Skip to main content
Log in

Electoral cycles in MPs’ salaries: evidence from the German states

  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Members of parliament (MPs) often set their own salaries. Voters dislike self-serving politicians, and politicians are keen to please voters. In line with political business cycle theories, politicians thus may delay giving themselves a salary increase until after elections. We investigate electoral cycles in the salary increases of German state MPs. Using data for 15 states over the period 1980–2014, we find no evidence that increases in MP salaries are influenced by election cycles. Politicians can increase their salaries at any point during the legislative period without negative consequences. We posit that this may be because even those voters who are most disenchanted with politics likely understand that all politicians benefit from a salary increase and thus do not punish the governing party at the polls.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Source: Own illustration

Fig. 2

Source: Own illustration

Fig. 3

Source: Own illustration

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. On the importance of recognizing political rent seeking in the analysis of public policy, see Hillman and Ursprung (2016). An example for rent extraction is employing a spouse; see Kauder and Potrafke (2015, 2016).

  2. A survey among citizens in 2007 showed that 46% of the citizens think that MP salaries are too high, while only 4% believe that they are too low compared to top-level executives (Welt online; see https://www.welt.de/politik/article1475841/Buerger-glauben-dass-Politiker-genug-verdienen.html).

  3. We used Google Trends to examine search requests in the German states over the period 2004–2014. We calculated for each state the average value for search requests on MP salary increases in months where a decision on salary increases in the individual state took place, and the average value for the other months.

  4. Salaries, of course, are only one part of politicians’ remuneration (see Arnim 1998, 2010); however, increases in other parts (such as pensions) are less visible and thus may be less likely to show electoral effects.

  5. On political budget cycles in the European Union, see Efthyvoulou (2011); on political budget cycles in a larger set of countries, see Haan and Klomp (2013) and Klomp and Haan (2013). Kneebone and McKenzie (2001), Katsimi and Sarantides (2012), Bove et al. (2017), Köppl-Turyna et al. (2016), and Castro and Martins (2016) investigate how elections and Tsai (2016) how the timing of the National Congress of the Communist Party in China influence budget composition. Osterloh (2012) and Potrafke (2012a) examine how elections influence economic performance. Incumbents increase the growth in public health expenditures and engage in creative accounting before elections (Potrafke 2010; Herwartz and Theilen 2014; Reischmann 2016). Foreign reserves in democracies tend to be lower before elections (Jäger 2016). Transparency may mitigate political budget cycles (Benito and Bastida 2009). On public investment and reelection prospects, see Katsimi and Sarantides (2015).

  6. On electoral cycles in other federal states such as the USA, see, for example, Cahan (2017). In federal states, the welfare costs of political budget cycles at the state level may be reduced by using federal fiscal transfers (Aronsson and Granlund 2017).

  7. In the UK, elections influence MPs’ outside activities (Geys 2013). In the USA, bureaucrats’ salaries increase more in election years (Borjas 1984). See Vadlamannati (2015) on electoral cycles and anti-corruption policies. Political cycles may be influenced by term limits (Klein and Sakurai 2015; Dalle Nogare and Kauder 2017) and globalization (Efthyvoulou 2011).

  8. Holding political office may also give rise to private returns (Eggers and Hainmueller 2009; Querubin and Snyder 2013; Fisman et al. 2014; Kotakorpi et al. 2015), which may, in turn, influence parliamentary effort (Gagliarducci et al. 2010; Arnold et al. 2014; Geys and Mause 2016; for a survey on moonlighting politicians, see Geys and Mause 2013). See Peichl et al. (2013) on differences between the salaries of politicians and those of private-sector executives in Germany; Elliott et al. (2005) compare public- and private-sector pay in the UK. Voters’ education and US governors’ salaries have been shown to be negatively correlated (Mirhosseini 2016).

  9. See Weichold (2001) on the historical development of how MP salaries are set. Gersbach (2009) examines how welfare is affected when candidates offer their individual salaries competitively.

  10. There were 14 salary increases above 20% during 1980–2014. In a part-time parliament, politicians may well work in addition to their parliamentary function. In a full-time parliament, the parliamentary function is full-time and other professional activities are possible only to a limited extent.

  11. In some cases, salaries were not increased. To define the dates on which these pay freezes were decided on, we use the average day on which increases in salaries were decided on in other years in the respective state. In our sample, we defined 172 artificial dates for the pay freezes.

  12. Note that we only consider the salary increases closest to the election when there was more than one increase in the 365 days after or before an election. In the case of early elections, we consider an increase in salaries only as belonging to the pre-election period when early elections were known at that point of time.

  13. In the case of early elections, we consider the regular length of a legislative period when salaries were increased before early elections were called, and the actual length when salaries were increased after early elections were called.

  14. By excluding fixed state effects, the continuous time variable is positive and statistically significant at the 10% level.

  15. A t test on means shows that neither post-election nor pre-election increases are significantly different from positive increases at other times.

References

  • Arnold, F., Kauder, B., & Potrafke, N. (2014). Outside earnings, absence, and activity: Evidence from German parliamentarians. European Journal of Political Economy, 36, 147–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aronsson, T., & Granlund, D. (2017). Federal subsidization of state expenditure to reduce political budget cycles. International Tax and Public Finance, 24, 536–545.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benito, B., & Bastida, F. (2009). Budget transparency, fiscal performance, and political turnout: An international approach. Public Administration Review, 69, 403–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benito, B., Bastida, F., Ríos, A.-M., & Vicente, C. (2014). The causes of legal rents extraction: Evidence from Spanish municipalities. Public Choice, 161, 367–383.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, H., & Woitek, U. (1997). Searching for political business cycles in Germany. Public Choice, 91, 179–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T. (2004). Paying politicians: Theory and evidence. Journal of the European Economic Association, 2, 193–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boone, C., Dube, A., & Kaplan, E. (2014). The political economy of discretionary spending: Evidence from the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring, 2014, 375–441.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bordignon, M., Gamalerio, M., & Turati, G. (2013). Decentralization, vertical fiscal imbalance, and political selection, CESifo Working Paper 4459.

  • Borjas, G. (1984). Electoral cycles and the earnings of federal bureaucrats. Economic Inquiry, 22, 447–459.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bove, V., Efthyvoulou, G., & Navas, A. (2017). Political cycles in public expenditure: Butter versus guns. Journal of Comparative Economics, 45, 582–604.

  • Braendle, T. (2015). Does remuneration affect the discipline and the selection of politicians? Evidence from pay harmonization in the European Parliament. Public Choice, 162, 1–24.

  • Braendle, T. (2016). Do institutions affect citizens’ selection into politics? Journal of Economic Surveys, 30, 205–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cahan, D. (2017). Electoral cycles in government employment: Evidence from US gubernatorial elections, UCSD Working Paper.

  • Caselli, F., & Morelli, M. (2004). Bad politicians. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 759–782.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Castro, V. & Martins, R. (2016). Politically driven cycles in fiscal policy: In depth analysis of the functional components of government expenditures, NIPE Working Paper 02.

  • Dalle Nogare, C., & Kauder, B. (2017). Term limits for mayors and intergovernmental grants: Evidence from Italian cities. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 64, 1–11.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Haan, J., & Klomp, J. (2013). Conditional political budget cycles: A review of recent evidence. Public Choice, 157, 387–410.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Tella, R., & Fisman, R. (2004). Are politicians really paid like bureaucrats? Journal of Law and Economics, 47, 477–513.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Efthyvoulou, G. (2011). Political cycles under external economic constraints: Evidence from Cyprus. Journal of Economics and Business, 63, 638–662.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Efthyvoulou, G. (2012). Political budget cycles in the European Union and the impact of political pressures. Public Choice, 153, 295–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eggers, A. C., & Hainmueller, J. (2009). MPs for sale? Returns to office in postwar British politics. American Political Science Review, 103, 513–533.

  • Elliott, R. F., Bell, D., Scott, A., Ma, A., & Roberts, E. (2005). Devolved government and public sector pay reform: Considerations of equity and efficiency. Regional Studies, 39, 519–539.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferraz, C. & Finan, F. (2009). Motivating politicians: The impacts of monetary incentives on quality and performance, NBER Working Paper No. 14906.

  • Fisman, R., Harmon, N., Kamenica, E., & Munk, I. (2015). Labor supply of politicians. Journal of the European Economic Association, 13, 871–905.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisman, R., Schulz, F., & Vig, V. (2014). The private returns to public office. Journal of Political Economy, 122, 806–862.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foremny, D., Freier, R., Moessinger, M.-D., & Yeter, M. (2014). Overlapping political budget cycles in the legislative and the executive, ZEW Discussion Paper 14-099.

  • Foremny, D., & Riedel, N. (2014). Business taxes and the electoral cycle. Journal of Public Economics, 115, 48–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gagliarducci, S., & Nannicini, T. (2013). Do better paid politicians perform better? Disentangling incentives from selection. Journal of the European Economic Association, 11, 369–398.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gagliarducci, S., Nannicini, T., & Naticchioni, P. (2010). Moonlighting politicians. Journal of Public Economics, 94, 688–699.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garmann, S. (2017). Electoral cycles in public administration decisions: Evidence from German municipalities. Regional Studies, 51, 712–723.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gersbach, H. (2009). Competition of politicians for wages and office. Social Choice and Welfare, 33, 51–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geys, B. (2013). Election cycles in MPs’ outside interests? The UK House of Commons, 2005–2010. Political Studies, 61, 462–472.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geys, B., & Mause, K. (2013). Moonlighting politicians: A survey and research agenda. Journal of Legislative Studies, 19, 76–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geys, B., & Mause, K. (2016). The limits of electoral control: Evidence from last-term politicians. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 41, 873–898.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herwartz, H., & Theilen, B. (2014). Health care and ideology: A reconsideration of political determinants of public healthcare funding in the OECD. Health Economics, 23, 225–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, A. L. (2015). Rent seeking as political economy. In R. D. Congleton & A. L. Hillman (Eds.), Companion to the political economy of rent seeking (pp. 10–16). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, A. L., & Ursprung, H. W. (2016). Where are the rent seekers? Constitutional Political Economy, 27(2), 124–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huber, P. J. (1967). The behavior of maximum likelihood estimates under nonstandard conditions. In Proceedings of the fifth Berkeley symposium on mathematical statistics and probability (pp. 221–233).

  • Jäger, K. (2016). The role of regime type in the political economy of foreign reserve accumulation. European Journal of Political Economy, 44, 79–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katsimi, M., & Sarantides, V. (2012). Do elections affect the composition of fiscal policy in developed, established democracies? Public Choice, 151, 325–362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katsimi, M., & Sarantides, V. (2015). Public investment and reelection prospects in developed countries. Southern Economic Journal, 82, 471–500.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kauder, B., & Potrafke, N. (2013). Government ideology and tuition fee policy: Evidence from the German states. CESifo Economic Studies, 29, 628–649.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kauder, B., & Potrafke, N. (2015). Just hire your spouse! Evidence from a political scandal in Bavaria. European Journal of Political Economy, 38, 42–54.

  • Kauder, B., & Potrafke, N. (2016). Supermajorities and political rent extraction. Kyklos, 68, 65–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kauder, B., Potrafke, N., & Schinke, C. (2017). Manipulating fiscal forecasts: Evidence from the German states. FinanzArchiv/Public Finance Analysis, 73, 213–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keane, M. P., & Merlo, A. (2010). Money, political ambition, and the career decisions of politicians. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 2, 186–215.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein, F. A., & Sakurai, S. N. (2015). Term limits and political budget cycles at the local level: Evidence from a young democracy. European Journal of Political Economy, 37, 21–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klomp, J., & de Haan, J. (2013). Political budget cycles and election outcomes. Public Choice, 157, 245–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kneebone, R. D., & McKenzie, K. J. (2001). Electoral and partisan cycles in fiscal policy: An examination of Canadian provinces. International Tax and Public Finance, 8, 753–774.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Köppl-Turyna, M., Kula, G., Balmas, A., & Waclawska, K. (2016). The effects of fiscal decentralization on the strength of political budget cycles in local expenditure. Local Government Studies, 42, 785–820.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kotakorpi, K., Poutvaara, P., & Terviö, M. (2015). Returns to office in national and local politics (unpublished paper).

  • Kotakorpi, K., & Poutvaara, P. (2011). Pay for politicians and candidate selection: An empirical analysis. Journal of Public Economics, 95, 877–885.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matschke, X. (2003). Are there election cycles in wage agreements? An analysis of German public employees. Public Choice, 114, 103–135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mattozzi, A., & Merlo, A. (2008). Political careers or career politicians? Journal of Public Economics, 92, 597–608.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mause, K. (2014). Self-serving legislators? An analysis of the salary-setting institutions of 27 EU parliaments. Constitutional Political Economy, 25, 154–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mechtel, M., & Potrafke, N. (2013). Electoral cycles in active labor market policies. Public Choice, 156, 181–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Messner, M., & Polborn, M. K. (2004). Paying politicians. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 2423–2445.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mirhosseini, M. R. (2016). Optimal wages for politicians. Southern Economic Journal, 82, 1004–1020.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mocan, N., & Altindag, D. T. (2013). Salaries and work effort: An analysis of the European Union parliamentarians. Economic Journal, 123, 1130–1167.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W. D. (1975). The political business cycle. Review of Economic Studies, 42, 169–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Osterloh, S. (2012). Words speak louder than actions: The impact of politics on economic performance. Journal of Comparative Economics, 40, 318–336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peichl, A., Pestel, N., & Siegloch, S. (2013). The politicians’ wage gap: Insights from German members of parliament. Public Choice, 156, 653–676.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Potrafke, N. (2010). The growth of public health expenditures in OECD countries: Do government ideology and electoral motives matter? Journal of Health Economics, 29, 797–810.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Potrafke, N. (2012a). Political cycles and economic performance in OECD countries: Empirical evidence from 1951–2006. Public Choice, 150, 155–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Potrafke, N. (2012b). Is German domestic social policy politically controversial? Public Choice, 153, 393–418.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Potrafke, N., Riem, M., & Schinke, C. (2016). Debt brakes in the German states: Governments’ rhetoric and actions. German Economic Review, 17, 253–275.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Querubin, P., & Snyder, J. M, Jr. (2013). The control of politicians in normal times and times of crisis: Wealth accumulation by U.S. congressmen, 1850–1880. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 8, 409–450.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reischmann, M. (2016). Creative accounting and electoral motives: Evidence from OECD countries. Journal of Comparative Economics, 44, 243–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riem, M. (2016a). Corporate investment decisions under political uncertainty, Ifo Working Paper 221.

  • Riem, M. (2016b). Does political uncertainty influence firm owners’ business perceptions? Ifo Working Paper 226.

  • Rogoff, K., & Sibert, A. (1988). Elections and macroeconomic policy cycles. Review of Economic Studies, 55, 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider, C. (2010). Fighting with one hand tied behind the back: Political budget cycles in the West German states. Public Choice, 142, 125–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svaleryd, H., & Vlachos, J. (2009). Political rents in a non-corrupt democracy. Journal of Public Economics, 93, 355–372.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tepe, M., & Vanhuysse, P. (2009). Educational business cycles. Public Choice, 139, 61–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tepe, M., & Vanhuysse, P. (2013). Cops for hire? The political economy of police employment in the German states. Journal of Public Policy, 33, 165–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tepe, M., & Vanhuysse, P. (2014). A vote at the opera? The political economy of public theaters and orchestras in the German states. European Journal of Political Economy, 36, 254–273.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsai, P.-H. (2016). Fiscal incentives and political budget cycles in China. International Tax and Public Finance, 23, 1030–1073.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vadlamannati, K. C. (2015). Fighting corruption or elections? The politics of anti-corruption policies in India: A subnational study. Journal of Comparative Economics, 43, 1035–1052.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Arnim, H. H. (1975). Abgeordnetenentschädigung und Grundgesetz. Wiesbaden: Karl-Bräuer-Institut des Bundes der Steuerzahler.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Arnim, H. H. (1998). Diener vieler Herren - Die Doppel- und Dreifachversorgung von Politikern. München: Knaur.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Arnim, H. H. (2010). Die Privilegien von Landespolitikern. Zeitschrift für Rechtspolitik, 43, 56–57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weichold, J. (2001). Der Abgeordnete und die Diäten. Zum verfassungsrechtlichen Problem der “angemessenen”, die “Unabhängigkeit” des Abgeordneten sichernden Entschädigung. UTOPIE kreativ, 125, 232–241.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, H. (1980). A heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for heteroskedasticity. Econometrica, 48, 817–838.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Hans Herbert von Arnim, Sutirtha Bagchi, Frank Bohn, Paul Hufe, Stephan Michel, seminar/conference participants at the Public Choice Society’s Annual Meeting (Fort Lauderdale 2016), the Spring Meeting of Young Economists (Lisbon 2016), the Meeting of the Association for Public Economic Theory (Rio de Janeiro 2016), the Annual Congress of the International Institute of Public Finance (Lake Tahoe 2016), the Annual Conference of the European Association of Law and Economics (Bologna 2016), the European Public Choice Society’s Annual Meeting (Budapest 2017), the Annual Conference of the Canadian Economic Association (Antigonish 2017), the University of Munich, and the Ifo Institute, and an anonymous referee for their helpful comments, and Lisa Giani Contini and Deborah Willow for proofreading. Kristin Fischer, Felix Hugger, Adam Job, Benedikt Kauf, Antonia Kremheller, Sebastian Kropp, Luisa Lorenz, Julia Richenhagen, Leonard Thielmann, and Johanna Wietschel provided excellent research assistance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Björn Kauder.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kauder, B., Krause, M. & Potrafke, N. Electoral cycles in MPs’ salaries: evidence from the German states. Int Tax Public Finance 25, 981–1000 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-017-9479-7

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-017-9479-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation