Skip to main content
Log in

Veblen’s evolutionary methodology and its implications for heterodox economics in the calculable future

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Review of Evolutionary Political Economy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Critics have repeatedly claimed that heterodox economics has failed. They blame heterodox economists for their own failure. I subject this claim to critical examination from the perspective of Veblen’s evolutionary methodology. Veblen’s theory of the business enterprise will be used as an example, which exemplifies the case that a ‘blasphemous’ theory is ignored and marginalized even though it provides rich and perspicacious insights into the evolution of economy and society. It is also argued that social science does not follow the biological principle of natural selection and the survival of the fittest. What survives does not necessarily mean the fittest in the social realm. The history of science is replete with paradoxical incidents that an incoherent, irrelevant, or even wrong theory becomes dominant and widely accepted because it is one that serves the vested interests in academia and society. Economics is no exception.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Data availability

NA

Notes

  1. There are different definitions of heterodox economics. By heterodox economics, I mean here the various schools of thought that are organized through currently active intellectual communities (see, Lee 2009: pp. 203–204) and that provide a scientific analysis of the social provisioning process (Jo and Todorova 2018; Jo et al. 2018a). How to classify heterodox economics from the Veblenian perspective is one of the main issues dealt with in this article (in particular, Section 4).

  2. Marshall’s evolutionary thinking was largely influenced by Herbert Spencer, rather than by Charles Darwin, as evidenced by Marshall’s biological analogies of the survival of the fittest and natural selection which presume that economy and society resemble the natural realm (Marshall [1890] 1920: p. 241; Hodgson 2004; Jennings and Waller 1998; Laurent 2000; Thomas 1991; Jo 2019b).

  3. The concept of the ‘joint stock of community knowledge’ warrants further but brief elaboration as it is relevant to the present discussion. The stock of (technological and managerial) knowledge animates resources (and, of course, requires resources to conduct scientific enterprise). That is to say, whether any resource is useful or not depends upon the joint stock of community knowledge; and by the same token, some previously utilized resources become obsolete when new knowledge is created and accepted. In this regard, “Resources are not, they become; they are not static but expand and contract in response to human wants and acts” (Zimmermann [1933] 1951: 15, original italics). Two important theoretical implications can be drawn from this evolutionary view of resources. Firstly, if all knowledge is socially created, it is not possible to single out one individual’s ‘productivity’ from another’s in the process of production. Labor, natural inputs, and the produced means of production become productive resources because of the joint stock of technological and managerial knowledge in place. ‘Capital’ or ‘labor’ alone cannot be productive in and by itself. Capital goods should be mobilized by skilled labor for a particular productive purpose. The joint stock of knowledge accumulated from the past determines the kind of inputs and the utilization ratio between inputs. Thus it is not possible to have the neoclassical production function with variable input proportions, marginal productivity, and profit maximization from Veblen’s evolutionary perspective (Veblen [1914] 1964b: 103, 144; Lee 2018: pp. 43–45). Consequently, a theory of the business enterprise that is completely different from the mainstream theory is required. Veblen (1904) is an attempt to that end (more on this in Section 3). Secondly, the assumption of scarce resources is a non-evolutionary, static, and hypothetical concept which presumes the fixed system of individual preference and society (including markets) and the absence of transformative social agency. Some evolutionary-institutional economists, however, postulate ‘local and global scarcity’ (Hodgson 2019: 54), the concept of which is at odds with this evolutionary point of view. While Hodgson calls for a more precise use of the scarcity concept, his local and global scarcity concept is still neither precise nor relevant to the critique of the incoherent neoclassical concept of relative scarcity (see Levine 1977: pp. 180–186, for a trenchant critique of the scarcity concept). Moreover, both Veblen’s and Zimmermann’s arguments are not about the temporal, individual, or locational availability of a resource. They are about the creation and use of resources that depends upon the accumulated joint stock of knowledge and the decision to generate specific knowledge for a particular purpose.

  4. A careful and informed reader, like one of the anonymous reviewers of this journal, would raise a question if I mean here that evolutionary-heterodox economists would or should reject mathematical formalism entirely. My answer is no. Although this is one of controversial issues that merits a fuller discussion, let me just briefly discuss since it is not directly linked to the main thesis of the present article. The same reviewer also brought up her/his own experience that most mainstream economists believe economics without mathematics is poetry and an economist who does not build a mathematical model is not an economist. For example, many students and economists of Harvard University did not consider John Kenneth Galbraith an economist because “he wasn’t a modeler” (Coyle 2007: 231). These observations indicate that there is a fundamental difference between heterodox economics and mainstream economics in terms of the use of mathematics in economic analysis. In this regard, I am quite sympathetic to Tony Lawson’s argument that heterodox economists are opposed to the “abuse of mathematical formalism,” rather than simply rejecting the use of mathematics (Lawson 2009: p. 190). By the same token, Veblen ([1908] 1961a) is critical of the mathematical-deductivist models to the extent it is a fundamentally limited way of explaining the uncertain and open-ended socio-historical process.

  5. Nelson and Winter (1982: p. 39) consider their evolutionary approach “neo-Schumpeterian.” They also claim that it is an alternative to the neoclassical theory for the reasons stated here. There is a vast literature on the neo-Schumpeterian approach to economics which is not confined to Nelson and Winter (see, e.g., Magnusson 1994). One of two anonymous reviewers of this journal asserts without supporting arguments that the same critiques of new institutional economics cannot be applied to the ‘heterodox’ neo-Schumpeterian theory. I do not agree (and, interestingly, the other reviewer is of the same opinion as the present author). I would refer readers to Jo (2019b) which argues that Nelson and Winter’s evolutionary theory is an anti-Veblenian theory and a protective modification of the neoclassical theory.

  6. To quote Veblen, “It may be interesting to point out that the like identification of the categories of normality and right gives the dominant note of Mr. Spencer’s ethical and social philosophy, and that later economists of the classical line are prone to be Spencerians” (Veblen [1900] 1961a, 167). And also: “It is a notable fact that even the genius of Herbert Spencer could extract nothing but taxonomy from his hedonistic postulates; e.g., his Social Statics. Spencer is both evolutionist and hedonist, but it is only by recourse to other factors, alien to the rational hedonistic scheme, such as habit, delusions, use and disuse, sporadic variation, environment forces, that he is able to achieve anything in the way of genetic science, since it is only by this recourse that he is enabled to enter the field of cumulative change within which the modern post-Darwinian science live and move and have their being” (Veblen [1908] 1961e, pp. 191–192).

References

  • Anderson KL (1933) The unity of Veblen’s theoretical system. Q J Econ 47(4):598–626

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Argyrous G, Sethi R (1996) The theory of evolution and the evolution of theory: Veblen’s methodology in contemporary perspective. Camb J Econ 20(4):475–495

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker MC, Knudsen T (2012) Nelson and Winter revisited. In: Dietrich M, Krafft J (eds) Handbook on the economics and theory of the firm. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, p 243–255

  • Boulding K (1984) Review of an evolutionary theory of economic change by Richard R. Nelson and Sidney G. Winter. Am J Agr Econ 66(4):535–536

  • Colander D (2010) Moving beyond the rhetoric of pluralism: suggestions for an inside the mainstream heterodoxy. In: Garnett RF, Olsen E, Starr M (eds)  Economic pluralism. Routledge, London, p 36–47

  • Colander D, Holt RPF, Rosser JB (2004) The changing face of mainstream economics. Rev Polit Econ 16(4):485–499

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colander D, Holt RPF, Rosser JB (2007–8) Live and dead issues in the methodology of economics. J Post Keynes Econ 30(2):303–312

  • Coyle D (2007) The soulful science: what economists really do and shy it matters. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Dugger WM (1990) The new institutionalism: new but not institutionalist. J Econ Issues 24(2):423–431

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dugger WM (1995) Douglass C. North’s new institutionalism. J Econ Issues 29(2):453–458

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dugger WM (2006) Veblen’s radical theory of social evolution. J Econ Issues 40(3):651–672

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dugger WM, Sherman HJ (1994) Comparison of Marxism and institutionalism. J Econ Issues 28(1):101–127

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edgell S, Tilman R (1989) The intellectual antecedents of Thorstein Veblen: a reappraisal. J Econ Issues 23(4):1003–1026

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Endres T (2004) One hundred years from today. Hist Econ Rev 40(1):152–156

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finch J, McMaster R (2018) History matters: on the mystifying appeal of Bowles and Gintis. Camb J Econ 42(2):285–308

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fine B (2019) Economics and interdisciplinarity: one step forward, n steps back? Revista Crítica de Ciências Sociais 119:131–148

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fontana G, Gerrard B (2006) The future of Post Keynesian economics. Banca Nationale del Lavoro Quarterly Review 59(236):49–80

    Google Scholar 

  • Foss NJ (1998) The competence-based approach: Veblenian ideas in the modern theory of the firm. Camb J Econ 22(4):479–495

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frigato P, Santos-Arteaga FJ (2012) Planned obsolescence and the manufacture of doubt: on social costs and the evolutionary theory of the firm. In: Ramazzotti P, Frigato P, Elsner W (eds) Social costs today: institutional analyses of the present crises. Routledge, London, p 73–95

    Google Scholar 

  • Groenewegen J (2004) Who should control the firm? Insights from new and original institutional economics. J Econ Issues 38(2):353–361

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henry JF (1990) The making of neoclassical economics. Unwin Hyman, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Henry JF (2018) Society and its institutions. In: Jo T-H, Chester L, D’Ippoliti C (eds), p 163–175

  • Hodgson GM (2004) Social Darwinism in anglophone academic journals: a contribution to the history of the term. J Hist Sociol 17(4):428–463

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson GM (2007) The 2007 Veblen-Commons award recipient: Richard R. Nelson. J Econ Issues 41(2):311

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson GM (2013) Understanding organizational evolution: toward a research agenda using generalized Darwinism. Organ Stud 34(7):973–992

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson GM (2019) Is there a future for heterodox economics? Institutions, ideology and a scientific community. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson GM, Knudsen T (2004) The firm as an interactor: firms as vehicles for habits and routines. J Evo Econ 14:281–307

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holt RPF, Rosser JB, Colander D (2011) The complexity era in economics. Rev Polit Econ 23(3):357–369

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jennings A, Waller W (1998) The place of biological science in Veblen’s economics. Hist Polit Econ 30(2):189–216

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jo T-H (2018) A heterodox theory of the business enterprise. In: Jo T-H, Chester L, D’Ippoliti C (eds), p 199–212

  • Jo T-H (2019a) The institutionalist theory of the business enterprise: past, present, and future. J Econ Issues 53(3):597–611

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jo T-H (2019b) A Veblenian critique of Nelson and Winter’s evolutionary theory. MPRA working paper 101380. https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/101380. Accessed 22 August 2020

  • Jo T-H, Henry JF (2015) The business enterprise in the age of money manager capitalism. J Econ Issues 49(1):23–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jo T-H, Todorova Z (2018) Social provisioning process: a heterodox view of the economy. In: Jo T-H, Chester L, D’Ippoliti C (eds), p 29–40

  • Jo T-H, Chester L, D’Ippoliti C (2018a) The state of the art and challenges for heterodox economics. In: Jo T-H, Chester L, D’Ippoliti C (eds), p 3–26

  • Jo T-H, Chester L, D’Ippoliti C (eds) (2018b) The Routledge handbook of heterodox economics. Routledge, London

  • Kay NM (1994) Theory of the firms. In: Hodgson GM, Samuels WJ, Tool MR (eds) The Elgar companion to institutional and evolutionary economics, Edward Elgar, vol 1. Aldershot, UK, p 237–241

    Google Scholar 

  • Knoedler JT (1995) Transaction cost theories of business enterprise from Williamson and Veblen: convergence, divergence, and some evidence. J Econ Issues 29(2):385–395

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kvangraven IH, Alves C (2019) Why so hostile? Busting myths about heterodox economics. https://developingeconomics.org/2019/05/08/why-so-hostile-busting-myths-about-heterodox-economics. Accessed 22 April 2020

  • Laurent J (2000) Alfred Marshall’s annotations on Herbert Spencer’s Principles of Biology. Marshall Studies Bulletin 7. https://www.disei.unifi.it/upload/sub/pubblicazioni/msb/2000/laurent7.pdf. Accessed 21 April 2020

  • Lavoie M (2014) Post-Keynesian economics: new foundations. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lawson T (2003) Reorienting economics. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Lawson T (2009) On the nature and roles of formalism in economics. In: Fullbrook E (ed) Ontology and economics: Tony Lawson and his critics. Routledge, London, p 189–231

  • Lawson T ([2013] 2016) What is this ‘school’ called neoclassical economics? In: Morgan J (ed) What is neoclassical economics? Debating the origins, meaning and significance. Routledge, London, p 30–80. Originally published in Camb J of Econ 37(5):947–983

  • Lee FS (2009) A history of heterodox economics: challenging the mainstream in the twentieth century. Routledge, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lee FS (2013) Heterodox economics and its critics. In: Lee FS, Lavoie M (eds) In defense of Post-Keynesian and heterodox economics. Routledge, London, p 104–132

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee FS (2018) Microeconomic theory: a heterodox approach, Jo T-H (ed). Routledge, London

  • Levine DP (1977) Economic studies: contributions to the critique of economic theory. Routledge & Kegan Paul, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Magnusson L (ed) (1994) Evolutionary and neo-Schumpeterian approaches to economics. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall A ([1890] 1920) Principles of economics, 8th edn. Macmillan, London

  • Marx K (1852) The eighteenth Brumaire of Louis Bonaparte. Marx/Engels online archive. https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1852/18th-brumaire/index.htm. Accessed 21 April 2020

  • Mayhew A (2000) Veblen and theories of the ‘firm.’ In: Louça F, Perlman M (eds) Is economics an evolutionary science? The legacy of Thorstein Veblen. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK, p 54–63

  • Mearman A, Berger S, Guizzo D (2019) What is heterodox economics: conversations with leading economists. Routledge, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mirowski P ([1983] 1998) Nelson and Winter’s evolutionary theory of economic change. In: Against mechanism: protecting economics from science. Rowman & Littlefield, Totowa, NJ, p 161–170. Originally published as ‘An evolutionary theory of economics [sic] change: a review article, J Econ Issues 17(2):757–768

  • Mumford L (1931) Thorstein Veblen. The New Republic, August 5:314–316

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RR, Winter SG (1982) An evolutionary theory of economic change. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Nightingale J, Potts J (2003) An alternative framework for economics. In: Fullbrook E (ed) The crisis in economics. Routledge, London, p 180–182

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramstad Y (1994) On the nature of economic evolution: John R. Commons and the metaphor of artificial selection

  • Rosser JB, Colander D, Holt RPF (2013) How can something so right as heterodox economics have so little influence? http://cob.jmu.edu/rosserjb/Friendly%209%2012%2012%20final.docx. Accessed 21 April 2020

  • Spencer H ([1862] 1890) First principles, 5th edn. Williams and Norgate, London

  • Thomas B (1991) Alfred Marshall on economic biology. Rev Polit Econ 3(1):1–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tilman R (1996) The intellectual legacy of Thorstein Veblen: unsolved issues. Greenwood Press, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Tilman R (2007) Thorstein Veblen and enrichment of evolutionary naturalism. University of Missouri Press, Columbia, MO

    Google Scholar 

  • Veblen, T ([1896] 1973) Review of Socialisme et science positive by Enrico Ferri. In: Dorfman J (ed) Thorstein Veblen: essays, reviews and reports. Augustus M. Kelley, Clifton, NJ, p 449–455. Originally published in J Polit Econ 5(1):97–103

  • Veblen T (1904) The theory of business enterprise. Charles Scribner’s Sons, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Veblen T ([1918] 1957) The higher learning in America: a memorandum of the conduct of universities by business men. Hill and Wang, New York

  • Veblen T (1919) The vested interests and the common man. BW Huebsch, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Veblen T ([1908] 1961a) The evolution of the scientific point of view. In: the place of science in modern civilisation and other essays. Russell & Russell, New York, p 32–55. Originally published in University of California Chronicle 10(4)

  • Veblen T ([1901] 1961b) Industrial and pecuniary employments. In: the place of science in modern civilisation and other essays. Russell & Russell, New York, p 279–323. Originally published in Am J Econ 2(1):190–235

  • Veblen T ([1906] 1961c) The place of science in modern civilisation. In: the place of science in modern civilisation and other essays. Russell & Russell, New York, p 2–31. Originally published in Am J Sociol 11(5):585–609

  • Veblen T ([1900] 1961d) The preconceptions of economic science III. In: the place of science in modern civilisation and other essays. Russell & Russell, New York, p 148–179. Originally published in Q J Econ 14(2):240–269

  • Veblen T ([1908] 1961e) Professor Clark’s economics. In: the place of science in modern civilisation and other essays. Russell & Russell, New York, p 180–230. Originally published in Q J Econ 14(2):240–269

  • Veblen T ([1898] 1961f) Why is economics not an evolutionary science? In: the place of science in modern civilisation and other essays. Russell & Russell, New York, p 56–81. Originally published in Q J Econ 12(4):379–397

  • Veblen T ( [1907] 1961g) The socialist economics of Karl Marx and his followers II. In: the place of science in modern civilisation and other essays. Russell & Russell, New York, p 431–456. Originally published in Q J econ 21(2):299–322

  • Veblen T ([1923] 1964a) Absentee ownership and business enterprise in recent times: the case of America. Augustus M. Kelley, New York

  • Veblen T ([1914] 1964b) The instinct of workmanship and the state of the industrial arts. Augustus M. Kelley, New York

  • Vromen J (1995) Economic evolution: an enquiry into the foundations of new institutional economics. Routledge, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Vromen J (2001) Ontological commitments of evolutionary economics. In: Mäki U (ed) The economic world view. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, p 189–224

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Wais E (2005) Trained incapacity: Thorstein Veblen and Kenneth Burke. J Kenneth Burke Soc 2(1). http://kbjournal.org/wais. Accessed 21 April 2020

  • Watkins JP (2010) Mainstream efforts to tell a better story – natural selection as a misplaced metaphor: the problem of corporate power. J Econ Issues 44(4):991–1008

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wible JR (1998) The economics of science: methodology and epistemology as if economics really mattered. Routledge, London

  • Yalcintas A (2016) Intellectual path dependence in economics. Routledge, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Zimmermann EW ([1933] 1951) World resources and industries, revised edn. Harper & Brothers, New York

Download references

Acknowledgments

An early version of this article was first presented at a special session on heterodox economics (“The success, obstacles and potential opportunities for heterodox economics”) of the European Association for Evolutionary Political Economy (EAEPE) Annual Conference, Warsaw, Poland, in September 2019. I thank Carlo D’Ippoliti and Paolo Ramazzotti for inviting me to present the paper. A revised version of the paper was presented at the plenary session of the International Confederation of Associations for Pluralism in Economics (ICAPE) Annual Conference, San Diego, USA, in January 2020. I thank Geoff Schneider for giving me an opportunity to present my paper to a large audience, especially young heterodox economists. Thanks are due also to John F. Henry, Zdravka Todorova, Nuno Ornelas Martins, and Wesley Marshall, and two REPE reviewers for valuable comments and suggestions which have improved the paper greatly. Any remaining error is author’s responsibility.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tae-Hee Jo.

Ethics declarations

Code availability

NA

Ethics approval

NA

Consent to participate

NA

Consent for publication

NA

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Jo, TH. Veblen’s evolutionary methodology and its implications for heterodox economics in the calculable future. Rev Evol Polit Econ 2, 277–295 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s43253-020-00024-1

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s43253-020-00024-1

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation