciprocity and its evolution. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyd R, Richerson P (1985) Culture and the evolutionary process. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Breslin D (2011) Reviewing a generalized Darwinist approach to studying socio-economic change. Int J Manag Rev 13(2):218–235

    Google Scholar 

  • Burt RS (1992) Structural holes: the social structure of competition. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Busenitz LW, West GP, Shepherd D, Nelson T, Chandler GN, Zacharakis A (2003) Entrepreneurship research in emergence: past trends and future directions. J Manag 29(3):285–308

    Google Scholar 

  • Buss DM (1999) Evolutionary psychology: the new science of the mind. Allyn and Bacon, Needham Heights

    Google Scholar 

  • Cahlik T (2000) Search for fundamental articles in economics. Scientometrics 49(3):389–402

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell DT (1965) Variation, selection and retention in sociocultural evolution. In: Barringer HR, Blanksten GI, Mack RW (eds) Social change in developing areas: a reinterpretation of evolutionary theory. Schenkman, Cambridge, pp 19–49

    Google Scholar 

  • Case DO, Higgins GM (2000) How can we investigate citation behavior? A study of reasons for citing literature in communication. J Am Soc Inf Sci Technol 51(7):635–645

    Google Scholar 

  • Cawkell AE (1976) Understanding science by analysing its literature. Inf Sci 10(1):3–10

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase RH (1937) The nature of the firm. Economica 4:386–405

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen WM, Levinthal DA (1990) Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation. Adm Sci Q 35(1):128–152

    Google Scholar 

  • Cosmides L, Tooby J (1994) Better than rational: evolutionary psychology and the invisible hand. Am Econ Rev (Pap Proc) 84(2):327–332

    Google Scholar 

  • Crane D (1972) Invisible colleges. Diffusion of knowledge in scientific communities. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Culnan MJ (1986) The intellectual development of management information systems, 1972–1982: a co-citation analysis. Manag Sci 32(2):156–172

    Google Scholar 

  • Culnan MJ (1987) Mapping the intellectual structure of MIS, 1980–1985: a co-citation analysis. MIS Q 11(3):341–353

    Google Scholar 

  • Cyert RM, March JG (1963) A behavioral theory of the firm. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs

    Google Scholar 

  • Dachs B, Roediger-Schluga T, Widhalm C, Zartl A (2001) Mapping evolutionary economics: a bibliometric analysis. In: EMAEE 2001 conference, Austria

  • Darwin CR (1859) On the origin of species by means of natural selection, or the preservation of favoured races in the struggle for life. Murray, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Dawkins R (1976) The selfish gene. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Dolfsma Wilfred, Leydesdorff Loe (2010) The citation field of evolutionary economics. J Evol Econ 20(5):645–664

    Google Scholar 

  • Dollimore D, Hodgson GM (2014) Four essays on economic evolution: an introduction. J Evol Econ 24(1):1–10

    Google Scholar 

  • Dosi G (1982) Technological paradigms and technological trajectories. Res Policy 11(3):147–162

    Google Scholar 

  • Dosi G, Freeman C, Nelson R, Silverberg G, Soete LLG (eds) (1988) Technical change and economic theory. Pinter, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunning JH (1989) The study of international business: a plea for a more interdisciplinary approach. J Int Bus Stud 20(3):411–436

    Google Scholar 

  • Durand R (2006) Organizational evolution and strategic management. Sage Publications, Beverly Hills

    Google Scholar 

  • Economist (1996) Dons and dollars. Economist, July 20, pp 53–54

  • Friedman M (1953) The methodology of positive economics. In: Friedman M (ed) Essays in positive economics. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 3–43

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman D (1991) Evolutionary games in economics. Econometrica 59(3):637–666

    Google Scholar 

  • Geroski PA (2001) Exploring the niche overlaps between organizational ecology and industrial economics. Ind Corp Change 10(2):507–540

    Google Scholar 

  • Gmür M (2003) Co-citation analysis and the search for invisible colleges: a methodological evaluation. Scientometrics 57(1):27–57

    Google Scholar 

  • Granovetter M (1973) The strength of weak ties. Am J Sociol 78(6):1360–1380

    Google Scholar 

  • Granovetter M (1985) Economic action and social structure: the problem of embeddedness. Am J Sociol 91(3):481–510

    Google Scholar 

  • Griffith BC, Small HG, Stonehill JA, Dey S (1974) The structure of scientific literatures II: toward a macro- and microstructure for science. Sci Stud 4:339–365

    Google Scholar 

  • Hair JF, Anderson RE, Tatham RL, Black WC (1998) Multivariate data analysis. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs

    Google Scholar 

  • Hammerstein P (ed) (2003) Genetic and cultural evolution of cooperation. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Hannan MT, Freeman J (1977) The population ecology of organizations. Am J Sociol 82(4):929–964

    Google Scholar 

  • Hannan MT, Freeman J (1989) Organizational ecology. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson GM (1993) Economics and evolution: bringing life back into economics. Polity Press and University of Michigan Press, Cambridge and Ann Arbor

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson GM (ed) (1998) The foundations of evolutionary economics: 1890–1973. International library of critical writings in economics, vol 2. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson GM (1999) Evolution and institutions: on evolutionary economics and the evolution of economics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson GM (2013) Understanding organizational evolution: toward a research agenda using generalized Darwinism. Organ Stud 34(7):973–992

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson GM, Huang K (2012) Evolutionary game theory and evolutionary economics: are they different species? J Evol Econ 22:345–366

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson GM, Knudsen T (2010) Darwin’s conjecture: the search for general principles of social and economic evolution. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson GM, Stoelhorst JW (2014) Introduction to the special issue on the future of institutional and evolutionary economics. J Inst Econ 10(4):513–540

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman DL, Holbrook MB (1993) The intellectual structure of consumer research: a bibliometric study of author cocitations in the first 15 years of the journal of consumer research. J Consum Res 19(4):505–517

    Google Scholar 

  • Hull DL (1988) Science as a process: an evolutionary account of the social and conceptual development of science. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Jain AK, Murty MN, Flynn PJ (1999) Data clustering: a review. ACM Comput Surv (CSUR) 31(3):264–323

    Google Scholar 

  • Kauffman SA (1995) At home in the universe: the search for laws of self-organization and complexity. Oxford University Press, Oxford and New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes JM (1936) The general theory of employment, interest and money. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Kitcher P (1993) The advancement of science: science without legend, objectivity without illusions. Oxford University Press, Oxford and New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Knorr-Cetina KD (1981) The manufacture of knowledge: an essay on the constructivist and contextual nature of science. Pergamon, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Koestler A (1964) The act of creation. Hutchinson, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuhn TS (1962) The structure of scientific revolutions. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Lakatos I (1970) Falsification and the methodology of scientific research programmes. In: Lakatos Imre, Musgrave Alan (eds) Criticism and the growth of knowledge. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 91–195

    Google Scholar 

  • Laudan L (1977) Progress and its problems: towards a theory of scientific growth. Routledge and Kegan Paul, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewin AY, Volberda HW (1999) Prolegomena on coevolution: a framework for research on strategy and new organizational forms. Organ Sci 10(5):519–534

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucio-Arias D, Leydesdorff L (2008) Main-path analysis and path-dependent transitions in HistCite™-based historiograms. J Am Soc Inf Sci Technol 59(12):1948–1962

    Google Scholar 

  • Macroberts MH, Macroberts BR (1989) Problems of citation analysis—a critical review. J Am Soc Inf Sci 40(5):342–349

    Google Scholar 

  • March JG (1991) Exploration and exploitation in organizational learning. Organ Sci 2(1):71–87

    Google Scholar 

  • March JG, Simon HA (1958) Organizations. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Martinsons MG, Everett JE, Chan K (2001) Mapping the scholarly development of strategic management. J Inf Sci 27(2):101–110

    Google Scholar 

  • McCain KW (1990) Mapping authors in intellectual space—a technical overview. J Am Soc Inf Sci 41(6):433–443

    Google Scholar 

  • Murmann JP, Aldrich HE, Levinthal D, Winter SG (2003) Evolutionary thought in management and organization theory at the beginning of the new millennium: a symposium on the state of the art and opportunities for future research. J Manag Inq 12(1):22–40

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RR (1995) Recent evolutionary theorizing about economic change. J Econ Lit 33(1):48–90

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RR, Winter SG (1982) An evolutionary theory of economic change. Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RR, Winter SG (2002) Evolutionary theorizing in economics. J Econ Perspect 16(2-Spring):23–46

    Google Scholar 

  • Noam EM (1995) Electronics and the dim future of the university. Science 270:247–249

    Google Scholar 

  • Osareh F (1996) Bibliometrics, citation analysis and co-citation analysis: a review of literature. 2. Libri 46(4):217–225

    Google Scholar 

  • Parvinen MT (2003) Towards a governance perspective to mergers and acquisitions. Helsinki University of Technology, Espoo

    Google Scholar 

  • Pasadeos Y, Phelps J, Kim BH (1998) Disciplinary impact of advertising scholars: temporal comparisons of influential authors, works and research networks. J Advert 27(4):53–54

    Google Scholar 

  • Peirce CS (1958) Collected papers of Charles Sanders Peirce. In: Burks AW (ed) Science and philosophy, vol VII. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Pessali HF (2006) The rhetoric of Oliver Williamson’s transaction cost economics. J Inst Econ 2(1):45–65

    Google Scholar 

  • Pieters R, Baumgartner H (2002) Who talks to whom? Intra- and interdisciplinary communication of economics journals. J Econ Lit 40(2):483–509

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramos-Rodriguez AR, Ruiz-Navarro J (2004) Changes in the intellectual structure of strategic management research: a bibliometric study of the Strategic Management Journal, 1980–2000. Strateg Manag J 25(10):981–1004

    Google Scholar 

  • Ratnatunga J, Romano C (1997) A “citation classics” analysis of articles in contemporary small enterprise research. J Bus Ventur 12(3):197–212

    Google Scholar 

  • Schildt HA (2002) SITKIS: software for bibliometric data management and analysis. Helsinki University of Technology, Espoo

    Google Scholar 

  • Schildt H (2004) Sitkis: SITKIS 2.0: software for bibliometric data management and analysis. Helsinki: Institute of Strategy and International Business. http://www.hut.fi/~hschildt/sitkis

  • Schildt HA, Mattsson JT (2006) A dense network sub-grouping algorithm for co-citation analysis and its implementation in the software tool Sitkis. Scientometrics 67(1):143–163

    Google Scholar 

  • Schildt HA, Zahra SA, Sillanpää A (2006) Scholarly communities in entrepreneurship research: a co-citation analysis. Entrep Theory Pract 30(3):399–415

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1934) The theory of economic development: an inquiry into profits, capital, credit, interest, and the business cycle. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Sillanpää A (2006) Firm strategies in the competition for dominance of networked business systems. Helsinki University of Technology, Espoo

    Google Scholar 

  • Silva ST, Teixeira AAC (2009) On the divergence of evolutionary research paths in the past 50 years: a comprehensive bibliometric account. J Evol Econ 19(5):605–642

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon HA (1957) Models of man: social and rational. Mathematical Essays on Rational Human Behavior in a Social Setting, Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon HA (1969) The sciences of the artificial. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Small H (1973) Co-citation in the scientific literature: a new measure of the relationship between publications. J Am Soc Inf Sci 24(4):265–269

    Google Scholar 

  • Small H (2004) On the shoulders of Robert Merton: towards a normative theory of citation. Scientometrics 60(1):71–79

    Google Scholar 

  • Small H, Greenlee E (1980) Citation context analysis of a co-citation cluster: recombinant-DNA. Scientometrics 2(4):277–301

    Google Scholar 

  • Sobrero M, Schrader S (1998) Structuring inter-firm relationships: a meta-analytic approach. Organ Stud 19(4):585–615

    Google Scholar 

  • Starkey K, Madan P (2001) Bridging the relevance gap: aligning stakeholders in the future of management research. Br J Manag 12(Suppl S1):S3–S26

    Google Scholar 

  • Stoelhorst JW (2008) The explanatory logic and ontological commitments of generalized Darwinism. J Econ Methodol 15(4):343–363

    Google Scholar 

  • Stoelhorst JW (2014) The future of evolutionary economics is in a vision from the past: a comment on the essays on evolutionary economics by Sidney Winter and Ulrich Witt. J Inst Econ 10(4):665–682

    Google Scholar 

  • Tijssen RJW, Van Raan AFJ (1994) Mapping changes in science and technology: bibliometric co-occurrence analysis of the R and D literature. Eval Rev 18(1):98–115

    Google Scholar 

  • Trivers R (1985) Social evolution. Benjamin/Cummings, Menlo Park

    Google Scholar 

  • United States Census Bureau (2012) Statistical abstract. http://www.census.gov/compendia/statab/cats/education.html. Accessed 19 May 2013

  • Usdiken B, Pasadeos Y (1995) Organizational analysis in North-America and Europe—a comparison of co-citation networks. Organ Stud 16(3):503–526

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Raan AFJ (2000) The interdisciplinary nature of science: theoretical framework and bibliometric-empirical approach. In: Weingart P, Stehr N (eds) Practising interdisciplinarity. University of Toronto Press, Toronto, pp 66–77

    Google Scholar 

  • Veblen TB (1898) Why is economics not an evolutionary science? Q J Econ 12(3):373–397

    Google Scholar 

  • Veblen TB (1899) The theory of the leisure class: an economic study in the evolution of institutions. Macmillan, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Verspagen B, Werker C (2003) The invisible college of the economics of innovation and technological change. Estudios de Economía Aplicada 21(3):393–419

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingart P, Stehr N (eds) (2000) Practising interdisciplinarity. University of Toronto Press, Toronto

    Google Scholar 

  • Wenger E (1998) Communities of practice: learning, memory and identity. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Whitley R (1984) The intellectual and social organisation of the sciences. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Whitley R (1986) The structure and context of economics as a scientific field. Res Hist Econ Thought Methodol 4:179–209

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson OE (1975) Markets and hierarchies: analysis and antitrust implications: a study in the economics of internal organization. Free Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson OE (1985) The economic institutions of capitalism. Free Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson EO (1975) Sociobiology. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Winter SG (2014) The future of evolutionary economics: can we break out of the beachhead? J Inst Econ 10(4):613–644

    Google Scholar 

  • Witt U (2003) The evolving economy: essays on the evolutionary approach to economics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham and Northampton

    Google Scholar 

  • Witt U (2008) What is specific about evolutionary economics? J Evol Econ 18:547–575

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors are very grateful to Denise Dollimore, Francesca Gagliardi, Thorbjørn Knudsen, Gerry Silverberg, Jan-Willem Stoelhorst, Bart Verspagen, and others for comments on earlier versions of this essay. The authors also thank Joonas Järvinen for extensive research assistance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Geoffrey M. Hodgson.

Appendix: Bibliometric methodology

Appendix: Bibliometric methodology

Bibliometrics involves the analysis of patterns that appear in the publication and use of documents, to shed light on the nature and development of a discipline.Footnote 8

Citation analysis is a powerful tool for the identification of intellectual bases and underlying research streams (Usdiken and Pasadeos 1995; Pasadeos et al. 1998; Schildt and Mattsson 2006). Citation analyses divide into ‘macro’ approaches that focus on the overall structure of disciplines, and develop principles governing the evolution of science, and ‘micro’ approaches that describe retrospectively the structure and historical development of schools of research and their interdependencies (Gmür 2003). This study fits with the micro-stream of research.

Criticisms of the use of citation analysis concern citation biases, a focus on only published articles and books, and the technical limitations and imperfections of citation indices and bibliographies (Macroberts and Macroberts 1989; Osareh 1996). With improved databases, some of these limitations have been ameliorated (Sillanpää 2006). Important limitations remain, but we have done our best to address possible biases and to remove errors from our extensive database.

Our approach combines co-citation and cluster analysis (Schildt et al. 2006; Sillanpää 2006; Schildt and Mattsson 2006). Co-citation analysis reveals the closeness of two pieces of work in a common discourse. Cluster analysis and network analysis enable further structuring the research field under study. Our approach of highlighting the structure of the field by the means of both cluster analysis and network analysis (which produce highly similar results) mitigates the biases in any individual research method.

1.1 Data

We used data from the Social Science Citation Index (SSCI) of the Thomson-Reuters Web of Science, which is a massive multidisciplinary index to social sciences journals. It indexes over 1,720 journals across 50 social science disciplines; and individually selected, relevant items from over 3,300 of the world’s leading scientific and technical journals.

Within the database, we conducted searches for the word evolution and its derivatives. Further searches confirmed the result of Dachs et al. (2001) that related search words (e.g., Schumpeter, biological, biology, genes) yielded a much smaller number of retrieved articles, compared to ‘evolution’ and ‘evolutionary’. To narrow down the number of hits (over 20,000), and confine our study to business-related issues, we refined the search to cover documents related to the following fields only: management, business, economics, and sociology. The search was further refined to cover articles only, thus excluding book reviews, notes and editorial announcements.

The start date of the searches was 1 January 1986 (the 1st accessible year on the Thomson-Reuters database), and the end date was 31 December 2010. Before 1986, much fewer articles discussing ‘evolution’ were published in the social sciences (Hodgson 1998). To identify changes for the whole period, we retrieved 8,474 articles; 217 were published during 1986–1990, 954 during 1991–1995, 1,637 during 1996–2000, 2,172 during 2001–2005, and 3,494 during 2006–2010. These were all possible citation sources.Footnote 9

Sitkis computer software (Schildt 2004) was used to download data on possible citation objects from the Web of Science to a Microsoft Access database. The articles in the whole period cited another 373,848 texts, of which 24,098 were discarded by the program.Footnote 10 The program reported disregarded citations, and all of these were checked manually. Most referred to newspapers, trade journal articles or statistics and were deemed tangential to this analysis. A small number of corrections were made.

Thomson Reuters’ data are not entirely accurate. In the first 5-year sub-period, we went through all the citations manually and made any required corrections. But because the total number of references in other sub-periods exceeded 20,000, going through all of these was impossible. Schildt (2002) argued that correcting citation data for the top 20–50 authors or documents is sufficient to provide reliable and usable results. But we imposed higher standards.Footnote 11

References made to reprints and book editions were combined as references to one, original article or book. But citations to compiled book editions were left unaltered (Sillanpää 2006).

1.2 Analysis

A co-citation involves a link between two documents that is created by a later document (Griffith et al. 1974). A co-citation measures ‘the frequency with which two documents are cited together’ (Small 1973, p. 265). If two articles are cited in the same text, then they may be closely related to each other either because they are part of the same topic area or because their topic areas are closely connected (Small 1973; Cawkell 1976). Although some co-citations are between unrelated references, a sufficiently large sample of cited articles enables researchers to mitigate this problem (Schildt and Mattsson 2006).

Using Sitkis software, we produced a co-citation network for each sub-period. A threshold level, based on the frequency the citing articles cited the references, was used to exclude references that did not have a serious impact on the study (Schildt et al. 2006). A series of two-dimensional (citer-cited) networks were then produced to determine the best threshold level. In a two-dimensional network, the citing articles were the first dimensions, and the cited texts acted as their affiliations. When the threshold was raised, the number of remaining cited documents decreased, and the number of citing articles also declined. After testing the series of networks, the threshold was set to a point at which lowering the threshold level by one would bring the maximum marginal increase in the number of cited articles. Below this threshold, the heterogeneity of the cited documents increased considerably, leaving additional documents outside the core of the field.Footnote 12

Next, we normalized co-citation data to emphasize proximate relationships between similar references that are not cited as often as the most common references (Gmür 2003). The normalized co-citation strength measure, S, for individual pairs was calculated by means of the Jaccard index (Small and Greenlee 1980). The co-citation link strength S(A, B) between papers A and B is defined as follows:

$$S(A,B) = \frac{a \cap b}{a + b - a \cap b},$$

where a represents the number of citations to document A, b the number of citations to document B, and a ∩ b the number of co-citations of A and B.

We employed cluster analysis to classify objects into clusters that maximize homogeneity within clusters and heterogeneity between clusters (Culnan 1987; Hair et al. 1998).Footnote 13 We employed Johnston’s average-link hierarchical algorithm, as in the Ucinet 6 software (Borgatti et al. 2002), to produce clusters from the co-citation network data. In the average-link algorithm, the distance between two clusters is the average dissimilarity between members (Borgatti et al. 2002). According to Sillanpää (2006), the average-link method produces clusters more continuously than other hierarchical methods.

Ucinet Netdraw software was used to draw network figures from the co-citation network data for the sub-periods. To make reading of the networks easier, we reduced the number of visible links by imposing an arbitrary cut-off level of co-citation strength. The links below the cut-off level were left out of the figures, as well as documents isolated by the procedure.Footnote 14 The Netdraw software then arranged the remaining documents according to geodesic distances.

We performed the cluster analysis for documents in co-citation networks for the sub-periods, and for the 1986–2010 period as a whole. As there is no unique way to identify clusters, their identification involves some interpretation: we used similarity levels calculated by the algorithm as guidelines. We set two rules for the identification of clusters from the tree diagrams. First, an independent cluster or sub-cluster must consist of at least two documents. Second, main clusters were separated at a similarity level that produced a moderate number of clearly identifiable clusters.Footnote 15

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hodgson, G.M., Lamberg, JA. The past and future of evolutionary economics: some reflections based on new bibliometric evidence. Evolut Inst Econ Rev 15, 167–187 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40844-016-0044-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40844-016-0044-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation