Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Measuring Disparities in Access to Health Care: A Proposal Based on an Ex-ante Perspective

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Social Indicators Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We provide a novel approach to evaluate access to health care based on the monetization of access barriers individuals face. This approach allows to distinguish the opportunities individuals enjoy from their utilization of health services, permitting a better assessment of potential, as opposed to revealed, access. An application to Italian data on heart valve replacement shows that the methodology we provide can be easily applied to quantify the share of the population to which access is precluded and the key determinants of denied access.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Traditionally, the economic literature sees access as depending on supply as well as demand factors (e.g. Mooney 1983). Supply factors affecting access to health care relate to the spatial distribution of providers, the production technology as well as other factors influencing the cost and the appropriateness of health services. Demand factors are generally related to the individual capacity of obtaining and processing the necessary information; the burden of disease; the individual’s skills and attitudes; the diffusion of self-care practices (Andersen 1995). Levesque et al. (2013) outline five dimensions capturing supply as well as demand-side determinants of access to care: approachability, acceptability, availability and accommodation, affordability and appropriateness.

  2. First, even if some inequalities in the health status might be unproblematic (e.g. due to bad lifestyles), health care is a social primary good, whose accessibility is a prerequisite for the exercise of basic rights and liberties (Daniels 1981, 1985); it turns out that, by rewarding lifestyle decisions in the context of health care, one would inevitably jeopardize the liberal principle of equal political and civil rights, because a bad health status would limit individual possibilities to exercise these rights. Second, the principle of responsibility states that individuals should be held responsible for their choices, not for the consequences of their choices; it is only in the special case in which outcomes depend solely (or sensibly) on personal choices (what does not seem to be the case with health) that individuals can be held responsible. As actual consequences of a choice partly depend on factors beyond the individual's control, those who make the same choices may not have the same need for treatment. Forcing only the subset of people in need to pay the cost of irresponsible choices is at the hearth of what might be called a fairness objection (Cappelen and Norheim 2005). In addition to these, a humanitarian argument is also worth mentioning, according to which, any society has a moral obligation to help people in need. Given these objections, one may agree that Roemer’s ideal of levelling the playing field, widely accepted in the literature on income inequality, can be seriously questioned as far as disparities in health or in health care consumption are concerned.

  3. The low no access probability associated with Latina finds an explanation in its low cost of access due to its proximity to Rome (where a health treatment of appropriate quality is provided).

  4. Notice that, although important, our paper does not report the result of the simulation exercise when differences in needs for heart valve replacement at the provincial level are accounted for, since this does not affect the findings in any significant way. Indeed, by proxying the risk of heart valve substitution with data on general cardiovascular risk, we have computed the distribution of the probability of access weighted by the risk. Results remain basically unchanged (the linear correlation between the weighted and non-weighted probabilities is indeed 0.96). Data are available upon request.

  5. We wish to thank one of the reviewers for raising this point.

References

  • Abatemarco, A., Beraldo, S., & Stroffolini, F. (2020). Equality of opportunity in health care: Access and equal access revisited. Interanational Review of Economics, 67(1), 13–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alice. (2011). Indagine ALICe Italia Onlus 2011. Associazione per la Lotta all’Ictus Cerebrale.

  • Allin, S., Masseria, C., Sorenson, C., Papanicolas, I., & Mossialos, E. (2007). Measuring inequalities in access to health care: a review of the indices. Brussels: European Commission.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andersen, R. A. (1995). Revisiting the behavioral model and access to medical care: does it matter? Journal of Health and Social Behavior,36(1), 1–10.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aria, M., Gaeta, G. L., & Marani, U. (2019). Similarities and differences in competitiveness among European NUTS2 regions: an empirical analysis based on 2010–2013 data. Social Indicators Research,142(1), 431–450.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cappelen, A. W., & Norheim, O. F. (2005). Responsibility in health care: A liberal egalitarian approach. Journal of Medical Ethics,31, 476–480.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Culyer, A. J., & Wagstaff, A. (1993). Equity and equality in health and health care. Journal of Health Economics,12(4), 431–457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cylus, J., & Papanicolas, I. (2015). An analysis of perceived access to health care in Europe: how universal is universal coverage? Health Policy,119(9), 1133–1144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daniels, N. (1981). Health-care needs and distributive justice. Philosophy & Public Affairs,10, 146–179.

    Google Scholar 

  • Daniels, N. (1985). Just health care. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Daniels, N. (2013). Justice and access to health care. In Edward N. Zalta (Ed.), The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Spring 2013 Edition). http://plato.stanford.edu/archives/spr2013/entries/justicehealthcareaccess/. Accessed 9 Jan 2019.

  • Di Novi, C., Piacenza, M., Robone, S., & Turati, G. (2019). Does fiscal decentralization affect regional disparities in health? Quasi-experimental evidence from Italy. Regional Science and Urban Economics,78, 103465.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Expert Panel on effective ways of investing in Health (ExPH). (2018). Benchmarking access to healthcare in the EU. Luxembourg: Publications Office of the European Union.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fabbri, D., & Robone, S. (2010). The geography of hospital admission in a national health service with patient choice. Health Economics,19(9), 1029–1047.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fattore, G., Petrarca, G., & Torbica, A. (2014). Traveling for care: inter-regional mobility for aortic valve substitution in Italy. Health Policy,117(1), 90–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fleurbaey, M., & Schokkaert, E. (2011). Equity in health and health care. In Handbook of health economics (Vol. 2, pp. 1003–1092). North Holland: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frenz, P., & Vega, J. (2010). Universal health coverage with equity: what we know, don’t know and need to know. Background Paper for the Global Symposium on Health Systems Research, 16–19 November 2010—Montreux, Switzerland: HSR Symposium.

  • Italian Ministry of Health. (2016). Programma Nazionale Esiti, Rome.

  • Jones, A. M. (2019). Equity, opportunity and health. Empirica,46(3), 413–421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khan, A. A. (1992). An integrated approach to measuring potential spatial access to health care services. Socio-Economic Planning Sciences,26(4), 275–287.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuo, C.-T., & Chen, D.-R. (2018). Double disadvantage: income inequality, spatial polarization and mortality rates in Taiwan. Journal of Public Health,40(3), e228–e234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kwon, S. (2003). Health and health care. Social Indicators Research,62(1–3), 171–186.

    Google Scholar 

  • Le Grand, J. (1982). The strategy of equality: Redistribution and the social services. London: Allen ad Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Le Grand, J. (1987). Equity, health and health care. Social Justice Research,1, 257–274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levaggi, R., & Zanola, R. (2004). Patients’ migration across regions: The case of Italy. Applied Economics,36(16), 1751–1757.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levesque, J. F., Harris, M. F., & Russell, G. (2013). Patient-centred access to health care: Conceptualising access at the interface of health systems and populations. International Journal for Equity in Health,11, 12–18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li Donni, P., Peragine, V., & Pignataro, G. (2014). Ex-ante and ex-post measurement of equality of opportunity in health: A normative decomposition. Health Economics,23(2), 182–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mooney, G. (1983). Equity in health care: Confronting the confusion. Effective Health Care,1, 179–185.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oliver, A., & Mossialos, E. (2004). Equity of access to health care: outlining the foundations for action. Journal of Epidemiology and Community Health,58, 655–658.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olsen, E. O., & Rodgers, D. L. (1991). The welfare economics of equal access. Journal of Public Economics,45, 91–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perucca, G., Piacenza, M., & Turati, G. (2019). Spatial inequality in access to healthcare: Evidence from an Italian Alpine region. Regional Studies,53(4), 478–489.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roemer, J. E. (1993). A pragmatic theory of responsibility for the egalitarian planner. Philosophy & Public Affairs, 22(2), 146–166.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roemer, J. E. (1998). Theories of distributive justice. Harvard University Press.

  • Sen, A. (2002). Why health equity? Health Economics,11(8), 659–666.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Doorslaer, E., & Masseria, C. (2004). Income-related inequality in the use of medical care in 21 OECD countries (pp. 8–12). Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagstaff, A., & van Doorslaer, E. (2000). Equity in health care finance and delivery. In: A. Culyer & J. Newhouse (Eds.), Handbook of health economics (Vol. 1, pp. 1803–1862).

  • Zhang, X., & Kanbur, R. (2005). Spatial inequality in education and health care in China. China Economic Review,16(2), 189–204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We wish to thank Paolo Li Donni, Massimiliano Piacenza, Silvana Robone and all the participants to the XXXI Conference of the Italian Society of Public Economics (Turin, September 2019) for helpful suggestions and comments. The usual disclaimers apply.

Funding

Funding was provided by University of Naples Federico II (Grant No. PG_2017_0016542_00016542).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Massimo Aria.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix 1: Computing Accessible Resources

Appendix 1: Computing Accessible Resources

The accessible resources of individual i in province j, can be written as

$$Y_{ij} = \left( {C_{ij}^{E} - P_{ij}^{E} } \right) + S_{hj} + FA_{hj}$$

where Yij denotes the accessible resources available to individual i in province j. Such resources are given by the difference between equivalent consumption CEij and the equivalent poverty line PEij , where equivalent means that use is made of the equivalence scales provided by ISTAT to take into account the composition of the household. That is \(C_{ij}^{E} = \frac{{C_{hj} }}{{K_{hj} }}\), \(h = 1, \ldots ,H\), where Chj is the overall consumption of household h, to which individual i belongs, in province j, and Khj is the equivalence scale associated to household h. CEij is therefore the per-capita consumption within the household taking into consideration economies of scale in consumption. \(P_{ij}^{E}\) is calculated in the same way, \(P_{ij}^{E} = \frac{{P_{hj} }}{{K_{hj} }}\). The difference \(C_{ij}^{E} - P_{ij}^{E}\) gives the resources that an individual can rely upon in case of need together with the overall savings of family h, Shj, and other financial (immediately available) assets, FAhj.

Notice that the survey on Household Income and Wealth provides information concerning only the region where a given household lives. As our purpose is to carry on the analysis at the provincial level, we have employed an incremental nearest-neighbourhood strategy to place individuals in the right province.

To this end we have first computed the average income in each of the Italian provinces, then we have considered each region in turn. For any given region, we have performed a fuzzy clustering analysis providing, as a probability vector, the likelihood that a given household belongs to a certain province. Individuals are so randomly associated to provinces. The analysis has been designed in such a way as to respect the two following conditions: (1) the proportion of sampled individuals assigned to a given province respects the real proportion of the province population over the regional one; (2) the expected income in the pool of individuals associated to a given province must be consistent with the real mean income of the province.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Abatemarco, A., Aria, M., Beraldo, S. et al. Measuring Disparities in Access to Health Care: A Proposal Based on an Ex-ante Perspective. Soc Indic Res 150, 549–568 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-020-02305-y

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-020-02305-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation