Abstract
Urban communities were established in the twelfth and thirteenth century with the aid of legal concepts that comprised early notions of the rule of law. Cities were envisaged as “communes”, which referred to popular sovereignty. In a first period, urban citizenship was flexible and closely related to place of residence. From around 1220 this model came under increasing pressure. In order to safeguard the interests of the most affluent citizens, large guilds were established. Status determined rights, and there were significant inequalities even among citizens. Ideas of democratic democracy and the civic virtues of citizenship were fostering reforms after 1250. Existing urban governments were expanded to include councils and burgomasters. A framework of checks and balances developed because the commune, now considered as the body of citizens and residents, was seen as a force coexisting with metropolitan institutions. The medieval examples show that, in response to economic and even global conditions, community-building and rule-of-law thinking were solutions offering a “unity-in-diversity”.
1 Introduction
Since the 1980s authors have detected embryonic conceptions of the rule of law in the institutional constellations of medieval cities. They pointed, for example, to elementary ideas on checks and balances and equality before the law.Footnote 1 Also, a connection with constitutional thinking, even constitutionalism, was made.Footnote 2 However, over the past decades cities have been identified less frequently as cradles of early constitutional rules. Instead, the emphasis is mainly on the ecclesiastical origins of several aspects of public law, even democracy and human rights.Footnote 3
Research on these topics is often conducted by social scientists and the connection with historical literature is not always strong. And with regard to the theme that is analyzed here this is highly relevant. Indeed, historical research on the communal movements of the High and Later Middle Ages has witnessed new analysis. And the results thereof allow to recalibrate existing perspectives on early local governmental regimes and the incipient rule of law in cities. Traditionally, urban historians considered concepts that were found in the historical sources and which referred to governance and the public institutions of cities as functional and instrumental. As a result, their embeddedness in intellectual traditions was not often explored. And historians of political ideas have for a long time not studied the links between (legal or institutional) practice and doctrine. It is therefore fortunate that the discourse and concepts that were applied, for example during medieval urban revolts, but also in the earliest urban documentations, have recently been re-examined from a combined cultural and social angle.Footnote 4
This article goes into the “commune” (commune, communia) as related to (an early understanding of) the rule of law. Commune refers to a governance model for small-scale polities (cities, villages) that is closely related to popular sovereignty. The focus is on the Low Countries, in the period between c. 1070 and approximately 1300. This article proposes to consider the emergence of this model in the later eleventh century as a reaction to new circumstances. It will be argued that old cities can be analyzed for their institutional responses to societal processes, and that in particular in the period of c. 1070-c. 1300 urban communities may have been established—at least partly—in answer to profound socio-economic changes. These latter developments are often close to what we today would consider phenomena of “globalization”. Furthermore, it will be explained hereafter that the medieval urban rule of law was to a large extent a symbolic one, which does not easily fit with categorizations of the contemporary concept of the rule of law. In a first stage, between approximately 1070 and 1250, the “communal” government was tied to the city as corporation, which marked a symbolic unity between rulers and ruled. In a second period, from around the middle of the thirteenth century, the urban administrators were regarded as separated from the commune, which became considered as a “state in the state”. Thoughts on checks and balances became connected with the interests of the commune.
2 Medieval Intellectual Traditions Regarding “Good Governance”
Before roughly 1070, ecclesiastical law was most determining in the use of legal concepts with regard to popular sovereignty. The concept of “communitas” had been known in church law, but it acquired new meanings after approximately 1100. These meanings were derived from Southern Europe, where “communes” had been established as “popular” regimes, led by consules or aldermen.Footnote 5 As a result thereof, since the twelfth century communitas was used in the Low Countries as well, and phrases such as “magistratus et communitas”Footnote 6 or “scabini et communitas”,Footnote 7 referring to urban governments, became common. These expressions hinted at the legitimation of the power of the administrators of cities as rooted in the people.
The canon law tradition became combined with Roman law.Footnote 8 Roman law was rediscovered near the end of the eleventh century and became taught at universities throughout Europe. By the end of the 1100 s, the scholarly production on the basis of source texts of Roman law had reached a high level of sophistication. The fact that many graduates of law faculties ended up in the administrations of lords and cities ensured an increasing application in practice of Roman terminology and rules. Cities became described as civitates, for example. For the first time, urban citizenship was detailed in the municipal law of cities.Footnote 9
In the second half of the thirteenth century, Roman law was reinterpreted, now from an Aristotelian perspective. Starting from the 1250 s Aristotle’s main writings, in particular the Politica and Ethica, were translated into Latin, from Arab versions.Footnote 10 In Roman times, the legal concepts of imperium and potestas had served the purposes of expressing powers of authority that were extensive. However, in the later 1200 s and early 1300 s, jurists focused on those passages in the Roman sources that put limits to the power of government, no doubt because they were inspired by the Politica. For example, it became emphasized that even though the prince was legibus solutus (that is, not held to obey the laws), he was nonetheless required to live according to the law (lex digna vox).Footnote 11 Moreover, the lex regia became a topic of interest. The lex regia was read in a fragment in Justinian’s Digest that mentioned that imperium had been granted to the Emperor by the people (populus).Footnote 12 Bartolo da Sassoferrato (d. 1357) interpreted this rule in such a way that the people kept its foundational power and could revoke it.Footnote 13
In the later Middle Ages, scholastic reasoning was ubiquitous at universities and Aristotelian thought became spread through the writings of influential authors, in particular Thomas Aquinas (d. 1278). Aristotle’s views engendered a new mental framework in which governments could be corrupt and which contributed to considering some rules as being so fundamental that even rulers had to stick to them. Furthermore, Aristotle provided ideas on popular government, which came to be proffered alongside views regarding popular sovereignty. It became acknowledged that the people’s consent had to be heard in deliberation processes, which is why representatives from the population were chosen. The Roman maxim “Quod omnes tanget, ab omnibus aprobari debet” (what binds all, must be approved by all) gained new attention.Footnote 14 Therefore, from the end of the thirteenth century onwards, it became common, also in cities of the Low Countries, that the city government not only consisted of consules (scabini or aldermen) but in addition of a communal council, of representatives.Footnote 15
In the Middle Ages people were not equal, and human rights did not exist. It has often been mentioned that the ideas of sovereignty or governance by the populus should therefore be taken with a grain of salt, or at least be considered against a context that is very different from the one existing in Western liberal democracies.Footnote 16 However, when digging a little deeper into the mindset of the Middle Ages, it becomes clear that these differences did not entirely preclude conceptions of a rule of law.
The community constituted a corporation, including both members and its leaders.Footnote 17 From our present-day perspective, it is very difficult to understand how both the governing and governed classes were considered as belonging to the same entity. Yet, it is true that legal ideas on protection against rulers did not, as such, exist. One clear indication thereof is that law, at least at the level of cities, was foremost conceived of as custom. According to the scholarship of Roman law of the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries, custom required “tacitus consensus populi”, the “tacit” consent from the people. This was directly connected to the abovementioned ideas on popular sovereignty.Footnote 18 However, the maiores, the most prominent members of the society, had the right to “express” what the custom was.Footnote 19 In the medieval perspective on things, there was no contradiction in this. It was acknowledged that custom could be “new”, and that when such a new custom became established, by way of its formulation by those in charge, the rulers nonetheless stuck to the tradition of the polity.Footnote 20 “Popular sovereignty”, as among others was mentioned by Bartolo da Sassoferrato, has to be interpreted along these lines. “Consent” was a presumed requirement, not a necessary one. It was assumed to be there; it was not to be evidenced.
3 The Commune: Community-Building in New Circumstances
Between approximately 1000 and 1300, Western Europe witnessed strong demographic growth and a rise in the number of cities.Footnote 21 After around 1070, many of the expanding urban communities were given the status of a legal entity. This was not a smooth development; it went together with strife and revolt against local and regional lords.
The “communal movement” has been a topic of historical study since the nineteenth century. As one can expect, it became a theme of ideological debate as well, especially after the middle of the 1800s. For many politically sensitive issues, such as workers’ rights, suffrage and government intervention in the economy, the “rise of the communes” provided arguments and material for reflection.Footnote 22
Over recent years, the long period between the year 1000 and 1300 has become studied in detail, with an eye for differences between stages. Around the middle of the tenth century the Mediterranean re-opened, which caused new growth for cities such as Venice, Genoa and Pisa. In the 990 s also North-West Europe became re-integrated economically; merchants from Cologne travelled to England, for example.Footnote 23 This came from a recent rise in population, which was due to better climatic conditions and some innovations in agriculture. However, the changes in economic circumstances did not immediately trigger renewal in the status of communities. Local and regional lords continued to administer cities without much upheaval until the second half of the eleventh century. Slowly, changes in the social stratigraphy in new and old centers of habitation resulted in pressures on existing political structures. In the Italian Peninsula, around 1080 the class of nobles collapsed, possibly because of the dwindling importance of agriculture and rural yields. This left a void and this came to be filled by coalitions of rural elites and artisans. They installed urban governments that were self-reliant.Footnote 24 This model of explanation is more refined than earlier class-orientated views which took a class of workers as growing and ultimately challenging the powers of the ruling bourgeoisie. Politics has become much more prominent as a variable in analyses of the communal era.Footnote 25
For the Low Countries, the earliest traces of communes date from the 1070 s. In the County of Flanders, in the present-day North of France several cities, including Arras, Aire-sur-Lys and Cambrai, experienced a transition towards a communia.Footnote 26 The members of the community “swore together” (coniurare)Footnote 27 and the rules to which they pledged to abide were considered an “amicitia” (friendship)Footnote 28 or “pax” (peace).Footnote 29 These notions referred to coalitions, compromises, that stood at the basis of the constellations of cities. Breaching the rules that were agreed on was equivalent to breaching the peace.Footnote 30 What coalitions of the type mentioned had in common was that they united residents of a certain area, and phrased rules communal to them, even though the subjects could have a different status.Footnote 31
The later eleventh century and the entire twelfth century were periods of economic expansion. Especially after around 1150, the maritime areas of the County of Flanders attracted many merchants, coming from areas surrounding the North Sea and from German lands. In this period guilds were set up. Within cities inhabitants with the same profession could join ranks; they created brotherhoods to ensure mutual protection. However, the main trade routes and the export of the most expensive products were controlled by wealthy merchants. As a result, over the course of the mentioned period the differences in revenue between different groups of urban residents increased. In his account of the murder of count Charles the Good in 1127, written around 1130, Galbert of Bruges refers to a difference, existing in Bruges, between “cives majores” (important citizens) and “cives minores” (minor citizens). The latter had some of the same rights as the former, but only the elites—which Galbert also called “sapientiores” (the wiser)—controlled the institutions.Footnote 32
It is remarkable how this stratification, within the communiae, lasted for several decades with minimal consequences. Eventually, it was a deterioration of economic circumstances that brought about change. Starting in the 1220 s, the economy declined. Real wages went down and profits from trade decreased.Footnote 33 This resulted in a closing of ranks; the merchant elites in cities of trade created corporations that were highly exclusive, and which served to maintain their factual monopolies. They established gildas, large municipal corporations. These were city guilds, which identified the entity of the city with its merchant administrators. Examples are the Comansgilde in Dordrecht and the Wollewerk corporation in Mechelen.Footnote 34 The idea was promoted that mercatores (merchants) were burgenses (citizens), and vice versa; citizenship was thus, thenceforth, reserved for the highest strata in the urban community.Footnote 35 The only true citizens were those that were part of the municipal corporation.
However, deteriorating conditions challenged this new approach. In the 1240 s and 1250 s cities of the Low Countries were hit by strikes. Now it was craftsmen and -women who urged for reforms of the urban government, in order to protect their rights. Patricians had cut the wages of textile workers, because of the drops in international trade. The strikes and revolts reacted against these actions. Now, in turn, the idea emerged that the commune was not only the legal entity of the city, but also a “state-within-the-state”. The medieval understanding of the city as a corporation, which encompassed both its rulers and inhabitants, came under pressure. The commune became a power in itself, which served to check the urban government. After approximately 1250, the Aristotelian ideas added fuel to these views. It was envisaged that governance had to be directed towards the common good, and the commune prevented that the rulers of cities turned an aristocracy into an oligarchy. Revolts were described as instances of meentucht (literally, disciplining by the commune).Footnote 36
4 The Burgomaster: Protector of the Commune
Near the end of the thirteenth century, communiae had greatly changed. The territorial jurisdiction of cities now included larger areas. Also, the aldermen were assisted by a concilium, a council of citizens. Since the commune had become considered as a body in itself, which existed alongside the urban government, it was deemed to check on the rulers with regard to their respect for the common good. And further measures were taken in order to preserve the interests of the commune. One catalyst were discussions on the urban finances. Guilds fiercely reacted against corruption and asked for control on the municipal treasury. In 1296 the town council of Dordrecht appointed two “burgermeyster” (masters of the citizens) following complaints on the city’s financial administration. The newly nominated burgomasters seemed to have been responsible for the collection of urban taxes and for the municipal treasury.Footnote 37 The choice for two burgomasters most probably followed the example of Roman magistrates, who were appointed as a duo and who had a reciprocal veto-right. Slowly, the example of Dordrecht was followed in other cities. In Mechelen, for example, burgomasters are mentioned from 1317.Footnote 38 For Utrecht and Nijmegen the first references to burgomasters date from 1315 and 1317 respectively.Footnote 39
In the course of the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries, the tasks of the burgomasters were filled in in reference to a felt difference between the commune and the patrician segments of the population. In Bruges a distinction was made between the burgomaster of the “corps” (the corporation, meaning the commune) and the burgomaster “of the aldermen”.Footnote 40 In Leuven, there was a burgomaster “of the (patrician) lineages” (“van de geslachten”) and a burgomaster “of the guilds” (“van de ambachten”).Footnote 41
The burgomaster of the commune (also: outer-burgomaster) was given a higher status than the burgomaster of the patricians (or inner-burgomaster).Footnote 42 And in combination with this figure of the outer-burgomaster came the idea that this official had to protect the rights of the commune, even against the other urban institutions. In den Briel the burgomaster swore an oath “der steden recht te houdene” (to maintain the law of the city, and also, to keep the city “straight”).Footnote 43 Views on checks and balances were combined with nascent conceptions of the rule of law. The burgomaster of the commune protected the urban tradition and liberties against intrusion from other administrators and also the central level. In Leuven, the burgomaster was the one who prompted the words of the oath sworn by a new prince, and which mentioned respect for the “rights, privileges, charters, customs and usages” of the city.Footnote 44 The outer-burgomaster was the one representing the city in the state assemblies (statenvergaderingen) as well.Footnote 45
Protection of the commune was the outer-burgomaster’s primordial task. In Mechelen, for example, the guards of the city gates stood under the direct and exclusive authority of the outer-burgomaster.Footnote 46 During uprisings, control over the city gates was crucial. Therefore, this rule can be considered as a measure taken to prevent that the city government was easily overtaken by rebels. Also referring to public safety was the outer-burgomaster’s right to summon any citizen for a hearing, even without a judgment or backing from the aldermen.Footnote 47 In Dordrecht, the burgomaster of the commune registered new citizens.Footnote 48
Nascent views on the rule of law were symbolic. They served to depict a city community in legal terms. In doing so, they aimed to portray the city as a unity. As such, they glossed over the many differences in rights that existed between the individuals and groups that lived in the city. In the earliest communitates, from around 1070 to c. 1200, rules were imposed on residents. The community was referring to an institutionalized peace within a certain area, to be respected by both landed inhabitants and those who lived there but were less wealthy. Both manentes and citizens were subjected to the criminal law of the commune and both groups could invoke assistance from the urban government when confronted with crime.Footnote 49 However, starting from the early thirteenth century, citizenship became considered as an exclusive status, and this increased the differences between citizens and non-citizens. City governments came to impose requirements on those seeking to become cives of the urban communities. The mentioned gildas were installed. Conditions of membership could be the payment of a high fee, and later on, marriage or birth. As a result thereof, some citizens were considered as “better” than others; only the highest strata of citizens were eligible for public office. In turn, the concept of manentes, referring to “mere residents”, was used more often. Rights were differentiated. For example, citizens were protected against the interventions of governments of other cities, residents were not. Only citizens could be part of the urban militias. Moreover, citizens had the right to appeal for the assistance of compatriots. In Mechelen it was stipulated that a citizen who shouted “comoignie” had to be helped by any co-citizen in the proximity.Footnote 50
It seems that the concepts of rule of law changed in the thirteenth century, and that these changes were responding to the new social stratifications. The privileges and laws of the town were now protected on behalf of the commune. The commune was now consisting of the manentes and the lower cives; the patricians were regarded as belonging to another group. The new inequalities had resulted in new images of the urban institutional constellation.
The symbolic nature of the rule of law that applied in medieval cities renders it difficult for comparison with present-day categories that are present within the rule of law. A city community regarded itself as unified, under a communal institutional framework and because of a shared tradition and law. However, this did not make the rule of law in those cities “thick”.Footnote 51 The thirteenth-century concept of the “commune” relied on values and traditions that had to be respected by the city’s administrators. However, there was no understanding of citizens’ rights against the government. The shared institutional beliefs marked the glue between a factually oligarchic urban government and a sense of community that was underpinning the urban institutions. Even after the instalment of a concilium, of a council of citizens, there was no regime of representation or democracy. Also, rights of individuals were greatly divergent. Citizens had more rights than non-citizens, but there were additionally many differences according to sex, profession and social group. Therefore, even a “thin” conception of the rule of law cannot easily be projected onto the medieval situation. Urban governments were not “bound” by the existing rules and traditions. The symbolic unity between rulers and ruled meant that rules could change, for it was held that the maiores, the “better part” of the urban population, knew what the law was. Even if new, rules could be considered as customs.
5 Towards Contextual Analysis of the Communal Movement
Over the past years the mentioned processes of community-building have more and more been described as political. Several groups were involved, but the dynamics that resulted in institutional change were not exclusively social. Coalitions did not necessarily overlap with classes or professions.Footnote 52 However, the changes of urban governmental set-ups in the twelfth and thirteenth centuries can also be analyzed from a more contextual perspective, referring to, for example, international trends and economic conditions. The developments in medieval cities nonetheless provide data of the process of imposing a (symbolic) rule of law onto heterogeneous communities.
In this regard, looking at the abovementioned phenomena from the angle of (the effects of) globalizationFootnote 53 and, in close relation thereto, “glocality”Footnote 54 can potentially be enriching.
Starting from around 1050, developments in the West became increasingly “global”. Certain events had an effect that transgressed the boundaries of polities.Footnote 55 When such effects were disruptive, it was difficult for rulers to address them in an adequate fashion. For example, the abovementioned trend of installing large merchant guilds, which can be dated to the second quarter of the thirteenth century, was most probably an answer to contractions in the international economy. When revenues dropped, competition intensified. Setting up an urban guild then served to secure cooperation and limit rivalry among the urban merchants. This institutional response was “glocal”; it seems that several cities took similar measures in answer to the new challenges.
Economic crisis had other consequences as well. Margins were adjusted, down the chain of producers and suppliers. This then resulted in the lowering of wages of textile workers, which explains for the context in which the changes of after approximately 1250 took place. Also, the first abovementioned stage of community building, between c. 1070 and c. 1250, was potentially reflecting a highly mobile workforce, which could easily move to other cities. Indeed, there are traces, since the beginning of the eleventh century, of groups of textile workers, travelling large distances, and settling in locations of their choice.Footnote 56 In several cities these professions, in particular those of dyers and fullers, were considered as inferior,Footnote 57 and their members were not eligible for citizenship, when citizenship became an exclusive status.Footnote 58 Groups of travelling craftsmen could supply the necessary workers for a booming textile industry. Was the commune established to tie them to the city? The groups mentioned could function as pressuring groups demanding rights. The phenomenon of the rise of the commune, as an entity in itself, may have had to do with requests from these groups. It was mentioned that institutional responses could be “glocal”, but maybe, as well, institutional models were spread by migrants.
Another factor that has seldom been analyzed, refers to rivalries between cities. Maybe the depiction of the city as a communitas (also) served the purpose of tightening the bonds within the community in order to address external enemies. The link between citizenship and membership of the communal army may be an indication thereof. The communitas ideal may have served to bolster patriotic feelings or to facilitate the recruitment of fighters.Footnote 59 The building of city walls can be indicative of such ideas on external protection and patriotism. Already in the tenth century, most cities of the Low Countries had some sort of inner-city wall, as part of a fortress, or built as place of shelter, but it was only from the later eleventh century onwards that walls were erected for the purpose of enclosing the most important areas of habitation of the urban community.Footnote 60
In urban-historical literature, the imaginative aspect of institutional ordering has not often been taken into account. The abovementioned examples of concepts referring to urban communities could have gone hand in hand with “inequalities” of all sorts and may have purported to symbolically reduce such differences. For example, even though (Aristotelian) views of popular government were known since the middle of the thirteenth century, urban governments became more oligarchic and hereditary in the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries.Footnote 61
Further research is needed, before a beginning of an answer to the questions listed can be given. And thereafter, other, more fundamental, problems may see solutions. For example, were the abovementioned institutional changes—also considering the increased oligarchical trends over the long run—“cynical”? Were they merely superficial changes, aimed at pleasing the crowds, but with a hidden agenda of rulers to stay in power? Or were they conceived of as genuine innovations? The latter is definitely possible, considering the mentalities of people in the Middle Ages. Adding a council of advisors to the council of aldermen, for example, could have been rooted in a thorough rethinking of governance issues. The question of the success of the new models should not be confused with the question on the genuineness of the intent of those who initiated them.
6 Conclusion
In this article, the argument was made that in the twelfth and thirteenth centuries concepts defining the status of urban communities were changing, and that these changes were connected to cultural, social and—potentially—international and economic variables. In a first period, between c. 1070-c. 1250, cities were devised as “communes”, referring to popular sovereignty. Citizenship was inclusive and largely linked to residence. In practice however international merchants managed to monopolize the institutions of the municipal polity. It was after approximately 1220 that this model increasingly came under pressure. Large overarching guilds were created, with the purpose of protecting the interests of the maiores. After c. 1250, ideas of popular government and the political qualities of citizenship were nurturing reforms. Councils and burgomasters were added to existing urban governments.
In terms of the rule of law, the abovementioned developments are important. Besides doctrine and political thought, also the institutional practice of cities informs on governance models, and how their institutional change responded to different variables. The rule of law in twelfth- and thirteenth-century cities was a symbolic one. It did not have the effect of bringing equality; rights were status-bound and even among citizens large differences existed. The rule of law had minimal substance. At first, it referred to rights linked to residence within an area that was under a negotiated “peace”. Later, when the commune was considered as a force existing alongside the urban institutions, a conception of checks and balances emerged. The commune demanded protection of the urban liberties and customs, and the outer-burgomaster served as the keeper of these rights.
A potentially fruitful path forward lies in the contextual approach towards changing conceptualizations of urban political and institutional regimes. One tool thereto may be a vantage point of globalization and glocal responses thereto. Economic and international developments most probably had an impact on the abovementioned changes. Also, the medieval examples demonstrate that community-building and rule-of-law thinking were answers providing a “unity-in-diversity”. Also for that reason, studying the history of medieval cities and their governments can help us understand our present day.
Notes
For an overview, see Scott (2012).
An early example is Diplomata Belgica (https://www.diplomata-belgica.be/colophon_fr.html, hereafter DiBe) 4662 (11 November 1166).
For example, DiBe 35,266 (26 May 1217); Warnkönig (1836), 46 (June 1248).
Anthony Black considers Roman law, and in particular its notion universitas, as pre-eminent in the early stages of the commune-movement. See Black (1996), pp. 99–112, at 102. This conclusion is not valid for the Low Countries.
An early example is Maastricht. In 1109 there is a reference to a “ius civile et forense” in the city. A first mention of the city as civitas dates from 1204, but it is highly likely that the term was used earlier as well. See Cox (2021), lemma “Maastricht”.
The influence of Aristotle in communal theories and concepts of the later Middle Ages is a theme of debate. Walter Ullmann considered Aristotle as very influential, whereas Anthony Black thinks this influence as minimal. See Black (1996)
C. 1,14,4. This law states that the auctoritas of law is higher than the auctoritas of the Emperor (imperium).
D. 1,4,1,1.
Ryan (2000).
This phrase was important as it provided a basis for the conciliar movement in the Church. See on this Congar (1958).
Aristotle’s influence can be seen in the establishment of concilia in cities, existing besides the council of aldermen (scabini), and in the increased use of phrases such as “scabini, concilium et burgenses”. Before approximately 1280, and starting from the 1150s, it was usual that cities had iurati next to the scabini. These iurati were selected and sworn advisors, often from craft guilds. For an early example of iurati, see DiBe 12,470 (1156). In contrast to this earlier period, after approximately 1280 the concepts used to refer to the government of cities were more inclusive. Concilium referred then to a group of representatives, not merely to sworn assessors. See for example, Willems (1839), (20 December 1328, Brussels, mentioning “scabini, concilium, aut universitas oppidi nostri Bruxellensis”).
However, there is ample literature that still stresses the “fraternal” and even egalitarian nature of city communities, and which even considers the constitution of cities as a coniuratio, an Eidgenossenschaft. See, with regard to the city as a Schwörgemeinschaft, for example Isenmann (2014); Oexle (2001), pp. 290–293; Planitz (1954), pp. 102–125. Recent research that closely examined the different stages in the emergence of cities yields many arguments against these views. For example: Saint-Denis (2008) and Wickham (2015).
Nootens (2013).
Garré (2005), pp. 128–140.
van Caenegem (1996), at 103, footnote 26 (referring to Petrus de Ravannis’ (d. c. 1528) statement that governments can create customs).
For this argument, see De ruysscher (2022).
For detailed estimates, see Bairoch (1988).
For liberal historians such as François Guizot the communal movement was a bourgeois revolution, directed against feudal nobles, whereas socialist historians tended to consider them as anti-bourgeois.
Sawyer (2013).
Wickham (2015), 87.
For example, the commune of 1102 in Cambrai was supported by wealthy citizens, who opposed the clergy. See Ruffini-Ronzani (2018).
Verhulst (1999).
The term is rather rare for cities in the Low Countries. One exceptional example is a charter for Valenciennes, dating from 1174, which seems to refer to coniurati in the meaning of citizens. See Tock (2000).
Derville (2002).
For example DiBe 2965 (June 1147, the count grants the homines of St Bertin’s abbey (St Omer) in Poperinghe the same rights as the citizens of Furnes (“omnia gaudere qua Furnenses fruuntur quam coniuraverunt in qua et confirmati sunt”, to enjoy everything which the Furnenses have sworn and in which they have been confirmed). Then it is said: “Quam pacem qui infregerit constituta lege multetur” (the one who breaches this peace will be punished according to the fixed law).
This economic conjuncture in the thirteenth century is a topic of contention. While it is generally accepted that in this period the aggregate growth was rising, over the course of the 1200 s revenues were unevenly spread. Large farmers and merchants profited, whereas craftsmen and nobles struggled. See, for example, Nicholas (1992).
See on these large guilds, Alberts and Jansen (1964).
For example in Bruges in 1280, where the group of protesters called itself “meentucht” and sought to incorporate areas at the outskirts of the first commune. See Dumolyn (2012).
van Dalen (1903), at 276.
Municipal Archives Mechelen, A. Charters, series VII, nr 1 (1317, “magistri communitas”).
Burgmans and Peters (1909), 163 and 197.
van Houtte (1982), 308.
van Uytven (1995), pp. 375–376. In 1234 magistri communitatis and rectores communionis were mentioned in Leuven, but these are—in my opinion—to be considered as chairs of the bench of aldermen and not yet as the presidential figures of burgomasters of the later thirteenth and fourteenth centuries.
Leuven is an exception here. The burgomaster of the patricians was the one responsible for diplomatic relations. See Uytven (1995), 375.
Matthijssen (1880), 59. By contrast, the aldermen swore to protect the city and to act in the interest of the city and its citizens. There was no reference to the “law of the city” in their oath. See Ibid., 64.
Vrancken (2018), 97.
Ham (2000), 204.
Installé (1995), 849.
For example, in Dordrecht the outer-burgomaster had to give authorization for summoning a citizen to the court. See Oudenhoven (1654), 84.
Wall (1790), pp. 574–575 (30 May and 4 June 1445).
On the rights of citizens, see Godding (1987), pp. 52–59.
Foncke and Buskens (1947), 135.
Tamanaha (2014), pp. 91–113; Møller and Kaaning (2012) pp. 136–153.
The impact of globalization processes on institutional change is not a classic theme of analysis in legal studies but is more prominent in political sciences. See, for example, Campbell (2004). Also, the theme has been analyzed mostly with regard to globalizing markets. See, for example, Jupille (2013).
For example, with regard to “the commons”, Haller et al. (2020).
Since globalization processes are typically located in modern, sometimes early modern times, the literature on such processes for medieval times, considering them from that angle, is rare. If mentioned for the Middle Ages globalization is typically connected to economic integration and trade routes.
Deploige and Stabel (2016), pp. 240–281.
Joosen, “Documents”, op. cit., 403 (1276, “… si vero fuerit de officio fullonum aut textorum aut ceteri fallacis officiis …” (… if however they belong to the profession of fuller or dyer or another vile profession …).
Ibid. This passage suggests that fullers and dyers could not be member of the gilda of the city of Mechelen, i.e. the Wollewerk.
On communal armies in the twelfth century, see Verbruggen (1997), pp. 149–152.
Verhulst (1999), pp. 119–147.
References
Alberts WJ, Jansen HPH (1964) Welvaart in wording: sociaal-economische geschiedenis van Nederland van de vroegste tijden tot het einde der middeleeuwen. Nijhoff, The Hague
Bairoch P (1988) Cities and economic development. From the dawn of history to the present. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago
Berman H (1983) Law and revolution: the formation of the Western legal tradition. Harvard University Press
Bervoets L (2020) Tam maiores quam minores: craftsmen, merchants, and burghers in thirteenth-century Bruges. The Medieval Low Countries 7:131–156
Bervoets L (2022) Quicumque in villa per annum unum et diem unum manserit, liber erit. De genese van het poorterschap in de dertiende-eeuwse steden van de Vlaamse ruimte. Unpublished PhD-thesis Ghent University
Black A (1996) The commune in political theory in the late middle ages. In: Blickle P (ed) Theorien kommunaler Ordnung. Oldenbourg, Munich, pp 99–112
Blockmans W (2010) Constructing a sense of community in rapidly growing European cities in the eleventh to thirteenth centuries. Hist Res 83:575–587
Blockmans W (2011) Inclusiveness and exclusion. trust networks at the origins of European cities. In: Hanagan M, Tilly Ch (eds) Contention and trust in cities and state. Springer, New York, pp 199–212
Burgmans H, Peters CH (1909) Oud-Nederlandsche steden in haar ontstaan, groei en ontwikkeling. Sijthoff, Leiden
Buylaert F (2020) From periphery to centre and back again: elite transformations in Mechelen (fourteenth to sixteenth centuries). Urban Hist 47:610–631
Buylaert F, Baguet J, Everaert J (2020) Returning urban political elites to the research agenda: the case of the southern Low Countries (c. 1350–c. 1550). Urban Hist 47:568–588
Campbell JL (2004) Globalization and institutional change. Princeton University Press
Carstens RW (1992) The medieval antecedents of constitutionalism. Lang, Frankfurt
Congar Y-M (1958) Quod omnes tangit ab omnibus tractari et approbari debet. Revue Historique de Droit Français et Étranger 81:210–259
Cox JCM (2021) Repertorium van de stadsrechten in Nederland. Stichting Oud-Vaderlandsch Recht, Oisterwijk
De Ruysscher D (2022) Customs and municipal law: the symbolic authority of the past (low countries, 16th-17th century). Dutch Crossing J Low Ctries Stud 46(2):95–114
Deploige J, Stabel P (2016) Textile entrepreneurs and textile workers in the medieval city. In: Lambert V, Stabel P (eds) Golden times wealth and status in the Middle Ages. Lannoo, Tielt, pp 240–281
Derville A (2002) Villes de Flandre et d’Artois (900–1500). Septentrion, Lille
Downing BM (1989) Medieval origins of constitutional government in the west. Theory Soc 19(2):213–247
Dumolyn J (2012) Economic development, social space and political power in Bruges, c. 1127–1302. In: Shaw RLJ (ed) Contact and exchange in later medieval Europe: essays in honour of Malcolm Vale. Boydell, Woodbridge, pp 33–58
Foncke R, Buskens E (1947) Mechelen die Heerlijke. Godenne, Mechelen
Garré R (2005) Consuetudo. Das Gewohnheitsrecht in der Rechtsquellen- und Methodenlehre des späten ius commune in Italien (16.-18. Jahrhundert). Klostermann, Frankfurt am Main
Godding PH (1987) Le droit privé dans les Pays-Bas méridionaux. Royal Academy, Brussels
Godding PH, Pycke J (1979) La paix de Valenciennes de 1114. Commentaire et édition critique. Bulletin de la Commission royale pour la Publication des Anciennes Lois et Ordonnances de Belgique 29:1–142
Groten M (2004) In tanto tumultu rerum. Die Bürger von Brügge in Galberts Bericht über die Ermordung Graf Karls von Flandern 1127. In: Happ S, Nonn U (eds) Vielfalt der Geschichte: Lernen, Lehren und Erforschen vergangener Zeiten. Festschrift für Ingrid Heidrich zum 65. Geburtstag. Wissenschaftliche Verlag, Berlin, pp 126-140
Grzymala-Busse AM (2023) Sacred foundations. The religious and medieval roots of the European state. Princeton University Press
Haller T et al (2020) The commons in a glocal world: global connections and local responses. Routledge, London
Installé H (1995) Bestuursinstellingen van de heerlijkheid Mechelen (11de eeuw-1795). In: Van Uytven R et al (eds) De Gewestelijke en Lokale Overheidsinstellingen in Brabant en Mechelen tot 1795, vol 2. Archives of the Realm, Brussels, pp 835–864
Isenmann E (2014) Die deutsche Stadt im Mittelalter 1150–1550: Stadtgestalt, Recht, Verfassung, Stadtregiment, Kirche, Gesellschaft, Wirtschaft. Böhlau, Cologne
Jones PH (1997) The Italian city-state: from commune to signoria. Oxford University Press
Joosen H (1935) Recueil de documents relatifs à l’industrie drapière à Malines (des origines à 1384). Bulletin De La Commission Royale D’histoire 99:365–572
Jupille J et al (2013) Institutional choice and global commerce. Cambridge University Press
Larson AA, Dumolyn J, ‘Liberty and the Rule of Law’ (2021) The Common Good. In: Napolitano D, Penningtond K (eds) A cultural history of democracy in the medieval age. Bloomsbury, London, pp 37–56
Matthijssen J (1880) Het rechtsboek van den Briel: beschreven in vijf tractaten. Nijhoff, The Hague
Møller J (2017) Medieval origins of the rule of law: the Gregorian Reforms as critical juncture? Hague J Rule Law 9:265–282
Møller J, Doucette JS (2022) The catholic church and European state formation, AD 1000–1500. Oxford University Press
Møller J, Kaaning SE (2012) Systematizing thin and thick conceptions of the rule of law. Justice Syst J 33(2):136–153
Nicholas D (1992) Medieval Flanders. Routledge, London
Nootens G (2013) Popular sovereignty in the west: polities, contention, and ideas. Routledge, London
Oakley F (2017) Medieval constitutionalism. In: Lang AF, Wiener A (eds) Handbook on global constitutionalism. Routledge, London, pp 35–46
Oexle OG (1996) Gilde und Kommune. Über die Entstehung von 'Einung’ und 'Gemeinde’ als Grundformen des Zusammenlebens in Europa. In: Blickle P (ed) Theorien kommunaler Ordnung. Munich, Oldenbourg, pp 75–98
Oexle OG (2001) Peace through conspiracy. In: Jussen B (ed) Ordering medieval society perspectives on intellectual and practical modes of shaping social relations. University of Pennsylvania Press, Philadelphia, pp 285–304
Planitz (1954) Die deutsche Stadt im Mittelalter. Böhlau, Graz
Rolland P (1925) Une étape de la vie communale de Tournai. La fédération de seigneuries Revue Historique du Droit Français et Étranger 4th series 4:411–435
Ruffini-Ronzani N (2018) Évêques et élites urbaines aux premiers temps de la commune de Cambrai (fin XIe-début XIIe siècle). Cahiers De Civilisation Médiévale 61:357–378
Ryan M (2000) Bartolus of Sassoferrato and free cities. Trans R Hist Soc 10:65–89
Saint-Denis A (2008) Instigateurs et acteurs des premières communes françaises (fin XIe-premier tiers du XIIe siècle). In: Depreux Ph (ed) Revolte und Sozialstatus von der Spätantike bis zur Frühen Neuzeit. Oldenbourg, Munich, pp 111–130
Sawyer PH (2013) The wealth of Anglo-Saxon England. Oxford University Press, Oxford
Scott T (2012) The rise of the communes, 1000–1150. In: Scott T (ed) The city-state in Europe, 1000–1600: hinterland, territory, region. Oxford University Press, pp 17–32
Tamanaha BZ (2014) On the rule of law history politics theory. Cambridge University Press, pp 91–113
Tock B-M (2000) La diplomatie urbaine au XIIe siècle dans le Nord de la France. In: Prevenier W, De Hemptine TH (eds) La diplomatique urbaine en Europe au Moyen Âge. Peeters, Leuven, pp 501–522
van Caenegem RC (1996) Aantekeningen bij het middeleeuwse gewoonterecht. Legal Hist Rev (Tijdschrift voor Rechtsgeschiedenis) 64(1):97–110
van Dalen JL (1903) De oude regeeringsvorm van Dordrecht, 3 4th series. Bijdragen voor Vaderlandsche Geschiedenis en Oudheidkunde, pp 225–289
van Ham WA (2000) Macht en gezag in het Markiezaat. Een politiek-institutionele studie over stad en land van Bergen op Zoom (1477–1583). Verloren, Hilversum
Van Houtte H (1982) De geschiedenis van Brugge. Lannoo, Gent
Van Oudenhoven J (1654) Out-Hollant, nu Zuyt-Hoillandt …. Andriessens, Dordrecht
Van Uytven R (1995) Bestuursinstellingen van de stad Leuven. In: Van Uytven R et al (eds) De gewestelijke en lokale overheidsinstellingen in Brabant en Mechelen tot 1795, vol 2. Archives of the Realm, Brussels, pp 369–392
Van de Wall PH (1790) Handvesten, privilegien, … der stad Dordrecht, vol. 1. Braem, Dordrecht
Verbruggen JF (1997) The art of warfare in western Europe during the middle ages. Boydell, Woodbridge, pp 149–152
Verhulst A (1999) The rise of cities in North-West Europe. Cambridge University Press
Vrancken V (2018) De Blijde Inkomsten van de Brabantse hertogen. Macht, opstand en privileges in de vijftiende eeuw. ASP, Brussels
Warnkönig LA (1836) Flandrische Staats- und Rechtsgeschichte bis zum Jahr 1305, vol 2. Fues, Tübingen
Wickham CH (2015) Sleepwalking into a new world: the emergence of Italian city communes in the twelfth century. Princeton University Press
Willems J-F (1839) De Brabantsche Yeesten, vol 1. Hayez, Brussels
Acknowledgements
This paper was written as part of the ERC-funded project CaPANES (ERC Consolidator Grant nr 101044356) and the Signature Plan Global Law and Governance (Tilburg Law School). I would like to thank Marco In’t Veld and Maurits den Hollander for their comments on an earlier version of this article.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Additional information
Publisher's Note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Rights and permissions
Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.
About this article
Cite this article
De ruysscher, D. The Rule of Law in Cities of the Medieval Low Countries: Community-Building in Context. Hague J Rule Law 15, 227–241 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40803-023-00197-x
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40803-023-00197-x