Skip to main content
Log in

Are the self-employed really jacks-of-all-trades? Testing the assumptions and implications of Lazear’s theory of entrepreneurship with German data

  • Published:
Small Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Using a large representative German data set and various concepts of self-employment, this paper tests the “jack-of-all-trades” view of entrepreneurship by Lazear (Am Econ Rev 94(2): 208–211, 2004). Consistent with its theoretical assumptions we find that self-employed individuals perform more tasks and that their work requires more skills than that of paid employees. In contrast to Lazear’s assumptions, however, self-employed individuals do not just need more basic but also more expert skills than employees. Our results also provide rather limited support for the idea that human capital investment patterns differ between those who become self-employed and those ending up in paid employment.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Further theoretical models are provided, e.g., by Lucas (1978), Kihlstrom and Laffont (1979), Kanbur (1979), Murphy et al. (1991) and Blanchflower and Oswald (1998); for surveys see de Wit (1993) and Parker (2009, chap. 2).

  2. In a modification of the Lazear model Benz (2009) also takes non-monetary benefits into account and thus focuses on overall utility rather than solely on income. While this implies that there will be a positive supply of entrepreneurship even if no profits can be made, it does not change the central prediction that entrepreneurs should be generalists and employees should be specialists.

  3. These hypotheses should not only apply to entrepreneurs in a narrow sense—such as innovators or “founders of a new small restaurant”, the example given by Lazear (2004, p. 208)—but to (almost) all individuals in self-employment. For a more detailed discussion of entrepreneurship and self-employment, see Sect. 3.

  4. In a recent study using the same data set but not explicitly designed to test the assumptions of Lazear's theory, Bublitz and Noseleit (2011) also ran regressions with the number of expert skills as the dependent variable, hypothesizing that the number of expert skills is higher for entrepreneurs than for employees (contrary to our hypothesis 4).

  5. Note that this theory also implies a seventh hypothesis, namely, that “[i]ndividuals with more balanced skill sets are more likely to become entrepreneurs” (Lazear 2005, p. 651). Data limitations and the problem of finding a convincing indicator of skill balance preclude us from directly investigating this hypothesis (although the results of testing hypotheses 5 and 6 may provide some indirect evidence). Studies that aim to directly test the balancing hypothesis are Lazear (2004, 2005), who uses the extent of special versus general courses of Stanford students; Backes-Gellner and Moog (2008), who construct a composite indicator of relative length of different types of work experience and extend this indicator to include human as well as social capital; Hartog et al. (2010), who investigate the impact of various cognitive and social abilities; Hsieh et al. (2011), who multiply the generality of degree majors and grade variance to obtain an indicator of skill balance; and Orazem et al. (2012) who use the number of courses in the major minus the average number of courses taken in other departments.

  6. See also Backes-Gellner et al. (2010) who derive and discuss various definitions of entrepreneurship from Lazear (2005), including self-employment with and without other employees.

  7. Note that our data set does not include apprentices and that we exclude helping family members and freelance collaborators from our analysis since they are neither entrepreneurial nor typical employees. The share calculated from the microcensus data excludes helping family members but includes freelance collaborators and apprentices. Also note that we are not making use of the weighting factors provided in the data set. Our results do not change substantially if we do.

  8. Note that our empirical results are virtually the same and our insights do not change if we make use of count data models (such as NegBin) rather than OLS in these and the following estimations (results are available from the first author on request). Count data models analyze the number of occurrences of a certain event within a certain interval (of time). We, however, count the number of singular occurrences of different events over uncertain intervals. Therefore, using standard count data methods might be regarded as similarly inappropriate as using OLS, but we are not aware of better ways to analyze our data. For a similar approach using both methods see Bublitz and Noseleit (2011).

  9. Note that a simple univariate OLS regression of the number of total skills required on the number of tasks occurring sometimes or often shows that about one-third of the variance in the number of skills can be traced back to the number of tasks.

  10. One explanation could be that expert skills act as a positive signal to capital lenders so that it makes sense for entrepreneurs to acquire (more) expert skills rather than just basic skills. However, individuals in our survey were explicitly asked about skills required in their current occupation, so that it seems likely that they actually need these expert skills at work and not just as a signal. Another explanation might be that entrepreneurs must have (more) expert skills since the market infrastructure for complementary inputs and services is not well developed, but in a market economy it is quite unlikely that this should occur on a large scale.

  11. Employees aiming for self-employment may be working exceedingly in small firms, which have been found both to provide jobs demanding higher skill diversity and to spawn more entrepreneurs than larger firms (see, e.g., Elfenbein et al. 2010 and the literature cited therein, and Bublitz and Noseleit 2011 for a related discussion). This is one more reason for taking account of firm size in a robustness check (see below).

  12. While risk aversion is usually thought to deter individuals from becoming self-employed, Hsieh et al. (2011) argue that individuals with higher risk aversion might want to invest in balanced skills in order to diversify their human capital, making them more likely to become entrepreneurs.

  13. Putting this insight in terms of the theory of the firm, entrepreneurs seem to be better characterized as multifaceted specialists rather than as mere coordinators (see also Hart and Moore 2005, p. 697).

References

  • Åstebro, T., & Thompson, P. (2011). Entrepreneurs, Jacks of all trades or Hobos? Research Policy, 40(5), 637–649.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Backes-Gellner, U., & Moog, P. (2008). Who chooses to become an entrepreneur? The Jacks-of-All-Trades in Social and Human Capital. University of Zurich Institute for Strategy and Business Economics Working Paper 76.

  • Backes-Gellner, U., Tuor, S. N., & Wettstein, D. (2010). Differences in the educational paths of entrepreneurs and employees. Empirical Research in Vocational Education and Training, 2(2), 83–105.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benz, M. (2009). Entrepreneurship as a non-profit-seeking activity. International Entrepreneurship and Management Journal, 5(1), 23–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower, D. G. (2004). Self-employment: More may not be better. Swedish Economic Policy Review, 11(2), 15–73.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower, D. G., & Oswald, A. J. (1998). What makes an entrepreneur? Journal of Labor Economics, 16(1), 26–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brixy, U., & Hessels, J. (2010). Human capital and start-up success of nascent entrepreneurs. EIM Research Reports H201013.

  • Bublitz, E., & Noseleit, F. (2011). The skill balancing act: determinants of and returns to balanced skills. Jena Economic Research Papers 2011-025.

  • Caliendo, M., Fossen, F., & Kritikos, A. (2011). Personality characteristics and the decision to become and stay self-employed. IZA Discussion Paper 5566.

  • de Wit, G. (1993). Models of self-employment in a competitive market. Journal of Economic Surveys, 7(4), 367–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elfenbein, D. W., Hamilton, B. H., & Zenger, T. R. (2010). The small firm effect and the entrepreneurial spawning of scientists and engineers. Management Science, 56(4), 659–681.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franco, A. M., & Filson, D. (2006). Spin-outs: Knowledge diffusion through employee mobility. RAND Journal of Economics, 37(4), 841–860.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1953). Essays in positive economics. Chicago, Ill.: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, A., & Tiemann, M. (2006). BIBB/BAuA employment survey of the working population on qualification and working conditions in Germany 2006, suf_1.0. In Research Data Center at BIBB (Ed.), GESIS Cologne, Germany (data access). Bonn: Federal Institute of Vocational Education and Training. doi:10.4232/1.4820.

  • Hart, O. D. (2011). Thinking about the firm: a review of Daniel Spulber’s The Theory of the Firm. Journal of Economic Literature, 49(1), 101–113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart, O. D., & Moore, J. (2005). On the design of hierarchies: coordination versus specialization. Journal of Political Economy, 113(4), 675–702.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hartog, J., van Praag, C. M., & van der Sluis, J. (2010). If you are so smart, why aren’t you an entrepreneur? Returns to cognitive and social ability: entrepreneurs versus employees. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 19(4), 947–989.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helsley, R. W., & Strange, W. C. (2011). Entrepreneurs and cities: complexity, thickness and balance. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 41(6), 550–559.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmström, B., & Roberts, J. (1998). The boundaries of the firm revisited. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12(4), 73–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmström, B., & Tirole, J. (1989). The theory of the firm. In R. Schmalensee & R. D. Willig (Eds.), Handbook of industrial organization (Vol. 1, pp. 61–133). Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hsieh, C., Parker, S. C., & van Praag, C. M. (2011). Risk, balanced skills and entrepreneurship. IZA Discussion Paper 6200.

  • Hundley, G. (2001). Why and when are the self-employed more satisfied with their work? Industrial Relations, 40(2), 293–316.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hyytinen, A., & Ilmakunnas, P. (2007). What distinguishes a serial entrepreneur? Industrial and Corporate Change, 16(5), 793–821.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kanbur, S. M. (1979). Of risk taking and the personal distribution of income. Journal of Political Economy, 87(4), 769–797.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kelleter, K. (2009). Selbstständige in Deutschland. Ergebnisse des Mikrozensus 2008. Wirtschaft und Statistik, 12(2009), 1204–1217.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kihlstrom, R. E., & Laffont, J.–J. (1979). A general equilibrium entrepreneurial theory of firm formation based on risk aversion. Journal of Political Economy, 87(4), 719–748.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lazear, E. P. (2004). Balanced skills and entrepreneurship. American Economic Review, 94(2), 208–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lazear, E. P. (2005). Entrepreneurship. Journal of Labor Economics, 23(4), 649–680.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E, Jr. (1978). On the size distribution of business firms. Bell Journal of Economics, 9(2), 508–523.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, K. M., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1991). The allocation of talent: Implications for growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(2), 503–530.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oberschachtsiek, D. (2012). The experience of the founder and self-employment duration: a comparative advantage approach. Small Business Economics, 39(1), 1–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Orazem, P. F., Li, Y., & Jolly, R. W. (2012). Bachelor’s degrees and business start-ups: a reexamination of Lazear’s theory of entrepreneurship. http://se.shufe.edu.cn/upload/htmleditor/File/120521031313.pdf. Accessed 11 September 2012.

  • Parker, S. C. (2009). The economics of entrepreneurship. Cambridge, UK; New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Schjoedt, L. (2009). Entrepreneurial job characteristics: an examination of their effect on entrepreneurial satisfaction. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 33(3), 619–644.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmitt, J., & Lane, N. (2009). An international comparison of small business employment. CEPR Reports and Issue Briefs 2009-27.

  • Schumpeter, J. (1911). Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot.

    Google Scholar 

  • Silva, O. (2007). The jack-of-all-trades entrepreneur: innate talent or acquired skill? Economics Letters, 97(2), 118–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stuetzer, M., Obschonka, M., & Schmitt-Rodermund, E. (2012). Balanced skills among nascent entrepreneurs. Small Business Economics, doi:10.1007/s11187-012-9423-2.

  • Tiemann, M., Schade, H.-J., Helmrich, R., Hall, A., Braun, U., & Bott, P. (2008). Berufsfeld-Definitionen des BIBB auf Basis der Klassifikation der Berufe 1992. Wissenschaftliche Diskussionspapiere des BIBB 105.

  • Wagner, J. (2003). Testing Lazear’s jack-of-all-trades view of entrepreneurship with German micro data. Applied Economics Letters, 10(11), 687–689.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, J. (2006). Are nascent entrepreneurs ‘jacks-of-all-trades’? A test of Lazear’s theory of entrepreneurship with German data. Applied Economics, 38(20), 2415–2419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zopf, S., & Tiemann, M. (2010). BIBB/BAuA-employment survey 2005/06. Schmollers Jahrbuch, 130(3), 409–420.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

For helpful comments and suggestions we would like to thank an anonymous referee of this journal as well as Udo Brixy, Michael Fritsch, Monika Jungbauer-Gans, Joachim Wagner, and participants in seminars at the Universities of Hannover and Erlangen-Nuremberg, in the IECER Conference in Regensburg, 2012, and in the 3rd IZA Workshop on Entrepreneurship Research in Potsdam, 2012. We further thank Anja Hall, Josef Hartmann and Holger Alda for assistance with data set related questions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Claus Schnabel.

Appendix

Appendix

See Table 6.

Table 6 OLS estimates for the number of tasks and skills, controlling for firm size

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Lechmann, D.S.J., Schnabel, C. Are the self-employed really jacks-of-all-trades? Testing the assumptions and implications of Lazear’s theory of entrepreneurship with German data. Small Bus Econ 42, 59–76 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-012-9464-6

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-012-9464-6

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation