Skip to main content
Log in

Regulation, competition, and the social control of business

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In George Stigler’s (1971) economic theory of regulation, the primary motive of regulatory intervention is the promotion of private interests, not the promotion of the general welfare or efficiency as suggested by the public interest theory of regulation (Pigou 1932). More recently, Andrei Shleifer (2010, 2012) along with some coauthors (Glaeser & Shleifer 2003; Djankov et al. 2003) has proposed an alternative to Stigler’s theory, which he calls the enforcement theory of regulation. Shleifer’s new theory of regulation holds that the rise of regulatory institutions over the course of the twentieth century is in fact efficient and providing the requisite social control of business, largely because the alternative judicial mechanism is so inefficient and costly. Contrary to Shleifer, we argue here that because both courts and regulation are subject to ex-post defection, individual bias, and subversion, neither is categorically preferable. Whether or not courts or regulation are more efficient at providing social control of business ultimately depends on the features of the specific regulatory or judicial institutions as well as the economic problem addressed. Institutional environments differ with respect to the severity of knowledge and incentive problems and mechanisms for overcoming them that are built into them. The comparative efficiency of an institutional solution depends more on its institutional features (centralized/decentralized, contested/uncontested) than its form (regulation, courts, or private orderings). Stigler’s (1971) contribution acknowledges that concern implicitly by incorporating competition between different interest groups as the essential mechanisms driving regulatory outcomes.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Shleifer (2012, p. 40): “the case for efficient regulation rests on that against efficient courts.”.

  2. Elinor Ostrom’s (1990) work has distilled the importance of eight institutional design principles for the proper functioning of self-governing institutions to overcome common pool resource problems. Her work highlights the importance of the specific features of institutions for their success or failure.

  3. In the context of his discussion of Tullock’s case against the common law, Shughart (2018, p. 222) suggests that “although the origins and evolutions of common-law and civil-law traditions differ considerably, especially with respect to norms of judicial discretion, judges are part of the political process (Tullock 1997, p. 15) and are perhaps subservient to it in both legal regimes.” While he does not elaborate on this point, the observation that all judges (in both civil and common law systems) are subject to political pressure is related to the argument we are advancing here, i.e., all institutions are subject to attempts at rent-seeking and ex-post subversion; it thus is not the institutional form but particular institutional features that will make institutional frameworks more robust and resilient to politicization.

  4. Note that Medema (2014) suggests that Pigou himself had an account of government failure that in many ways anticipated the public choice revolution.

  5. This part of Shleifer’s argument is somewhat surprising considering some of his other work with Djankov et al., (2002, p. 1), which finds that more heavily regulated countries also tend to be more corrupt, featuring large unofficial economies without “better quality of public or private goods.”.

  6. Maybe surprisingly, one of the founders of the public choice perspective, Gordon Tullock, is famous for arguing against the common law and in favor of a legal system based on a civil code. His preference rests on the idea that common law courts are rife with error (Tullock 1980, 1987, 1997). Recently, Shughart (2018) suggests, however, that Tullock’s argument against the common law is based on limited empirical evidence and ignores some of Tullock’s own insights regarding the operation of bureaucratic agencies.

  7. One important contribution to the literature on courts accounting for the public choice perspective is Fuller (1978). Fuller argues that courts are likely to produce inefficient outcomes because they are, by nature, limited in the number of perspectives that can be represented in any particular case. For issues that are polycentric in nature, markets or legislation therefore will provide more robust solutions, because they can accommodate a wider variety of interests that may not otherwise be represented in courts.

  8. In the same vein, Aghion et al. (2021) show that regulation stifles innovation.

  9. Piano (2019) makes a related contribution to the literature on state capacity. He points out that an important missing element in the state capacity literature is competition. In short, the literature suggests that economic development is the result of a state with sufficient fiscal capacity to finance public goods production (Besley and Persson 2009; Johnson and Koyama 2017). The overarching insight of the state capacity literature is that states with high levels of capacity also tend to be economically wealthy (i.e., high taxes and regulation are complements to economic development). Piano (2019) set up a dichotomy between those institutions that develop to provide more attractive environments for capital investment on the one hand and those that specialize in capturing rents on the other. He suggests that competition between states is an effective check on the tendency of states with greater fiscal capacity to abuse their power for the purposes of rent extraction. That line or reasoning is like the argument we are making here, which is that competition between jurisdictions (extramural) or between groups inside a jurisdiction (intramural) can curb rent seeking.

  10. Several other contributions build on Ekelund and Tollison (1982) by incorporating and elaborating on the insight that competition between jurisdictions or internal to a jurisdiction can keep the rent-seeking society at bay. See, for example, Nye (1997, 2007, 2009) and Moberg & Tarko (2021).

  11. Koppl (1992, p. 307) uses the term “extramural” in his discussion of type-two invisible hand explanations and specifically Hayek’s contribution to the literature on institutional evolution: “Says Hayek [1967, p. 71], ‘the selection process of evolution will operate on the system as a whole’. The rules that generate the overall pattern are enforced by an external discipline and not by an internal profit motive.” That description of externally enforced discipline constraining institutional evolution overlaps neatly with our understanding of competition between jurisdictions constraining special interests within a jurisdiction, which is why we adopt the term “extramural” here.

  12. Note that the conclusion is true only if regulatory agencies are either managing a commons or are producing a pure public good. If they are restricting access in an anti-commons type manner or if they are producing a public bad, the more efficient institution is monopoly (see Buchanan & Yoon 2000; Buchanan 1973). Apolte (2001) shows that competition between governments in the provision of public goods can serve as a substitute for constitutional constraints on government. Similarly, Ashworth et al. (2013) illustrate how decentralization functions as a constraint on the size of government.

  13. The example presented in this subsection is taken in large part from Thomas & Thomas (2018).

  14. The story of Cologne’s brewers is based on Diana W. Thomas (2009).

References

  • Aghion, P., Bergeaud, A., & VanReenen, J. (2021). The impact of regulation on innovation. NBER Working Paper: 28381

  • Amin, M., & Ulku, H. (2019). Corruption, regulatory burden and firm productivity. World Bank Policy Research. https://doi.org/10.1596/1813-9450-8911

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Apolte, T. (2001). How tame will Leviathan become in institutional competition? Competition among governments in the provision of public goods. Public Choice, 107(3/4), 359–381.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1950). A difficulty in the concept of social welfare. Journal of Political Economy, 58(4), 328–346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashworth, J., Galli, E., & Padovano, F. (2013). Decentralization as a constraint to Leviathan: A panel cointegration analysis. Public Choice, 156, 491–516.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bailey, J. B., & Thomas, D. W. (2017). Regulating away competition: The effect of regulation on entrepreneurship and employment. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 52, 237–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., & Persson, T. (2009). The origins of state capacity: Property rights, taxation, and politics. American Economic Review, 99(4), 1218–1244.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boudreaux, D. J., & Meiners, R. (2020). Externality: Origins and classifications. Natural Resources Journal, 59(1), 1–34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1973). A defense of organized crime? In S. Rottenberg (Ed.), Economics of crime and punishment (pp. 119–132). American Enterprise Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). [1999]) The calculus of consent: Logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Liberty Fund Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. B., & Yoon, Y. J. (2000). Symmetric tragedies: Commons and anticommons. The Journal of Law and Economics, 43(1), 1–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caplan, B. (2001). Rational ignorance versus rational irrationality. Kyklos, 54(1), 3–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carter, J. R., & Schap, D. (1987). Executive veto, legislative override, ad structure induced equilibrium. Public Choice, 52, 227–244.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coffey, B., McLaughlin, P. A., & Peretto, P. (2020). The cumulative cost of regulations. Review of Economic Dynamics, 38, 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. The Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2002). The regulation of entry. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(1), 1–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Djankov, S., Glaeser, E., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2003). The new comparative economics. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31(4), 595–619.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Djankov, S., McLiesh, C., & Ramalho, R. M. (2006). Regulation and growth. Economics Letters, 92(3), 395–401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of political action in a democracy. Journal of Political Economy, 65(2), 135–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ekelund, R. B., & Tollison, R. D. (1980). Economic regulation in Mercantile England: Heckscher revisited. Economic Inquiry, 18(4), 567–599.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ekelund, R. B., & Tollison, R. D. (1982). Mercantilism as a rent-seeking society: Economic regulation in historical perspective. Texas A&M University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fuller, L. L. (1978). The forms and limits of adjudication. Harvard Law Review, 92(2), 353–409.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gennaioli, N., & Shleifer, A. (2007). The evolution of common law. Journal of Political Economy, 115(1), 43–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gennaioli, N., & Shleifer, A. (2008). Judicial fact discretion. Journal of Legal Studies, 37(1), 1–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser, E., & Shleifer, A. (2003). The rise of the regulatory state. Journal of Economic Literature, 41(2), 401–425.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gutierrez, G., & Philippon, T. (2017). Declining competition and investment in the U.S. NBER Working Paper: 25583.

  • Gutierrez, G., & Philippon, T. (2018). How EU markets became more competitive than US markets: a study of institutional drift. Working Paper. https://fnce.wharton.upenn.edu/wp-content/uploads/2018/10/Phillippon_Europe_v2.5.pdf

  • Gutierrez, G., & Philippon, T. (2019). The failure of free entry. NBER Working Paper: 26001

  • Hirschman, A. O. (1970). Exit, voice, and loyalty: Responses to decline in firms, organization, and states. Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, N. D., & Koyama, M. (2017). States and economic growth: Capacity and constraints. Explorations in Economic History, 64, 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jordan, W. A. (1972). Producer protection, prior market structure and the effects of government regulation. Journal of Law and Economics, 15, 151–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keeler, T. E. (1972). Airline regulation and market performance. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 3(2), 399–424.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kessel, R. A. (1974). Transfused blood, serum hepatitis, and the Coase theorem. Journal of Law and Economics, 17(2), 265–289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1997). Legal determinants of external finance. Journal of Finance, 52(3), 1131–1150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1998). Law and finance. Journal of Political Economy, 106(6), 1113–1155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2008). The economic consequences of legal origins. Journal of Economic Literature, 46(2), 285–332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lipsey, R. G., & Lancaster, K. (1956). The general theory of the second best. The Review of Economic Studies, 24(1), 11–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin, N. P., & Storr, V. (2008). On perverse emergent orders. Studies in Emergent Order, 1(2008), 73–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Medema, S. G. (2014). Economics and institutions: Lessons from the Coase theorem”. Revue Economique, 65(2), 243–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moberg, L., & Tarko, V. (2021). Special economic zones and liberalization avalanches. Journal of Entrepreneurship and Public Policy, 10(1), 120–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moore, T. G. (1976). Trucking regulation: Lessons from Europe. American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moore, T. G. (1978). The beneficiaries of trucking regulation. Journal of Law and Economics, 21(2), 327–343.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moore, T. G. (1986). U.S. airline deregulation: Its effects on passengers, capital, and labor. Journal of Law and Economics, 29, 1–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mulligan, C. B., & Shleifer, A. (2005). The extent of the market and the supply of regulation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(4), 1445–1473.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niblett, A., Posner, R. A., & Shleifer, A. (2010). The evolution of a legal rule. Journal of Legal Studies, 39(2), 325–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, W. A. (1968). The peculiar economics of bureaucracy. The American Economic Review, 58(2), 293–305.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nye, J. V. C. (1997). Thinking about the state: property rights, trade, and changing contractual arrangements in a world with coercion. In J. N. Drobak & J. V. C. Nye (Eds.), Frontiers of the New Institutional Economics. Cambridge, MA: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nye, J. V. C. (2007). War, wine, and taxes: The political economy of Anglo-French trade, 1698–1900. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Nye, J. V.C. 2009. Why do elites permit reform? in The Annual proceedings of the wealth and well-being of nations Chamlee-Wright, E. ed. Beloit, WI: Beloit College Press

  • Olson, M. (1982). Rise and decline of nations: Economic growth, stagflation, and social rigidities. Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, V., Tiebout, C. M., & Warren, R. (1961). The organization of government in metropolitan areas: A theoretical inquiry. The American Political Science Review, 55(4), 831–842.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. The Journal of Law and Economics, 19(2), 211–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1989). The economic theory of regulation after a decade of deregulation. Brookings Papers Microeconomics

  • Peltzman, S. (1993). George Stigler’s contribution to the economic analysis of regulation. Journal of Political Economy, 101(5), 818–832.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piano, E. E. (2019). State capacity and public choice: A critical survey. Public Choice, 178, 289–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pigou, A. C. (1932). The economics of welfare. London: Macmillan (4th edition).

  • Shleifer, A. (2005). Understanding regulation. European Financial Management, 11(4), 439–451.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer, A. (2010). Efficient regulation, in Kessler, D. P. (ed.). Regulation vs. litigation: perspectives from economics and law. Chicago: University of Chicago Press

  • Shleifer, A. (2012). The failure of judges and the rise of regulators. MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shughart, W. F., II. (2018). Gordon Tullock’s critique of the common law. The Independent Review, 23(2), 209–226.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shughart, W. F., II., & Thomas, D. W. (2015). Regulatory rent seeking. In R. D. Congelton & A. L. Hillman (Eds.), Companion to the political economy of rent seeking (pp. 167–186). Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(1), 3–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tabarrok, A., & Helland, E. (1999). Court politics: The political economy of tort awards. The Journal of Law and Economics, 42(1), 157–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tarko, V., & Farrant, A. (2019). The efficiency of regulatory arbitrage. Public Choice, 181(1–2), 141–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, D. W. (2009). Deregulation despite transitional gains: The brewers guild of Cologne 1461. Public Choice, 140, 329–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, D. W., & Thomas, M. D. (2018). The rise of the regulatory state: Institutional entrepreneurship and the decline of markets for blood. The Independent Review, 22(4), 485–506.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, D.W. & Thomas, M.D. (2022). Knowledge and incentive problems in regulatory studies: an Austrian perspective. Forthcoming.

  • Thomas, M. D. (2019). Reapplying behavioral symmetry: Public choice and choice architecture. Public Choice, 180, 11–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tiebout, C. M. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 64(5), 416–424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1980). Trials on trial: The pure theory of legal procedure. Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. [1971] 1987. The logic of the law. Fairfax, VA: George Mason University Press

  • Tullock, G. (1997). The case against the common law Blackstone Commentaries. Fairfax VA: Locke Institute, 1(8), 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. R. (1995). The economic role of political institutions: Market-preserving federalism and economic development. The Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 11(1), 1–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. R., & Marshall, W. J. (1988). The industrial organization of Congress; or, why legislatures, like firms, are not organized as markets. Journal of Political Economy, 96(1), 132–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. R., & Moran, M. J. (1983). Bureaucratic discretion or congressional control: Regulatory policymaking by the Federal Trade Commission. Journal of Political Economy, 91(October), 765–801.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank two anonymous referees for extremely helpful comments and suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Diana W. Thomas.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Thomas, D.W., Thomas, M.D. Regulation, competition, and the social control of business. Public Choice 193, 109–125 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-022-00989-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-022-00989-z

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation