Skip to main content
Log in

Genes, Culture, and Preferences

  • Thematic Issue Article: Strategic Interaction
  • Published:
Biological Theory Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper explores the notion that economic preferences were shaped by the joint action of genetic and cultural evolution. We review the evidence that preferences are partly innate, the output of genetic forces, and partly plastic, the output of cultural forces. A model of how genes and culture might jointly shape preferences is sketched.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Croson and Gneezy (2009) for evidence on the greater risk aversion of women.

  2. The bulk of the behavioral genetics literature attempts to decompose IQ variance into genetic and environmental influences. See, for instance, the reviews by Goldberger (1979), Devlin et al. (1997), and Plomin and Spinath (2004).

  3. See Behrman and Taubman (1989) and also Sacerdote (2011).

  4. Of course, the environment’s influence is not limited to information—i.e., the quality of food consumed, exposure to toxins, and so on, all may potentially affect phenotypes.

  5. This latter requirement can be problematic. It is reasonable if environment is measured by parents’ income. It will not hold if parents invest differentially in their children according to perceived innate abilities, for example. The assumption that siblings’ environments are perfectly shared is also questionable.

  6. See Table II on page 1013 of the paper for these results.

  7. For a perspective from molecular biology see Kuhnen and Chiao (2009). For a discussion within economics see Beauchamp et al. (2011).

  8. Robson (2001) considers the still more basic question: What is the evolutionary reason for utility functions in the first place? Robson (2001) is an early survey and prospectus of this theoretical literature and related empirical work outside economics. Robson and Samuelson (2011) is a more recent survey focusing on the evolutionary basis of preferences.

  9. See Curry (2001) for the interpretation of these preferences.

  10. See also Robson and Samuelson (2007).

  11. It is straightforward to allow the signal to be multiple draws from this combined distribution.

  12. This is unrealistic since it allows marginal fitness to be negative when x > s, as must be the case for any fixed x if s is small enough. Since s is normally distributed, this possibility always exists. However, if the mean of s is large and positive, this possibility will be very unlikely, and is ignored for the present expository purpose.

  13. Although the additive constant term is also affected by the signal, this irrelevant to choice, of course.

  14. The expected utility for these utility functions can be expressed in terms of the mean and the variance of the distribution. Consider a gamble over x given by the pdf p(x). Suppose the mean of this gamble is \(\bar{p}\) and the variance is v(p). It follows readily that

    $$ \int p(x)U(x)dx=-({\mu}_0-\bar{p})^2 -v(p) -{\sigma}^2-{\sigma}_0^2 $$

    and

    $$ \int p(x)V(x)dx=-({{\mu}_0^{\prime}}-\bar{p})^2 -v(p) -{\sigma}^2-{{\sigma}_0^{2^{\prime}}}. $$

References

  • Barnea A, Cronqvist H, Siegal S (2010) Nature or nurture: What determines investor behavior. J Financ Econ 98(3):583–604

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beauchamp JP, Cesarini D, Johannesson M, van der Loos MJHM, Koellinger PD, Groenen PJF, Fowler JH, Rosenquist JN, Thurik AR, Christakis NA (2011) Molecular genetics and economics. J Econo Perspect 25(4):57–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behrman JR, Taubman P (1989) Is schooling ‘mostly in the genes’? Nature-nurture decomposition using data on relatives. J Polit Econ 97(6):1425–1446

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benjamin DJ, Cesarini D, van der Loos MJ, Dawes CT, Koellinger PD, Magnusson PK, Chabris CF, Conley D, Laibson D, Johannssson M, Visscher PM (2012) The genetic architecture of economic and political preferences. Proc Nat Acad Sci U S A 109(21):8026–8031

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bisin A, Verdier T (2000) Beyond the melting pot: cultural transmission, marriage, and the evolution of ethnic and religious traits. Q J Econ 115(3):955–988

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Björklund A, Lindahl M, Plug E (2006) The origins of intergenerational associations: lessons from swedish adoption data. Q J Econ 121(3):999–1028

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd R, Richerson PJ (1985) Culture and the evolutionary process. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyd R, Richerson PJ, Henrich J (2011) The cultural niche: why social learning is essential for human adaptation. Proc Nat Acad Sci 108:10918–10925

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter JP, Garcia JR, Lum JK (2011) Dopamine receptor genes predict risk preferences, time preferences, and related economic choices. J Risk Uncertain 42(3):233–261

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cavalli-Sforza LL, Feldman MW (1981) Cultural transmission and evolution: a quantitative approach. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Cesarini D, Dawes CT, Johannesson M, Lichtenstein P, Wallace B (2009) Genetic variation in preferences for giving and risk taking. Q J Econ 124(2):809–842

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cesarini D, Johannesson M, Lichtenstein P, Örjan Sandewall, Wallace B (2010) Genetic variation in financial decision-making. J Financ 65(5):1725–1754

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cronqvist H, Siegal S (2011) The origins of savings behavior. Working Paper URL http://ssrn.com/abstract=1649790

  • Croson R, Gneezy U (2009) Gender differences in preferences. J Econ Lit 47(2):448–474

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Curry PA (2001) Decsion making under uncertainty and the evolution of interdependent preferences. J Econ Theory 98(2):357–369

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeGroot MH (1970) Optimal Statistical Decisions. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Devlin B, Daniels M, Roeder K (1997) The heritability of IQ. Nature 388:468–471

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durham WH (1992) Coevolution: genes, culture, and human diversity. Stanford University Press, Stanford

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher RA (1918) The correlation between relatives on the supposition of mendelian inheritance. Transact R Soc Edinburgh 52(2):399–433

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldberger AS (1979) Heritability. Economica 46(4):327–347

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuhnen CM, Chiao JY (2009) Genetic determinants of financial risk taking. PLoS One 4(2):e4362

    Google Scholar 

  • Plomin R, Spinath FM (2004) Intelligence: genetics, genes, and genomics. J Pers Soc Psychol 86(1):112–129

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plug E, Vijverberg W (2003) Schooling, family background, and adoption: is it nature or is it nurture. J Political Econ 111(3):611–641

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robson AJ (1996) A biological basis for expected and non-expected utility. J Econ Theory 68:397–424

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robson AJ (2001) The biological basis of economic behavior. J Econ Lit 29:11–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robson AJ (2001) Why would Nature give individuals utility functions. J Political Econ 109(4):900–914

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robson AJ, Samuelson L (2007) The evolution of intertemporal preferences. Am Econ Rev 97:496–500

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robson AJ, Samuelson L (2009) The evolution of time preference with aggregate uncertainty. Am Econ Rev 99:1925–1953

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robson AJ, Samuelson L (2011) The evolutionary foundations of preferences. In: Bisin A, Jackson MO (eds) Handbook of social economics, vol 1. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 221–310

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Robson AJ, Szentes B (2008) Evolution of time preference by natural selection: comment. Am Econ Rev 98:1178–1188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robson AJ, Szentes B (2012) The evolutionary basis of time preference: intergenerational transfers and sex. Am Econ J Microecon 4(4):172–201

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogers AR (1994) Evolution of time preference by natural selection. Am Econ Rev 84:460–481

    Google Scholar 

  • Sacerdote B (2002) The nature and nurture of economic outcomes. Am Econ Rev 92(2):344–348

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sacerdote B (2007) How large are the effects from changes in family environment? A study of Korean American adoptees. Quarterly J Econ 122(1):119–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sacerdote B (2011) Nature and nurture effects on children’s outcomes: what have we learned from studies of twins and adoptees? In: Benhabib J, Bisin A, Jackson MO (eds) Handbook of social economics, vol 1. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1–30

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Robalino and Robson acknowledge financial support from the Human Evolutionary Studies Program at Simon Fraser University; Robson also acknowledges that of a Canada Research Chair.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Arthur J. Robson.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Robalino, N., Robson, A.J. Genes, Culture, and Preferences. Biol Theory 8, 151–157 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s13752-013-0108-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s13752-013-0108-0

Keywords

Navigation