Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Mobile Politicians: Opportunistic Career Moves

  • Published:
Journal of Labor Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Using information on more than 1,500 elected Members of the Parliament (MPs) and the votes received by political parties in five consecutive elections in Turkey (1991–2011) and employing a controlling strategy, we show that elected MPs are more likely to switch parties after an election if they faced greater electoral uncertainty and experienced a narrowly-won victory. Politicians switch parties after an election to improve their ex-ante re-election probability in the following election, and party-switching MPs are more likely to get elected in the next election. MPs switch parties to move towards the median voter. These results point to forward-looking opportunistic behavior of politicians regarding their strategy to win future elections to have a longer tenure in the Parliament.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Data Availability

We will make the data and program available.

Notes

  1. Kemahlioglu and Sayari (2017) (KS) also studies the determinants of party switching in Turkey. They show that MPs switch parties due to both re-election and ideological concerns. Our paper differs from theirs in a number of ways. First, we study the time period 1995–2011, while their analysis period is 1995–2002. Second, unlike (KS) who measure election uncertainty using MP’s party’s vote share in the most recent elections, we measure election uncertainty faced by the MPs by using their rank on their party’s ticket. Our measure allows each MP to face a different election uncertainty, while in (KS) all MPs of a party in a certain province face the same election uncertainty. Additionally, we investigate election outcomes after switching, such as the probability of re-election.

  2. This is in contrast to some of the past findings. For example, Heller and Mershon (2005) and Grose and Yoshinaka (2003) find that switchers are unlikely to get re-elected in Italy and US Congress, respectively. These authors argue that party-switchers are punished by voters or party leaders. Our paper shows that (destination) party leaders favor incoming MPs by nominating them in districts or ranks that are more favorable to their re-election chances. Also, the vote share of the destination party increases if their ticket contains a party-switcher. As a result, in the Turkish setting the party-switchers are more likely to get re-elected.

  3. In 1991 elections, a preferential voting system is used. In this system, voters, after choosing casting ballot for their party, optionally voted for one preferred MP candidate from that party’s list.

  4. Nominal MP salaries are increased twice a year. The rate of increase in salaries, however, varies from year to year.

  5. The MPs who passed away before the end of the term are not in the analysis, neither are those who resigned from their party but remained unaffiliated with any party or who were forced to resign by the constitutional court. An MP’s move to another party is not counted as a party-switch if their initial party is shut down by the constitutional court. If an MP’s party changed names, then this is not considered as party-switch either.

  6. This strategy resulted in about 110 treated (Party Switch = 1) observations in the working sample, i.e., they were within the common support and within our caliper depending on the model. This matching method improved covariate balance. Appendix 4 Table 16 shows the covariate balance for the model in column 2 of Table 6. The differences between the treated and control groups’ observable variables disappear in the matched sample.

  7. Some MP-term observations are omitted. Specifically, the MPs who passed away before the end of the term are not in the analysis, so are the MPs who resigned from their party but remained as independent (not affiliated with any party) or who were forced to resign by the constitutional court. An MP’s switch to another party is not counted as a party switch if their initial party is shut down by the constitutional court. Some parties changed their names. Such name changes are not considered as party switches either.

  8. https://www.tbmm.gov.tr/develop/owa/td_v2_istatistik.uyeler

  9. http://www.worldvaluessurvey.org/wvs.jsp. World Values Survey is administered to nationally representative samples that range between 1000 and 3400.

  10. This is because of two reasons. First, AKP could form majority governments without the support of other parties. For example, in the 22nd and 23rd terms, the number of seats of AKP in the Parliament were 90 and 61 above 275, the minimum number of supporting MPs required to form the government. AKP’s super majority reduced the value of “poaching” an MP from the government party or the opposition parties. In addition, post-2002 period coincided with increased political polarization as well as a reduction of the number of parties represented in the parliament. The system is almost reduced to AKP vs. anti-AKP blocs, and there were significant ideological differences between these blocs. If politicians are less likely to switch to parties that are ideologically distant (Kemahlioglu and Sayari 2017), then one should observe fewer switches.

  11. Here we provide a summary of some of these results. Table 2 shows that the age of the MP is negatively associated with party-switching. Appendix 3-Table 12 additionally shows that election uncertainty triggers party-switching for younger politicians but not for older ones. Table 2 shows that MP’s education level has no significant impact on party-switching. However, the analysis in Appendix 3-Table 13 reveals that the tendency to switch party affiliation due to election risk is driven by less educated politicians and that the undergraduate college major of the MP or the graduate-level field of study has no impact on the propensity to switch parties. On the other hand, Appendix 3-Fig. 2 shows the increase in the quality (selectiveness) of the MP’s alma mater mitigates the impact of electoral uncertainty on party-switching. Results in Table 2 suggest that if the MP is a member of the governing party, then his/her probability of switching parties is greater. This is likely because such a transfer is more valuable for destination parties (i.e., the opposition parties) as an MP’s switch to the opposition would weaken the government. Supporting this hypothesis, Appendix 3-Fig. 3 shows that the propensity of an MP to switch parties is higher if the MP is a member of the governing party, but only if the majority of that party in the Parliament is slim. In our empirical analyses, we omitted the MPs who remained independent (rather than joining another party) after resigning from their original party. Results are not sensitive to including these MPs in our regressions. We find that lower-ranked MPs are more likely to switch to another party rather than switching to the status of an “independent MP” (Appendix 4-Tables 14 and 15).

  12. District and party characteristics are not balanced across MP ranks. This is because highly-populated provinces are represented by more MPs, than smaller provinces. Consequently, the lower-ranked MPs are more likely to be elected in such districts. At the same time, provinces differ significantly according to how large they are. For example, the average income in large provinces is higher. Thus, if we compare the cities of the MPs of various ranks, we find significant differences. Similar arguments apply to party characteristics. We control for these province and party characteristics in our regressions.

  13. Margin of Victory is the distance between the elected MP’s quotient, calculated by the d’Hondt formula and the quotient of the Cutoff candidate (Appendix 1-Table 9). Smaller MVs signify a greater election uncertainty.

  14. Since we can only observe the MPs who ran for re-election, regressions in columns 2–5 of Table 6 are estimated over the MPs who ran for re-election. To guard against the potentially confounding selection effect, we use the inverse-probability-weighting (IPW) procedure (Wooldridge 2002). IPW gives less weight to observations from MPs who are more likely to be in the sample (more likely to run for re-election). The weights are the inverse of the predicted probability of running in the re-election (column 1 of Table 6). Results without IPW are almost identical to those presented in Table 6.

  15. As a robustness check, we estimated models in columns 2 to 4 of Table 6, using propensity score matching. We used nearest neighbor matching with a caliper of 0.001 and used bootstrapped standard errors. The results are similar to those reported in Table 6. Specifically, our estimates for the effect of party switching for columns 2 to 4 are -3.60 (2.84), -5.38* (2.97), -1.40 (1.31), and -1.29 (1.12), respectively. These estimates are within one standard error window of the estimated effects in Table 6.

  16. In these regressions, we use inverse-probability-weighting method. The weights are the inverse of the predicted probabilities estimated in column 1 of Table 7. We also estimated unweighted regressions. The coefficient Their results show that there is no statistically significant difference in re-election probabilities of party-switchers vs. those who did not switch.

  17. The location of parties on political spectrum has not moved over this time period, with one exception. One of the social democratic parties (CHP) has moved slightly to the right (from 3.5 to 5).

  18. The findings in the literature about the impact of being a member of the government party on party switching are mixed. For example, Heller and Mershon (2008) find that being a member of the governing party increased probability of switching in some terms of the Italian Parliament, while it decreased this probability in other terms. McMenamin and Gwiazda (2011) find a similar pattern for the Polish Parliament. On the other hand, Desposato (2006) finds that party switching MPs move to governmental parties in Brazil.

  19. More accurately, elections take place 4 years apart, and the change in a variable Y between elections (ΔYt) represents Yt -Yt-4.

References

  • Akhmedov A, Zhuravskaya E (2004) Opportunistic political cycles: test in a young democracy setting. Q J Econ 119(4):1301–1338

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Cassidy T, Troiano U (2019) Old and young politicians. Economica 86:689–727

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro R (1973) The control of politicians. Public Choice 14(1):19–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley T (2006) Principled Agents?: The Political Economy of Good Government. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley T, Montalvo J, Reynal-Querol M (2011) Do educated leaders matter? Econ J 121:205–227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brender A, Drazen A (2005) Political budget cycles in new versus established democracies. J Monet Econ 52:1271–1295

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clayton A, Zetterberg P (2021) Gender and party discipline: evidence from Africa’s emerging party systems. Am Polit Sci Rev 115(3):869–884

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Çarkoğlu A, Hinich MJ (2006) A spatial analysis of Turkish party preferences. Elect Stud 25(2):369–392

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Croson R, Gneezy U (2009) Gender differences in preferences. J Econ Lit 47(2):448–474

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Da Silveira B, DeMello J (2011) Campaign advertising and election outcomes: quasi-natural experiment evidence from gubernatorial elections in Brazil. Rev Econ Stud 78(2):590–612

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Dal Bó E, Dal Bó P, Snyder J (2009) Political dynasties. Rev Econ Stud 76:115–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desposato SW (2006) Parties for rent? ambition, ideology, and party switching in Brazil’s chamber of deputies. Am J Political Sci 50(1):62–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eggers A, Hainmueller J (2009) MPs for sale? returns to office in postwar British politics. Am Polit Sci Rev 103(4):513–533

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferejohn J (1986) Incumbent performance and electoral control. Public Choice 50(2):5–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finan F, Schechter L (2012) Vote-buying and Reciprocity. Econometrica 80(2):863–82

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Galasso V, Nannicini T (2015) So closed: political selection in proportional systems. Eur J Polit Econ 40B:260–273

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grose C, Yoshinaka A (2003) The electoral consequences of party switching by incumbent members of congress, 1947–2000. Legis Stud Q 28(1):55–75

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heller W, Mershon C (2005) Party switching in the italian chamber of deputies, 1996–2001. J Politics 67(2):536–559

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heller W, Mershon C (2008) Party switching and legislative voting in the italian chamber of deputies, 1988–2000. Am J Political Sci 52(4):910–925

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heller WB, Mershon C (2009) “Introduction: legislative party switching, parties and party systems” chapter 1. In: Heller WB, Mershon C (eds) Political parties and legislative party switching. Palgrave MacMillan, New York

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Hicken A (2006) Stuck in the Mud: Parties and Party Systems in Democratic Southeast Asia. Taiwan J Democr 2(2):23–46

    Google Scholar 

  • Kemahlioglu O, Sayari S (2017) Defecting alone or splitting together? individual and collective party switching by legislators. Public Choice 171(1–2):187–206

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laver M, Benoit K (2003) The evolution of party systems between elections. Am J Political Sci 47(2):215–233

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mershon C (2014) Legislative party switching. In: Martin S, Saafeld T, Strom K (eds) Ch.20 oxford handbook of legislative studies. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Mocan N, Rees D (2005) Economic conditions, deterrence and juvenile crime: evidence from micro data. Am Law Econ Rev 7(2):319–349

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Brien DZ, Shomer Y (2013) A cross-National Analysis of party switching. Legis Stud Q 38(1):111–141

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palomares A, Ramirez V (2003) Thresholds of the divisor methods. Numer Algorithms 34(2–4):405–415

    Article  ADS  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Persson T, Roland G, Tabellini G (1997) Separation of powers and political accountability. Quart J Econ 112(4):1163–1202

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reed S, Scheiner E (2003) Electoral incentives and policy preferences: mixed motives behind party defections in Japan. Br J Political Sci 33(3):469–490

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Secor AJ (2001) Toward a Feminist Counter-geopolitics: Gender, Space and Islamist Politics in Istanbul. Space and Polity 5(3):191–211

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge J (2002) Inverse probability weighted M-estimators for sample selection, attrition, and stratification. Port Econ J 1(2):117–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Funding

None.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

Both authors contributed equally to all aspects of research.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Naci Mocan.

Ethics declarations

Ethical Approval

None required.

Informed Consent

N/A.

Conflict of Interest

The authors declare no material or other conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix for Mobile Politicians: Opportunistic Career Moves

Appendix 1: d’Hondt Example

In this section, we first explain how seats are allocated to political parties in the d’Hondt method. We then provide evidence that shows small changes in the distribution of votes can impact the number of seats won by each party. We additionally show that MPs with smaller Margins of Victory (MVs) are at the risk of losing their seats if vote distribution in the district changes even slightly. Finally, we demonstrate how we compute the MVs.

In the d’Hondt method, the number of votes obtained by each party in the district is divided by consecutive positive integers up to, and including, the total number of seats in that district. Parties with the largest quotients win seats. Consider the hypothetical example of a district with 100 voters. Assume that there are seven seats to be allocated and five competing parties: A, B, C, D, and E. Suppose that in the election, these parties have obtained 10, 13, 19, 25, and 33 votes, respectively. d’Hondt method divides each party’s votes by 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, and 7. Parties with the seven largest quotients win seats. This is illustrated in Panel 1 of Appendix 1 Table 9. The seven biggest quotients (highlighted in bold) are 33, 25, 19, 16.5, 13, 12.5 and 11. The quotients 33, 16.5, and 11 are associated with party E. Therefore, Party E wins 3 of the seven available seats. The quotients 25 and 12.5 belong to Party D, so Party D wins two seats, and Parties B and C win one seat each. As a result, party B’s and party C’s top-ranked candidates are elected as MPs. Party D sends its top 2 candidates to the Parliament, and party E’s top 3 candidates are elected as MPs. Party A does not win a seat.

Table 9 Hypothetical d’Hondt example of votes shares and seat allocations

To see how small changes in the distribution of votes can impact who is elected from a given party, compare the vote distributions depicted in Panels 1 and 2 of Appendix 1 Table 9. In both cases, there are 100 voters, and in both cases, parties B, C, and E receive the same number of votes. The only difference between the election results shown in Panels 1 and 2 is that in Panel 2, Party D received 23 votes (instead of 25), and these two voters moved from Party D to Party A. The resultant d’Hondt calculation is presented in Panel 2, which shows that the 2% loss suffered by Party D did not impact the number of seats of Party D (party D still qualified for two seats). On the other hand, this 2% vote loss of Party D produced a seat in the Parliament for Party A at the expense of a seat for Party E. More specifically, this slight shift of votes from Party D to Party A cost one MP to Party E, while Party A gained one seat. As a result of these changes, the 3rd-ranked candidate of Party E is not elected, while the 1st ranked candidate of Party A is elected. As shown in Panel 3 of Appendix 1 Table 9, if two more individuals had voted for party A instead of D, the election outcome would have been more different yet: In that case, parties A, B, C, and D would qualify for one seat each, while party E would have 3 MPs.

The examples demonstrated above suggest that some candidates, especially those who won by a small margin of votes, were at the risk of losing their seats if the vote distribution in the district was slightly different. To identify the MPs who were at high risk of losing the election, we compute the Margin of Victory (MV) for each elected MP for in vote distribution depicted in Panel 1 of Appendix 1 Table 9. Panel 4 of Appendix 1 Table 9 displays these calculations. We define MV as the difference between the quotients of each elected candidate and the candidate who just missed qualifying for the last seat from that district. For example, the person who won the 7th and the last seat in this district is candidate E3, and her margin of victory is 1 (the difference between the E3’s and A1’s quotients). Candidate E1 is the first-ranked candidate of party E; her quotient is 33, and therefore, her MV is 23. Notice that the seats won by MPs with small MVs (D2 and E3) could have been easily lost to another candidate if the vote distribution changed even slightly (as demonstrated in Panels 2 and 3). In our analyses, in addition to using the whole sample of MPs, we employ the subsample of MPs who won by small margins in order to identify the impact of a candidate’s rank on the probability of party switching. In addition, in some specifications, we use the Margin of Victory as an (inverse) measure of electoral uncertainty faced by politicians.

Appendix 2: Distribution of Party Switchers by Party Over Time

Tables 10 and 11

Table 10 The change in parties’ seats in the parliament by parliamentary term
Table 11 The number of MPs and party switchers by parliamentary term in the Grand National Assembly of Turkey

Appendix 3: Discussion of the Estimates of the Control Variables in Table 2 of the Main Text

Personal Attributes of the MP

The estimated impact of MP characteristics on the propensity to switch parties is listed in panel B of Table 2 in the main text. The variable, titled “Relative Salary,” is the ratio of real MP salary to the per capita income in the province from which the MP was elected. MP salaries are periodically adjusted upwards by the Parliament, and there is variation in per capita income between cities. Thus, Relative Salary varies both over time and between cities. Table 2 of the main text shows that an increase in MP salaries in comparison to per capita income has a positive impact on the propensity to switch parties, likely because an increase in salary makes the MP’s post more attractive.

Members of the Parliament who are also members of the cabinet are less likely to switch to another party. Arguably, this is because Cabinet Members have access to government resources, and defecting from their current party may reduce opportunities to obtain governmental pork (Desposato 2006). Those who are elected multiple times from the same party (and have not switched parties) are more likely to be loyal to the party. The coefficient of Elected from the Same Party Before is negative and significant in all specifications, but omitting this variable, which captures party loyalty, had no impact on other coefficients. Freshman parliamentarians are less likely to switch parties. These MPs are elected to the parliament for the first time, and presumably because of this, they did not have enough time to network and make connections with competing parties to be able to switch their party affiliation.

In Table 2, the coefficient of the variable Influence of the MP is about -0.016. This result suggests that a one standard deviation increase in an MP’s influence reduces his/her probability of switching parties by 1.7 percentage points. This is probably because for those MPs with strong influence on other members of their party, party switching is more costly, in that defection from their party involves giving up their sway over other members. The coefficient of Effort of the MP is positive but insignificant in Table 2.

Members of the Parliament who were 50 years of age or older when they were elected are less likely to switch parties. This could be because it may not pay off to switch parties and start off anew at a different party when the time left until retirement is shorter. This finding is consistent with Alesina et al. (2015). In Appendix 3 Table 12, we present a more detailed investigation of the effect of MP’s age. Our results suggest that the effect of age on the probability of party switching is monotonic. In addition, we find that the effect of election uncertainty has a statistically significant impact on party switching in the sample of younger MPs, while older MPs do not respond to election uncertainty. Female MPs are more likely to switch to another party. Those MPs who have received a college or graduate degree outside Turkey (School Abroad) are less likely to switch parties. To receive a college degree abroad could be an indicator of wealth or superior academic performance in high school. MPs who obtained a degree abroad are more likely to be a member of a wealthy families compared to MPs who went to college in Turkey because attending school abroad is more expensive compared to obtaining a degree in the country. Alternatively, an MP could obtain a degree abroad with the support of a scholarship thanks to their superior academic performance in school. In either case, wealthy or academically successful MPs have better outside options in the labor market. Having a graduate degree (MA/PhD) does not significantly influence the probability of party switching. However, our analysis, presented in Appendix 3 Table 13, suggests that MPs who don’t hold graduate degrees respond more strongly to election uncertainty. Specifically, election uncertainty faced by the MP has a statistically significant effect on party switching in the sample of MPs who do not have graduate degrees but not in the sample of MPs who have MA or Ph.D. degrees. Conditioning on the MPs’ area of study or their universities’ quality does not change this finding. The quality of MP’s university, as measured by the selectiveness of the colleges, reduces the probability of party switching in the sample of MPs who do not have a graduate degree. These results are presented in Appendix 3 Table 13. In addition, Appendix 3 Fig. 2 shows that the impact of Ranked 2nd or Lower on the probability of party switching is greater when the university quality of the MP is smaller.

Table 12 The effect of electoral uncertainty on the probability of party switching by MP’s age
Table 13 The effect of electoral uncertainty on the probability of party switching by MP’s education conditional on MP’s area of study and university quality

An interesting result in Table 2 of the main text is the impact of Member of the Government Party. This variable takes the value of one if the MP’s party is the governing party in the Parliament, either as the majority party or as part of a coalition government. The results show that if MP is a member of the majority (the governing party), then his/her probability of switching parties is seven percentage points larger.Footnote 18 This is likely because it is a more attractive proposition for the MP to transfer to another party if he/she is a member of the majority party because such a move weakens the government and strengthens the opposition. As an extension, we investigated whether the impact is larger when the margin of the majority of the government is smaller. Results presented in Appendix 3 Fig. 3 support this idea. Specifically, compared to their counterparts in the opposition parties, members of the parties that formed the government are more likely to switch parties when the majority of the government in the Parliament is smaller.

The Impact of Party and District Attributes

Panel C of Table 2 in the main text shows that, all else the same, MPs are more likely to switch parties after an election if they are members of a party that has a longer existence in politics. On the other hand, if the leader of the party has held that position of leadership for at least ten consecutive years (Single Leader Party = 1), this reduces the propensity to switch parties. This could be because in such parties, the entire leadership team may be more stable, and therefore, they may be more attuned to the rank and file of the party, more effective in dealing with grievances, and reacting more promptly to any attempts to defection from the party.

Panel C of Table 2 of the main text shows that the higher the number of Contested Seats in a District, the lower the likelihood of party switching of an MP who was elected from that district. This result, which indicates that the MPs who are elected from smaller districts are more likely to switch parties after an election, makes sense to the extent that those seats are more valuable to transfer to another party (Figs. 2 and 3).

Fig. 2
figure 2

Effect of election uncertainty by university quality. We estimate a probit regression of the form \(P\left(Party\;Switch\;=\;1\right)=\Phi\;({\beta\;}_{1}Ranked\;2nd\;or\;Lower\;+\;{\beta\;}_{2}Quality+{\beta\;}_{3}Ranked\;2nd\;or\;Lower\times\;Quality\;+\;{{X}}{{{\beta}}}_{4}+\varepsilon\;)\) where \(Quality\) is the average university entrance exam score of the MP’s university. Greater \(Quality\) implies a more selective university. The solid connected line represents the marginal effect of \(Ranked 2nd or Lower\) evaluated at various \(Quality\) levels. Dashed lines are two standard error confidence intervals

Fig. 3
figure 3

The effect of being a member of the government party on party switching (by the strength of the government). The figure presents the effect of Member of the Government Party on the probability of Party Switch = 1. To obtain these marginal effects, we first run a probit regression same as the specifications in Table 2 in the main text with the following exceptions: 1. Among the controls, we include a new variable, No. Seats above Majority, which is constructed as the number of seats the governmental parties have in the Parliament at the beginning of the term minus half of the seats in the Parliament. We also include the interaction of No. Seats above Majority with Member of the Government Party. 2. We exclude Parliamentary term dummies. The connected line represents the marginal effects of Member of the Government Party evaluated at several values of No. Seats above Majority. Dashed lines represent two standard deviation confidence intervals. The confidence intervals start to contain zero after No. Seats above Majority = 50

Appendix 4: Sensitivity Checks

Tables 14, 15, and 16

Table 14 The effect of electoral uncertainty on the probability of party switching and being independent marginal effects from multinomial logit
Table 15 The effect of electoral uncertainty on the probability of remaining independent conditional on leaving the original party after the election
Table 16 Covariate balance in the matched and unmatched samples

Appendix 5: The Impact of Party Switching on the Electoral Success of the Destination Party

The results of Table 7 of the main text indicate that party switching MPs have slightly higher chances of re-election. While this finding explains why MPs switch parties, it seems to go against the prediction that voters would reprimand dishonest politicians by not re-electing them. It should be remembered, however, that in this electoral system, voters cast votes for the entire party ticket. In other words, even if voters are uncomfortable with having a politician on their party’s ticket who was elected to the Parliament in the previous election from another party, voters may still cast their votes for their party because the utility of their party sending more MPs to the Parliament may outweigh the disutility of electing the dishonest party-switcher.

To shed more light on this issue, we also analyze how a party’s election success in a district is impacted by having on the ticket an MP who was transferred from another party. In these regressions, the unit of observation is a province-election-party. Specifically, consider Eq. (6) below:

$${{\%\;Vote\;in\;District}_{pct} = \gamma {\;\%National\;Vote}_{pt} +\theta {Gov{'}tParty}_{pt}+{\lambda }_{c}+{\pi }_{t}+{\xi }_{p}+{\upsilon }_{pct} }$$
(6)

where the proportion of votes received by the party (p) in the province (c) in an election year (t) is depicted by %Vote in Districtpct, which is a function of the nation-wide success of the party (% National Votept) and whether the party entered the election as the Governing Party (Gov’t Partypt). The political sentiment in the province, which impacts the number of votes received by the party, is captured by province fixed effects λc. Election year fixed-effects are captured by πt, and party fixed-effects are represented ξp.

Writing Eq. (6) for the next election year t + 1 and taking the first differences, we estimate Eq. (7) below:

$${\Delta\;\%Vote\;in\;District}_{pct}={\gamma\;\Delta\;\% National\;Vote}_{pt} +{\theta\;\Delta\;Gov'tParty}_{pt}+{ \varphi\;MPs\;Gained}_{pct}+{\delta }_{t}+{\mu }_{c}+{\tau }_{p}+{u}_{pct}$$
(7)

where Δ stands for the change in the relevant variable between the two consecutive elections.Footnote 19 Although district fixed-effects and party fixed-effects drop out from eq. (7), we nevertheless keep them to absorb any unobserved residual variation. In eq. (7), the variable MPs Gainedpct stands for the number of MPs who switched to party (p) from other parties between the two elections and are now nominated from the party (p). Thus, we analyze how the vote share of the party (p) changes from one election to another and whether this change is impacted by whether or not the party’s ticket in that election in that province contains an MP who was transferred from another party.

The results are reported in Appendix 5 Table 17. The key variable is MPs Gained, which stands for the number of MPs who switched to the party from another party during the parliamentary term just ended. The results show that if the party’s ticket contains an MP who is transferred from another party, then the proportion of votes received by that party in that province goes up by about two percentage points. This means that in a province with 100,000 voters, the party has received 2,000 more votes (in comparison to the previous election) because of the transfer of the MP from another party.

Table 17 The Change in the proportion of votes received by parties (in consecutive elections)

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Mocan, N., Altindag, D.T. Mobile Politicians: Opportunistic Career Moves. J Labor Res 45, 58–110 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12122-024-09353-0

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12122-024-09353-0

Keywords

Navigation