1 Introduction

The fifth assessment report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC 2014) concluded that human interference with the climate system is occurring, and climate change poses risks for human and natural systems alike.Footnote 1 The 2014 report also serves as one of the first efforts by IPCC to present a case for the impact of climate change on poverty. Several other studies have addressed the nexus between climate change, food production, and poverty in developing countries. For example, a review by Hertel and Rosch (2010) of research studies using crop growth simulation models and statistical estimations of climate change effects indicates that rising temperatures are expected to significantly reduce cereal yields in low income countries with an attendant increase in household poverty. Results of climate simulations up to 2080 in Onyutha (2019) point to a similar conclusion about the linkage between food insecurity and poverty; thermal environments under future climatic conditions are expected to result in losses in arable land and agricultural output in many parts of Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA). Other related studies focus on the relationship between food prices and poverty through the lens of climate change (e.g., Mkhawani et al. 2016; Seaman et al. 2014; Vermeulen et al. 2012; Brinkman et al. 2010; Baiphethi and Jacobs 2009). Seaman et al. (2014) use a simulation method, the Household Economy Approach, to assess the vulnerability of households to large shocks in cereal prices and production prompted by climate change on household poverty in Malawi and Namibia. In their review of scientific studies about the effects of climate change on food systems, Vermeulen et al. (2012) indicate that climate change will slow down poverty reduction gains in developing countries in part by undermining risk mitigation strategies, investments in agriculture, and through increased food prices which disproportionately affect poor households. In a similar realm, Brinkman et al. (2010) find, not surprisingly, that higher food prices are associated with a reduction in the diversity and frequency of food consumption in Haiti, Nepal, and Niger using a regression model and data collected by the World Food Programme between 2006 and 2008. Baiphethi and Jacobs (2009) discuss changing trends in food supply channels in South Africa--how the infiltration of supermarkets into rural areas has served to lower food prices due to scale economies--and how government subsidies in Southern Africa can improve yields, lower food prices and enhance food security among vulnerable households. A special issue in the Journal Environment and Development Economics (Hallegatte et al. 2018) was devoted to the topic of poverty and climate change. It featured in-depth analyses of the heterogeneous impacts of climate change by income and exposure to environmental shocks at the household level.

Climate change can affect poverty in several ways, including displacement and migration because of climate hazards, impact on food prices, and increased poverty traps through extreme weather events such as pronounced droughts. These channels are interconnected in that displacement and migration from rural areas can lead to reduced agricultural production in said areas, which can spur an increase in food prices. Likewise, an increased likelihood of flooding or drought and lengthening of growing seasons can prompt an increase in real prices as well (Thornton et al. 2010).Footnote 2 In many SSA countries, extreme patterns of climate have the potential to significantly diminish agricultural output (Onyutha 2019; Onyutha 2018), hence worsening the imbalance between supply and demand of food products in the face of fast population growth and low productivity (Ivanic and Martin 2008; Nelson et al. 2010). The regularity of agricultural shocks resulting from extreme weather events in the past decade has led to a rise in food prices which, in turn, has negatively affected most consumers and some producers in the food chain, including farmers, traders of agricultural products, and food manufacturers (Terazono 2014). Wheeler and von Braun (2013) contend that climate change can reverse the gains realized towards the world’s goal of eliminating hunger as it reduces the production of crops resulting in increased poverty.

Like many SSA countries, agriculture is a key source of income in Swaziland, with about 75% of the population engaged in subsistence agriculture on drought-prone land (Burki et al. 2012). More than 50% of the arable land in the country is used to grow cereal with a high of 70% in 2014.Footnote 3 According to Mavuso et al. (2015), climate change has resulted in unreliable rainfall patterns, shifted crop growing seasons, and produced very high summer temperatures and dried wetlands. Mavuso et al. (2015) also argued that an increase in food prices would likely cause lower-income net consumers to trade-off necessary nutritious food for lower cost and less nutritious food. Potentially resulting in malnutrition in children and associated irreversible long-term effects. The real costs of using substitute food commodities with lower nutrients will only show at a later stage as the individuals’ immune system weakens, and the mortality rate increases (Wodon and Zaman 2010). According to the World Bank, 39.7% of the population lived under the international $1.90 poverty line in 2016 and 2017.Footnote 4 Together, these statistics illustrate the vulnerability of Swazi households to the effects of climate change. According to the World Food Programme Swaziland Country Brief (August 2017), the food security situation in Swaziland was severely impacted by the 2016/2017 El Nino drought. Production of maize was 64% less than the previous five-year average production in the country that year.Footnote 5 Food prices also remained significantly higher than before the drought.Footnote 6 They estimated that because of the 2016/17 drought, about 159,000 people would need food assistance due to a combination of reduced income opportunities and poor agricultural performance, leading to high reliance on purchases and relatively high food prices.

More closely related to our study are the papers by Dessus et al. (2008), Hertel et al. (2010), and Seaman et al. (2014). Using a similar microeconomic framework as ours, Dessus et al. (2008) provide “back of the envelope” estimates of the effects of the increase in world food prices that started in 2005 on urban poverty in 72 developing countries. The authors conclude that a growth rate of gross domestic product (GDP) between 0.2 and 3% is required to offset the effect of increased food prices on urban poverty. Unlike our study, however, they do not focus on the impact of climate change, nor do they estimate country-specific substitution elasticities. Instead, they rely on estimates in Seale et al. (2003) to obtain food budget shares and substitution elasticities at the country-level. Hertel et al. (2010) and Seaman et al. (2014), on the other hand, explore the effects of climate change on poverty through increased agricultural prices. Hertel et al. (2010) estimates the impacts of agricultural productivity shocks on poverty using the Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP) general equilibrium global trade model and its accompanying database. Seaman et al. (2014) applied the Household Economy Approach, which relies on a defined reference period in which conditions are known (i.e., a ‘good’ or ‘bad’ year). They used it to estimate the expected change in a household’s food access from a shock or change in a current ‘prediction’ year, factoring in the amount of food and non-food goods which the household should be able to obtain, and the types and acceptable use of ‘coping’ strategies.Footnote 7 In contrast to these two simulation studies, we adopt an econometric approach based on a microeconomic food demand model to study the impact of climate change on poverty at the household level. In addition to disrupting the production cycle, one potential major effects of climate shocks, especially on poor households, is on consumption. Climate shocks destabilize consumption patterns of poor households more so than wealthier households because wealthier households can sell off assets to help smooth consumption while the poor households generally cannot (Hoddinott 2006; Carter et al. 2007; Carter and Lybbert 2012).

The key contribution of this paper is the study of the impact of climate shocks on poverty through consumption expenditure patterns of households using an empirical framework grounded on economic theory. We implement our two-step micro econometric model to quantify the change in household welfare due to climate-induced commodity price increases. Our empirical results for Swaziland suggest that while SSA countries contribute significantly less to climate change, they could bear the brunt of it in terms of increased incidence of poverty and economic decline. Our analysis provides important insights for targeted policy interventions such as social protection or compensation for households most vulnerable to the effects of climate change.

2 Background and literature review

The Kingdom of Swaziland is a landlocked country bordered by Mozambique on the east and South Africa along the north, south, and west of the country. The country is characterized by varying monthly average temperatures with warm to hot summers ranging between 19 and 26 degrees Celsius and winter temperatures between 13 degrees and 20 degrees Celsius.Footnote 8 The country’s climate is characterized by seasonal rainfall that varies at higher altitudes from 1000 mm to 1600 mm and between 500 mm and 600 mm in the lower areas. The country has a wide variety of habitats and significant variations in flora and fauna.

Swaziland is divided into four administrative regions: Hhohho in the north, Manzini in the center, Shiselweni in the south, and Lubombo in the east. Each administrative region consists of regional councils made up of 10 chiefdoms (Mwendera 2006). The Kingdom also has six physiographic zones grouped by elevation, geology, landforms, soils, and vegetation.

In 2010, Swaziland’s emission inventory was 0.8MtCO2e, which represents 0.002% of global emissions (Swaziland's INDC-Final-UNFCCC 2005). Overall, Africa is responsible for less than 4% of global greenhouse gas emissions (Sy 2016); yet, climate change is viewed as a serious threat to economic growth in Africa because of the reliance of food production on climate sensitive sectors with limited adaptation to the daunting challenges it poses (Abidoye and Odusola 2015). Knox et al. (2012) project average yield reductions of 17% for wheat, 5% for maize, 15% for sorghum, and 10% for millet in the African continent by 2050 because of climate change. A higher frequency of drought will increase food insecurity in areas where livelihoods are already precarious. Mendelsohn (2008) argued that the most significant known economic impact of climate change is upon agriculture, especially because farms in the low latitude countries already endure climates that are too hot. Kurukulasuriya et al. (2006) showed that warming is harmful to rain-fed farming in Africa, and rain-fed and irrigated farms both benefit (lose) if rainfall increases (falls). Swaziland’s trade ties with an economically powerful neighbor --South Africa--can help cushion some of the negative consequences of climate shocks (Abidoye and Odusola 2015). However, these links do not insulate the country from local price changes and shocks even if they can import cereals from South Africa during droughts as those droughts would lead to an increase in prices in the whole region. Rural communities are more vulnerable to the effects of climate change due to a lack of information on mitigation strategies and the financial capital to implement them (Manyatsi et al. 2010).

The welfare impact of food price changes depends on the structure of the economy and the nature of the products whose prices change (Ivanic and Martin 2008; Hertel and Winters 2006; Ravallion and Lokshin 2005; Wodon and Zaman 2010; Demeke and Rashid 2012). For example, the severity of the impact depends on the distribution of income and the percentage of net buyers and sellers within the country (Groom and Tak 2015; Ivanic and Martin 2008). It is expected that with an increase in food prices, the pattern of food consumption amongst households will change. Instead of consuming more, households will reduce consumption levels or substitute food commodities towards cheaper goods. D'Souza and Jolliffe (2012) point that we should look at smaller price elasticities per calories rather than per food consumption as most households tend to choose quantity over quality as they shift from consuming highly nutritious food to staple food.

Net consumers of food are most likely the ones affected by higher food prices, especially in urban areas where farming is not practiced (Ravallion 1990; Ivanic and Martin 2008). Ruel et al. (2009) contend that the 2006/7 price and fuel shocks intensively affected the urban poor compared to the rural poor. In a study on the negative impacts of higher food prices in Ghana, Minot and Dewina (2015) stated that female-headed households, who are net-buyers of food commodities, are the most affected by higher food prices compared to male-headed households. This is a consequence of less food production from female-headed households than male-headed households. On the other hand, higher prices are beneficial for households that are net producers, especially in developing countries, where farmers can increase production (Demeke and Rashid 2012). Hertel and Rosch (2010) and Bellemare (2015) also indicate that increases in food prices improve the welfare of net producers while reducing the welfare of households whose consumption is higher than their production. Countries/households that benefit most from price decreases will lose most from price increases, although the net impact may be affected by various policies (trade policy, taxes, etc.), by institutions, and by the industrial organization of the food chain (Centre for Economic Policy Research 2010). Finally, it is noted that in a general equilibrium framework, labor market responses spurred by increasing agricultural commodity prices can also produce positive income effects for farming workers that mitigate the direct impact of the price hikes on consumption (Ravallion 1990; Hertel and Rosch 2010). However, Banerjee (2007) cautions that climate change could depress demand for labor depending on the severity of natural disasters, further weakening the well-being of impacted households.

It is clear from the literature that previous work has mostly concentrated on the aggregate impact of climate change on the agricultural sector as a whole or economic growth in general. Few empirical studies have drilled down to the household level factoring in both demand and supply of commodities in rural and urban areas. We, therefore, examine empirically the impact of climate change on the welfare of households in Swaziland using IFPRI’s projected food prices to the year 2050 (Nelson et al. 2010) in light of the threat of climate change.

3 Methods and data

A priori, a household that is a net buyer will experience a welfare loss due to an increase in food prices.Footnote 9 In quantifying changes in welfare, this study follows Friedman and Levinsohn (2002) in estimating the compensating variation (CV), which measures the gain or loss in welfare in terms of the amount of income transfer required for a household to stay on its pre-price change indifference curve. In other words, CV is the difference between the minimum expenditure necessary to maintain the initial utility level at the new prices and the initial expenditure. Using the IFPRI-calculated projected cereal price changes due to climate change, this study estimates how worse off households become when they move from the initial utility level to utility post-price changes.

Let c (p,u) denote the expenditure function, i.e., the minimum amount of expenditure required to achieve a certain utility level, u, at a given price vector p. Assume that prices change from p0 to p1 as a result of the effects of climate change. As mentioned above, the CV is the difference between the minimum expenditure required to maintain the initial utility level at the new prices and the initial expenditure. Hence it is computed as:

$$ CV=c\ \left({p}^1,u\right)\hbox{--} c\ \left({p}^0,u\right) $$
(1)

The CV can be approximated around initial prices using a second-order Taylor expansion of the minimum expenditure function as follows (see, e.g., Friedman and Levinsohn 2002):

$$ \kern0.75em \Delta \ \mathit{\ln}\ c\approx {\sum}_{i=1}{w}_i\Delta \ln {P}_i+\frac{1}{2}{\sum}_{i=1}{\sum}_{j=1}{w}_i\ {\varepsilon}_{ij}^{\ast }\ \Delta {lnP}_i\ \Delta \ {lnP}_j $$
(2)

where wiis the budget share of commodity i in the initial period (2009/10),  ln Pi approximates the proportionate change in the price of commodity i, and \( {\varepsilon}_{ij}^{\ast } \) is the compensated cross-price elasticity. Eq. (2) indicates that the impact of a price change can be decomposed into a first order and a second order effect. The first order effect is a function of the magnitude of the proportionate price change and the relative importance of different food groups in the household’s consumption basket (captured by the budget shares). It is a measure of the proportionate change in expenditure needed to maintain pre-change utility levels when substitution between food commodities is not possible. As such, the first order effect generally overstates the compensating variation. The second order effect takes into account the fact that households will substitute away from the relatively more expensive good to the cheaper alternatives. The substitution effect is captured by the product between cross-price elasticities of demand and the budget shares. We implement the Almost Ideal Demand System (AIDS) (Deaton and Muellbauer 1980), which is one of the most widely accepted and estimated demand systems in the applied economics literature to estimate the matrix of cross-price compensated elasticities, which we then use to approximate the compensating variation.Footnote 10

Let wi denote ith commodity budget share, the AIDS is specified as:

$$ {w}_i={\upalpha}_{\mathrm{i}}+{\sum}_{j=1}^n{\gamma}_{\mathrm{i}\mathrm{j}}\kern0.5em \log \kern0.2em {\mathrm{p}}_j+{\upbeta}_{\mathrm{j}}\log \kern0.1em \left(\frac{x}{P}\right) $$
(3)
$$ \log\ \mathrm{P}={\alpha}_0+{\sum}_{k=1}^n{\alpha}_{\mathrm{k}}\ \log {p}_k+\frac{1}{2}\ {\sum}_{\mathrm{k}}\ {\sum}_{\mathrm{j}}\ {\gamma}_{\mathrm{k}\mathrm{j}}\kern0.5em \log\ {p}_k\ \log {p}_{\mathrm{j}}\kern0.5em $$
(4)

where x is food expenditure, the pj’s are food prices, αi, γij, and βi are parameters to be estimated and P is the trans logarithmic price index; thus \( \frac{x}{P} \) stands for the real expenditure.

To estimate the AIDS model, we use the 2009/2010 Household and Income Survey data collected by the Central Statistics Office (Central Statistics Office 2011) from 375 enumerated areas of the Kingdom of Swaziland. The survey is national in nature with financial and technical assistance provided by the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) and the Accelerated Data Program that also provided technical support.Footnote 11 While the survey was initially designed to be conducted every 5 years, it has not been implemented since 2009/10, according to the government’s website.Footnote 12 The study used the 2007 population census to locate enumeration areas and the primary sampling units. A two-stage stratification sampling method was incorporated in the surveys across both rural and urban settlements, cutting through all the ecological, administrative, land distribution, and tenure features (CSO 2011). Our final sample is comprised of 3143 households and captures information on both the production and consumption of food products.

Given the broad nature of the food categories, we group the food commodities in five food bundles, as is standard practice in models similar to ours (e.g., Molina 1994; Agbola 2003). For instance, Agbola (2003), in estimating food demand for South Africa, grouped the food items into meat and fish, grains, dairy products, fruits, vegetables, and other foods. Our classification of the food items is closer to that of Agbola (2003), given the similarities in culture across the two countries. We categorize the food items into five groups, namely: (1) cereals, roots, and tubers, (2) vegetables, legumes and nuts, (3) fruits, (4) meat, eggs, fish and dairy products, and (5) other food products. Vegetables and fruits are not combined in line with Agbola (2003) and based on the way food is typically made in Swaziland. Pepper/chili, spinach, and tomatoes, for instance, are consumed with fresh peas, beans, and other nuts. Table 1 details the composition of food commodities found in each food group.

Table 1 Composition of food aggregation on consumed food commodities in Swaziland

To estimate the demand equation, the annual prices, annual expenditure, and annual budget shares of the five food groups were used. For the annual prices, the total expenditure values given by households on a specific item are used and divided by the number of items bought. The price was then multiplied by 12 to annualize and estimate the change of price over 12 months. For the commodity group prices, the price within the group is weighted by the total number of the items consumed in that group.

Per share statistics in Table 2, the cereals, root and tubers and meat, eggs, fish, and dairy product groups are the two most important food groups, accounting respectively for 31.46 and 25.14% of food expenditure. The cereal category consists mostly of maize, the staple food of Swaziland. Vegetables, legumes and nuts represent 20.47% and fruits represent 10.17% of food expenditure, while the remaining combined category accounts for 12.77%.Footnote 13

Table 2 Total consumption expenditure by households and share of households that consume each food group in Swaziland

The food consumption expenditures in the survey were collected in a series of diary modules filled daily by household members over a maximum period of 7 days. The diary was also used for “goods and services received” and “own-produce consumption.” However, despite the detailed diary of data, some food items were not purchased by the household.

Per Table 3, the food expenditure share remained stable between the survey rounds of 2000/01 and 2009/10, respectively 21.5% and 21.4% of the total household expenditure. However, the share of “food received,” primarily from food baskets from development aid programs, increased significantly from 2000/01 to 2009/10. Even with the grouping of the data into food categories, none of the five groups was purchased by all households sampled, resulting in zero expenditure. Zero expenditure, in this case, does not mean zero consumption; it simply means that the household did not purchase the product during the survey period either because the household produced the good, received it as a gift, survey period (7 days) being too short or because of household preferences.

Table 3 Household expenditure structure, 2000/01 vs. 2009/10

If unaccounted for econometrically, zero expenditure leads to biased and inconsistent elasticity estimates (Sam and Zheng 2010) due to censored response bias. We, therefore, implement a consistent two-stage estimator (Shonkwiler and Yen 1999; Sam and Zheng 2010) to circumvent this issue. The first stage consists of estimating a binary single-index model for each commodity to predict its probability of consumption. Suppose we have L household observations on each commodity and suppose that the probability of consuming commodity i by household l is a function of control variables \( {z}_{il}^{\prime } \) and a normally distributed error termvil. That is \( {d}_{il}=I\left({z}_{il}^{\prime }{\delta}_i+{v}_{il}>0\right)\kern0.75em \)where dil is a binary variable that equals one if commodity group i is consumed by household l, zero otherwise; I(.) is an indicator function and δi a parameter vector. To account for the censoring of the commodities, the predicted probabilities of consumption Φ(z'iδi)and inverse mills ratios \( \frac{\varphi \left(z{\hbox{'}}_i{\delta}_i\right)}{\Phi \left(z{\hbox{'}}_i{\delta}_i\right)} \)are computed for each commodity group from the first stage probit and added nonlinearly to the AIDS equation as follows:

$$ {w}_i=\Phi \left(z{\hbox{'}}_i{\delta}_i\right)\left({\alpha}_i+{\beta}_i\log \kern0.22em \left(\frac{x}{P}\right)+\sum \limits_{j=1}^n{\gamma}_{ij}\log {p}_{\begin{array}{l}j\\ {}\end{array}}+{\theta}_i\frac{\varphi \left(z{\hbox{'}}_i{\delta}_i\right)}{\Phi \left(z{\hbox{'}}_i{\delta}_i\right)}\right)+{\zeta}_i,\kern0.36em i=1,\dots \dots n\kern2.4em $$
(5)

As commonly done, the five censored AIDS equations are estimated as a system of seemingly unrelated regressions.Footnote 14 The expenditure and uncompensated (Marshallian) elasticities are calculated from the parameters of the AIDS model, respectively, as follows: ei = 1+\( {\Phi}_i\frac{\upbeta_{\mathrm{i}}}{w} \) where Φi is the estimated probability of consuming food category, and eij = \( {\Phi}_i\left(\frac{\upgamma_{\mathrm{i}\mathrm{j}}-{\upbeta}_{\mathrm{i}}\ \left[{\mathrm{w}}_{\mathrm{j}}-{\upbeta}_{\mathrm{j}}\ast \log \left(\frac{x}{P}\right)\right]\kern0.5em }{w_{\mathrm{i}}}\right)- \) sij where sij is a dummy that equals 1 if i = j; 0 otherwise (Sam and Zheng 2010).

4 Results

Before discussing the results, we present summary statistics of the key variables in the model in Table 4. The average household size is about 5, and household heads are about 45 years old on average. The sample has more male (55%) than female household heads and is more rural (56.5%) than urban. On average, households spend a significant share of their food expenditure on Cereals, root and tubers and Meat, fish, eggs, and dairy. Fruits have the lowest share of household food expenditure. The food group made of meat, fish, eggs, and dairy products is produced by most households (54%), while fruits are only produced by 10% of the households. Commodity group prices are obtained as a weighted average price of the food components for each group with the individual commodity expenditures serving as weights.

Table 4 Demographic and other variables used to estimate parameters in the demand system

In addition to the summary statistics at the national level, we also present summary statistics by region (Table 5). Household size, for instance, is highest in the Shisel region of the country at 5.4 people per household. The second highest average household size is in Lubomb region at about 4.6 people per household; in contrast, Hhohho has the smallest average household size at 4.0. There is also heterogeneity in the level of prices across the regions based on the combination of commodities in each group. For instance, Lubomb region has the highest annual average price (SZL/Kg.) for group 1 foods (cereals, roots, and tubers) at 1.32 SZL/Kg but with more substantial variation in the prices. Prices are lower in Hhohho region, and the standard deviation is also lower. In terms of production of the different food categories, it can be seen from Fig. 1 that households in the Shisel region produce the highest percentage of meat, cereal, vegetable, and fruit products which likely leads to lower consumption expenditure on these goods in this region relative to the other areas. Cereal production by households is about the same in the other three regions, but Luhomb is the second producer of fruit and vegetable products.

Table 5 Summary statistics of demographic variables by region
Fig. 1
figure 1

Percentage of households producing each of the commodity groups. Source: Authors’ calculations based on data from SHIES (2009/2010)

4.1 First stage results

The IFPRI price projections used in the analysis are conducted at a global level based on the price of mostly consumed food crops such as cereals (maize, wheat, and rice). The projections were from 2010 to 2050, a period of 40 years. Unlike Nelson et al. (2009), which projected future outcomes of climate change and price increases using only GDP and population, these projections utilized a combination of income and population growth to estimate the outcomes in 3 scenarios: a baseline scenario to represent the most likely outcome of status quo income and population growth, an optimistic scenario that is likely to result in low population and high-income growth rates, and a pessimistic scenario with more negative outcomes for human well-being with high population and low-income growth rates. Each of these scenarios is subjected to five plausible climate futures that range from slightly to substantially wetter and hotter on average than the current climate representative concentration pathways of low, medium, and high GHG emissions.Footnote 15 The IFPRI projected prices are based on climate change projections that are also typically based on average projected changes in precipitation and temperature up to either 2050, 2070, or 2100. The paper (Nelson et al. 2010) presented the projections for the 2050 average. Based on IPCC’s Special Report on Emissions Scenarios (SRES), climate change is given as a warming average for the period 2011 to 2030 compared to say 1980 to 1999. Thus the estimate is not a series of changes in climate over time but discrete values of the average. This average change in temperature and precipitation was used n the IFPRI paper to model price changes due to climate change. The price changes used in the welfare analysis are based on projected changes in one food category - cereal. The IFPRI projected prices covered three commodities: maize, rice, and wheat. These three commodities add up to about 58% of annual food expenditure in Swaziland.

The results of the first stage probit estimations can be found in Table 6. In the first stage, we estimate the likelihood of choosing each of the food categories by a household. The dependent variables in these equations are dichotomous variables that take the value 1 if the household makes a purchase and zero otherwise. In addition to income (deciles) and food prices, the probit models also control for the effects of several household characteristics on the probability of consumption. Estimated coefficients on the income decile, household size, and region 2 (Hhohho) are positive and significant for all food groups and significant at 1% level. The income decile coefficient is highly significant at 1% level and positive, indicating that the higher the income level, the higher one’s consumption level of each food group, especially the cereals, roots, and tubers category. The coefficient on the location variable indicates that rural households consume fewer meats and vegetables than urban households. The gender coefficient indicates that male-headed households consume less cereal and vegetables than female-headed households. Residents of the Manzini, Hhohho, and Shiselweni regions are significantly more likely to consume the food categories than residents of the Lubombo region (omitted to avoid perfect collinearity), which has lower crop yields. It is important to note that the first stage only serves to correct for potential censoring bias in the main parameters of interest (second stage), hence the lack of emphasis on the results.

Table 6 Probit model explaining the likelihood of consuming each of the food groups

4.2 Second stage results

Table 7 presents the second-stage parameter estimates of the censored AIDS model. The results show that all price and expenditure parameters and most of the parameters for the demographic variables are significant. All five inverse mills ratio coefficients are statistically significant, indicating the statistical necessity to account for the censoring of the commodities.

Table 7 AIDS model estimates (Eq. 5)

Since these coefficients do not lend themselves to a direct economic interpretation, we focus our discussion on the elasticity estimates instead. Table 8 presents expenditure shares and expenditure elasticities for the five food commodities, given at means. The results indicate that all the commodities are normal goods, consumption of which will increase with an increase in income. Overall, the results show price elasticities below 1.0 for cereals (0.9560), vegetables, legumes and nuts (0.8368), and fruits (0.7984). This indicates that these food groups are relatively income inelastic. On the other hand, the expenditure elasticities for meats and dairy (1.0561) and the other food group (which includes sugars, fats, and oils) (1.1738) suggest that they are luxury goods.

Table 8 Expenditure elasticities and expenditure shares for purchased food commodities

Price elasticities quantify the responsiveness of quantity demanded to a change in prices. As illustrated in the approximation of the CV equation, they are an essential input to the formulation of tax or subsidy policies designed to mitigate consumer welfare loss spurred by adverse price changes. Uncompensated elasticities measure households’ adjustment of quantities consumed as a result of a price change; as such, they reflect both income and substitution effects induced by the change in price. Compensated elasticities, on the other hand, measure only the substitution effect of a price change when consumers are compensated just enough to stay on their pre-price change utility level.

Uncompensated and compensated elasticities from the AIDS model, evaluated at the mean sample of the data, are reported in Table 9 in matrix form with rows and columns composed of the five food groups: (1) cereals, roots, and tubers, (2) vegetables, legumes, and nuts, (3) fruits, (4) meat, fish, eggs and dairy products and (5) other foods, respectively. A few observations are worthy of a brief discussion. First, all elasticities are less than unity in absolute value, indicating that the food groups are not very sensitive to changes in prices. Second, all compensated and uncompensated own-price elasticities of consumed commodities are negative and statistically different from zero as expected and consistent with the law of demand. Third, the estimated income effect is significant given the sizable differences between the compensated and uncompensated elasticities in general. For example, a 1% increase in the price of cereals leads to a 0.1386% decline in the demand for meats (uncompensated elasticity) when the income effect is considered. With no income effect, the same price change leads to a 0.1973% increase in the demand for meats due to a pure substitution effect to the relatively cheaper commodity. The size of the income effect is further evidenced by the fact that there are several gross complements (uncompensated elasticities) but net substitutes (compensated elasticities). We now turn to the welfare analysis to examine how consumers would fare if the projected price increases due to climate change were to materialize.

Table 9 Uncompensated and compensated own price elasticities for purchased commodities

4.3 Welfare analysis

To gauge the price effects of climate change on household welfare, we used the same scenarios from IFPRI’s food price projections to the year 2050 (Nelson et al. 2010). The use of scenarios is essential for climate change modeling because of the uncertainty about future economic development and human activities. The IFPRI food price projections were developed based on the original climate scenarios used in the SRES of the third IPCC assessment.Footnote 16 From the SRES, individual scenarios are grouped into families depending on assumptions around future population, GDP, and GDP per capita. For the IFPRI price projections and, consequently, welfare estimates in this paper, the scenarios A1B, A2, and B1 form the basis for the optimistic and pessimistic price projections. The population, GDP, and GDP per capita estimates from the SRES were updated by IFPRI to capture the 2010–2050 period (see Table A2.1 in Nelson et al. 2010).

As done in the IFPRI study, we consider three cases: the baseline or most likely case, an optimistic case with high income and low population growth and pessimistic case with low income and high population growth rate. We use data from Table 2.2 of Nelson et al. (2010) for these three scenarios to come up with projected prices increases that reflect consumption patterns in Swaziland for the cereal group only.Footnote 17 Cereal prices are expected to rise by 70.14%, 53.85%, and 82.1%, respectively in the baseline (most likely), optimistic and pessimistic cases by 2050, relative to 2010 baseline prices.

We combine the projected price increases mentioned above with the budget shares of the five commodity groups and their compensated price elasticities to estimate the first and second-order components of the compensating variation (Eq. 2). Table 10 presents the results of the welfare analysis for the three scenarios based on changes in the prices of maize, wheat, and rice (cereal group).

Table 10 Analysis of welfare effects due to an increase in cereal prices by household income decile

Two key observations emerge from the welfare estimation. First, the proportionate increase in income required to maintain pre-price change utilities is roughly the same across the income distribution as well as between urban and rural residents (unlike Friedman and Levinsohn (2002)). The estimated compensation variation figures indicate that climate spurred-increases in cereal prices are expected to lead to a significant worsening of well-being among Swazi consumers, income transfers of between 17.48 and 25.44% of pre-change expenditure are needed to avoid welfare losses depending on the price projection scenario. Swazi households are likely to experience even higher welfare losses due to increases in the prices of the other food categories, which for this analysis are held constant. Meat and dairy prices are likely to rise due to drier climate conditions and therefore reduced pasture for meat production.

Second, compared to the baseline (current) poverty rates, we find that the projected increases in cereal prices will result in a significant rise in poverty in the absence of an intervention to mitigate the consequences of the price increases. Per the survey data, many Swazi households live under SZL461 (about $63 based on the exchange rate at the time of the survey) per adult per month. This translates into a 100% poverty rate for 63% for all households that are in the 1st to the 6th household income deciles. The poverty rate declines to 28% at the 7th decile, and it is zero from the 8th to 10th decile. A 100% extreme poverty rate (below SZL215.00 per adult per month) is observed for the two lowest deciles, and it declines to 87.4% for households in the third decile and zeroes for all other deciles. 63% (28%) of rural residents are classified as poor (extremely poor), with 25% (4%) of urban residents classified as such.

With the estimated compensating variation figures, we calculated the new poverty rates that would prevail if the projected price increases were to materialize based on the current national poverty (SZL 462 a day per adult) and extreme poverty (SZL 125) levels. Doing so, we find a drastic increase in both poverty measures across the income distribution with 94.6% of households in decile 7 (compared to 28% with no price change) and 29.1% of households in decile 8 (compared to 0% with no price change) classified as “poor” in the most likely scenario. Extreme poverty is expected to increase similarly, going from zero to 84% and 23% for households in the fourth- and fifth-income deciles, respectively. Table 11 further summarizes the estimated welfare effects. While urban households are expected to experience faster growth in poverty compared to rural households (between a 33 and 51% growth in the poverty rate), poverty rates for rural households are expected to increase to alarming levels (between 70 and 74%). Extreme poverty is expected to double in urban areas though it will remain a small fraction compared to extreme poverty in rural areas (8.59% vs. 40.78% in the most likely scenario). The combination of the results in the urban and rural areas indicates that climate change is expected to have severe consequences for the well-being of households in developing countries with poorer rural households bearing the brunt of it.

Table 11 Analysis of welfare effects due to an increase in cereal prices for rural and urban households

5 Discussion

Our results show that Swazi households, especially those living in rural areas, could experience a significant deterioration in living standards if the IFPRI-projected climate scenarios were to materialize. Absent any intervention to mitigate the effect of food price increases, poverty rates are expected to increase by ten percentage points, up from 25 and 63%, respectively, in urban and rural areas. Likewise, extreme poverty is expected to double in urban areas but affect a relatively small fraction of residents (from 4 to nearly 9%) in the most likely scenario. In rural areas, extreme poverty is expected to rise from 28 to 41% in the most likely scenario. Besides the documented negative effect on poverty, a significant increase in food prices has the potential to generate violence and social unrest, as evidenced by Bellemare (2015). Climate change could also accentuate the volatility of agricultural production and prices, leading to increased risks for producers, consumers, and governments alike (Li et al. 2017; Sam 2010a).

As mentioned above, a spate of papers have studied the links between food prices and poverty. Three of these are closely related to ours. Dessus et al. (2008) conclude that a growth rate of gross domestic product (GDP) between 0.2 and 3% is required to offset the effect of increased food prices on urban poverty. Simulations by Hertel et al. (2010) indicate that a rapid rise in global temperatures, combined with high sensitivity of crops to heat and a low level of CO2 fertilization effect could result in as much as a 60% increase in prices by 2030 for major cereal crops. Such price increases are expected to raise the poverty rate by between 20 and 50% among non-agricultural households in some SSA countries. The estimated impacts on poverty take into account both the adverse change in the cost of living, which primarily affects urban wage earners, as well as a positive change in incomes (higher food prices due to reduced production and inelasticity of food demand) that mostly accrue to rural farmers. Similarly, simulations by Seaman et al. (2014) indicate that a 50% drop in agricultural output and increase in food prices will lead to a significant increase in the number of people below the poverty line in Salima, Malawi, and a substantial drop in disposable income in the Northern Border Upland Cereal and Livestock Zone in Namibia among the poor and very poor, potentially leading to migration from rural to urban areas.

Unlike our paper, Dessus et al. (2008) did not focus on the impact of climate change, and the other two papers use simulation methods to generate their results. Instead, we adopt an econometric approach based on a popular microeconometric food demand model (AIDS) to study the impact of climate change on poverty at the household level. Despite the difference in analytical approaches, our results are broadly consistent with the findings of these papers: climate change spurred shocks to food prices could have debilitating consequences on the welfare of many households in SSA.

It should be stressed that our methodology does not fully capture the effects of increasing food prices due to climate change on food consumption. First, higher food prices generate a beneficial income effect for rural households whose income primarily emanates from agriculture (Dessus et al. 2008). That said, a large proportion--a majority in some countries--of food producers are net food buyers (Barrett and Lentz 2010; Jayne et al. 1999), hence will be adversely impacted by higher food prices without an attendant increase in income. The trend toward more urbanization in SSA is likely to magnify the household welfare losses discussed above. Second, increases in agricultural commodity prices could trigger a positive wage response that dampens the negative spending-related effect of the price increase (Hertel and Rosch 2010; Ravallion 1990). However, Banerjee (2007) notes that such a positive wage response is not likely to materialize; instead, climate change could reduce wages for workers, creating a “double-whammy” spending and income effect. Finally, our welfare analysis rests on simulated changes in the prices of cereals only; further empirical research is needed to shed more light on the comprehensive effects of climate change on household welfare.

6 Conclusion

Climate change has become a subject of serious concern in Africa because of its potentially devastating effect on agriculture, the primary source of food production in the region. Our empirical estimates, based on household survey data from Swaziland, suggest that there is reason to be alarmed about its effects on poverty in SSA countries. Policy-wise, several actions can be taken to minimize the effects of climate change on household welfare. For example, international aid agencies and/or SSA governments could incentivize the adoption of climate resilient techniques and sustainable food security by training farmers on climate smart agricultural practices and providing subsidies to purchase inputs that tare are better suited for extreme weather patterns such as heat or drought resistant seeds to boost agricultural productivity (Onyutha 2019). Such policies should be coupled with better integration of rural food markets to regional and national markets. Doing so could motivate rural producers to increase food production, which in turn should minimize food price inflation. Households are also likely to adapt to the changing climate by diversifying income generating activities (Diiro and Sam 2015). Finally, SSA governments could keep price increases in check by reducing tariffs and other taxes on staple foods such as maize. Together, these policies could substantially mitigate the adverse effects of climate change on food prices and household welfare.