Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The Negligence Rule in the Presence of Judicial Corruption and Social Norms

  • Published:
Atlantic Economic Journal Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates the phenomenon of judicial corruption and incorporates it into Polinsky, A. M. (1980). Strict liability vs. negligence in a market setting. American Economic Review, 70, 363–367 framework so as to analyze the efficiency of the negligence rule. By shedding light on the role of social norms in regard to the phenomenon of judicial corruption, this analysis provides implications for policy. First, more prevalent corruption at the status quo tends to intensify the extent of the corruption itself and, as a result, the effectiveness of the government’s corruption enforcement is greatly lessened. This implies that an excessively lenient policy of corruption may result in an uncontrollable consequence; once corruption becomes rampant, it is costly to bring it down. Of great importance, in the presence of such a corruption effect, the social optimum cannot be achieved based on the negligence rule and the equivalence between the strict liability and negligence rule fails. Secondly, the attitude of the society toward a corrupt judge plays a crucial role in governing the effectiveness of an efficient wage arrangement. If the society can fully accept a corrupt judge, corruption will never be controlled even with the incentive wage scheme.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This idea, in effect, can be traced back to Becker and Stigler (1974). They claim that “[t]he fundamental answer is to raise the salaries of enforcers above what they could get elsewhere.... A difference in salaries imposes a cost of dismissal....” (Becker and Stigler 1974, p. 6)

  2. We specify θ > 1 in order to have an increasing psychological cost.

  3. We assume that μ is public information due to sufficient social interactions among the judges. It is consistent with a study by Geanakoplos et al. (1989) in which a psychological equilibrium requires not only the Nash equilibrium property, but also the correct expectations of all players in equilibrium.

  4. According to Posner (1983), the psychological cost arising from delinquent activity includes two parts: one is the guilt cost which is incurred even if the delinquency is not deterred, and the other is the shame of getting caught. As is evident, this model takes the guilt cost into account and ignores the possible shame effect. However, my main results are not altered even if the latter effect is considered as well.

  5. The second-order condition \( \frac{{d^{2} X}} {{dZ^{2} }} = D + \frac{{\partial Y}} {{\partial Z}} > 0 \) is assumed to be satisfied.

  6. Lambsdorff (2002) discusses various corruption agreements by shedding light on the transaction costs, including the costs of determining contract conditions and enforcing contract terms.

References

  • Akerlof, G. A. (1980). A theory of social custom, of which unemployment may be one consequence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 94, 749–775.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S., & Stigler, G. (1974). Law enforcement, malfeasance, and compensation of enforcers. Journal of Legal Studies, 3, 1–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benson, B. L. (1988). Corruption in law enforcement: One consequence of “the tragedy of the commons” arising with public allocation processes. International Review of Law and Economics, 8, 73–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., & McLaren, J. (1993). Taxes and bribery: The role of wage incentives. Economic Journal, 103, 119–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Booth, A. L. (1985). The free rider problem and a social custom model of trade union membership. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100, 253–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, D. T. (1982). Legal and primary-group social controls. Journal of Social and Biological Structures, 5, 431–438.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cho, J., & Kim, I. (2001). Jobs in the bureaucratic afterlife: A corruption-facilitating mechanism associated with law enforcement. Southern Economic Journal, 68, 330–348.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Commonwealth (1994) July 1, 22–52.

  • De Soto, H. (1989). The other path: The invisible revolution in the third world. New York: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elster, J. (1989). Social norms and economic theory. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3, 99–117.

    Google Scholar 

  • Esfahani, H. S. (1996). The political economy of the telecommunications sector in the Philippines. In B. Levy & P. Spiller (Eds.), Regulations, institutions, and commitment: Comparative studies of telecommunications. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geanakoplos, J., Pearce, D., & Stacchetti, E. (1989). Psychological games and sequential rationality. Journal of Games and Economic Behavior, 1, 60–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hollander, H. (1990). A social exchange approach to voluntary cooperation. American Economic Review, 80, 1157–1167.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmes, L. (1993). The end of communist power: Anti-corruption campaigns and legitimation crisis. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang, P. H., & Wu, H. M. (1994). More order without more law: A theory of social norms and organizational cultures. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 10, 390–406.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kramer, J. M. (1995). Political corruption in postcommunist Russia. Eurasian Report, 13–26.

  • Laffont, J. J., & Tirole, J. (1993). A Theory of incentives in procurement and regulation. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lambsdorff, J. G. (2002). Making corrupt deals: Contracting in the shadow of the law. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 48, 221–241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mookherjee, D., & P’ng, I. P. L. (1995). Corruption law enforcement: How should they be compensated? Economic Journal, 105, 145–159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mui, V. L. (1999). Contracting in the shadow of a corrupt court. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 155, 249–283.

    Google Scholar 

  • Naylor, R. (1989). Strikes, free riders, and social custom. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104, 771–785.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polinsky, A. M. (1980). Strict liability vs. negligence in a market setting. American Economic Review, 70, 363–367.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R. A. (1983). The economic theory of justice. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R. A. (1997). Social norms and the law: An economics approach. AEA Papers and Proceedings, 87, 365–369.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, T. C. (1978). The micromotives of macrobehavior. New York: W.W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro, C., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1984). Equilibrium unemployment as a worker discipline device. American Economic Review, 74, 433–444.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tajfel, H. (1982). Social psychology of intergroup relations. Annual Review of Psychology, 33, 1–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to the anonymous referee for helpful comments and suggestions. Any remaining shortcomings are our own responsibility.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Juin-jen Chang.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Chang, Jj., Liu, Cy. The Negligence Rule in the Presence of Judicial Corruption and Social Norms. Atl Econ J 35, 203–215 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11293-007-9068-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11293-007-9068-8

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation