Skip to main content
Log in

Entrepreneurship as a non-profit-seeking activity

  • Published:
International Entrepreneurship and Management Journal Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

It is typically assumed that people engage in entrepreneurship because there are profits to be made. In contrast to this view, this paper argues that entrepreneurship is more adequately characterized as a non-profit-seeking activity. Evidence from a broad range of authors and academic fields is discussed showing that entrepreneurship does quite generally not pay in monetary terms. Being an entrepreneur seems to be rather rewarding because it entails substantial non-monetary benefits, like greater autonomy, broader skill utilization, and the possibility to pursue one’s own ideas. It is shown how incorporating these non-monetary benefits into economic models of entrepreneurship can lead to a better understanding of the phenomenon.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Figure 1
Figure 2
Figure 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Entrepreneurship can therefore be seen as a source of “procedural utility” (Frey, Benz, & Stutzer, 2004), meaning that people do not only value material outcomes, but also the processes and conditions leading to outcomes.

  2. It is an interesting question why there is a superstar-distribution of entrepreneurial incomes. This is further explored in “Why is there a superstar-distribution of entrepreneurial incomes?” and “Counterarguments and alternative explanations.”

  3. Several of these studies also show that the higher job satisfaction of self-employed people is not due to different personality characteristics. If e.g., intrinsically optimistic people are more likely to be self-employed, and at the same time report higher job satisfaction regardless of their employment situation, a positive relationship between self-employment and job satisfaction might merely reflect personality differences. Using an individual-fixed-effects methodology in panel data, Frey and Benz (2003), Kawaguchi (2002) and Hundley (2001) document that this is unlikely to be the case. It is also noteworthy that the self-employment—job satisfaction result does not crucially depend on the definition of self-employment. Blanchflower (2004), for example, shows that self-employed business owners with employees, who can be considered as the most ‘entrepreneurial’ group within the self-employed, have generally the highest job satisfaction among self-employed people.

  4. If, for example, a logarithmic production function is assumed, F(H) = log(H), then it follows from Eq. 12 that H* = s·A/w. The resulting entrepreneur’s income is s·A·log(s·A/w)−s·A, i.e., the production costs s·A rise proportionally with A, while the output s·A·log(s·A/w) rises more than proportionally with A (see Fig. 2).

  5. It should be noted that the model of Murphy et al. (1991) only includes one dimension of ability, while Lazear’s (2005) model stresses the importance of the balance of abilities for entrepreneurship. The two approaches can be made compatible when A is assumed to be a measure for the balance of abilities rather then a measure for general ability.

  6. The full passage in Schumpeter (1934: 93–94) reads as follows: First of all there is the dream and the will to found a private kingdom, usually, though not necessarily, also a dynasty. [...] Then there is the will to conquer: the impulse to fight, to prove oneself superior to others, to succeed for the sake, not of the fruits of success, but of success itself. From this aspect, economic action becomes akin to sport [...]. The financial result is a secondary consideration, or, at all events, mainly valued as an index of success and as a symptom of victory, the displaying of which very often is more important as a motive of large expenditure than the wish for the consumers’ goods themselves. [...] Finally, there is the joy of creating, of getting things done, or simply of exercising one’s energy and ingenuity. [...] Our type seeks out difficulties, changes in order to change, delights in ventures.”

References

  • Aghion, P., & Howitt, P. (1997). A schumpeterian perspective on growth and competition. In D. M. Kreps & K. F. Wallis (Eds.), Advances in economics and econometrics: Theory and applications, vol. 2 (pp. 279–317). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Amabile, T. (1983). The social psychology of creativity. Berlin Heidelberg New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Amabile, T. (1997). Motivating creativity in organizations: On doing what you love and loving what you do. California Management Review, 40(1), 39–58.

    Google Scholar 

  • Amit, R., MacCrimmon, K. R., Zietsma, C., & Oesch, J. M. (2000). Does money matter?: Wealth attainment as the motive for initiating growth-oriented technology ventures. Journal of Business Venturing, 16, 119–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arabsheibani, G., de Meza, D., Maloney, J., & Pearson, B. (2000). And a vision appeared unto them of a great profit: Evidence of self-deception among the self-employed. Economics Letters, 67, 35–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Åstebro, T. (2003). The return to independent invention: Evidence of unrealistic optimism, risk seeking or skewness loving? Economic Journal, 113(484), 226–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Åstebro, T. (2005). Does it pay to be a jack-of-all-trades? Working Paper, Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto.

  • Backes-Gellner, U., & Lazear, E. P. (2003). Entrepreneurs and specialists: Jack-of-all-trades or master of one? Mimeo, University of Zurich.

  • Baumol, W. J. (1990). Entrepreneurship: Productive, unproductive, and destructive. Journal of Political Economy, 98, 893–921.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W. J. (1993). Entrepreneurship, management, and the structure of payoffs. Cambridge and London: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W. J. (2004). Education for innovation: Entrepreneurial breakthroughs vs. corporate incremental improvements. NBER Working Paper No. 10578.

  • Benz, M., & Frey, B. S. (2007). The value of doing what you like: Evidence from the self employed in 23 countries. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, forthcoming.

  • Blanchflower, D. G. (2000). Self-employment in OECD countries. Labour Economics, 7, 471–505.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower, D. G. (2004). Self-employment: More may not be better. Swedish Economic Policy Review, 11(2), 17–73.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower, D. G., & Oswald, A. J. (1998). What makes an entrepreneur? Journal of Labor Economics, 16(1), 26–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower, D. G., Oswald, A. J., & Stutzer, A. (2001). Latent entrepreneurship across nations. European Economic Review, 45, 680–691.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brockhaus, R. H. (1980). Risk taking propensity of entrepreneurs. Academy of Management Journal, 23, 509–520.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Busenitz, L. W., & Barney, J. B. (1997). Differences between entrepreneurs and managers in large organizations: Biases and heuristics in strategic decision-making. Journal of Business Venturing, 12, 9–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cramer, J. S., Hartog, J., Jonker, N., & van Praag, M. (2002). Low risk aversion encourages the choice for entrepreneurship: An empirical test of a truism. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 48(1), 29–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desai, M., Gompers, P., & Lerner, J. (2003). Institutions, capital constraints and entrepreneurial firm dynamics: Evidence from Europe. NBER Working Paper No. 10165.

  • Djankow, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2002). The regulation of entry. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(1), 1–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans, D., & Leighton, L. (1989). Some empirical aspects of self-employment. American Economic Review, 79, 519–535.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R., & Cook, P. (1995). The winner-take-all society. New York: Free.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S., & Benz, M. (2003). Being independent is a great thing: Subjective evaluations of self-employment and hierarchy. CESifo Working Paper No. 959.

  • Frey, B. S., Benz, M., & Stutzer, A. (2004). Introducing procedural utility: Not only what, but also how matters. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 160, 377–401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedwald, W. (1995). Sinatra! The song is you: A singer’s art. New York: Scribner.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gimeno, J., Folta, T. B., Cooper, A. C., & Woo, C. Y. (1997). Survival of the fittest? Entrepreneurial human capital and the persistence of underperforming firms. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42, 750–783.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, B. H. (2000). Does entrepreneurship pay? An empirical analysis of returns to self-employment. Journal of Political Economy, 108, 604–632.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hundley, G. (2001). Why and when are the self-employed more satisfied with their work? Industrial Relations, 40, 293–317.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hvide, H. (2004). Firm size and the quality of entrepreneurs. Working Paper, Graduate School of Business, Stanford University.

  • Kawaguchi, D. (2002). Compensating wage differentials among self-employed workers: Evidence from job satisfaction scores. Institute of Social and Economic Research, Osaka University, Discussion Paper No. 568.

  • Kerins, F., Smith, J., & Smith, R. (2004). Opportunity cost of capital for venture capital investors and entrepreneurs. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 39, 385–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kihlstrom, R. E., & Laffont, J. J. (1979). A general equilibrium entrepreneurial theory of firm formation based on risk aversion. Journal of Political Economy, 87, 719–749.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. M. (1973). Competition and entrepreneurship. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klapper, L., Laeven, L., & Rajan, R. (2004). Barriers to entrepreneurship. Working Paper, World Bank.

  • Knight, F. H. (1921). Risk, uncertainty and profit. New York: Houghton-Mifflin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lazear, E. P. (2005). Entrepreneurship. Journal of Labor Economics, 23, 649–680.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindh, T. & Ohlsson, H. (1996). Self-employment and windfall gains: Evidence from the Swedish lottery. Economic Journal, 106(439), 1515–1526.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martinelli, A. (2001). Entrepreneurship. In N. J. Smelser & P. B. Baltes (Eds.), International encyclopedia of the social and behavioral sciences (pp. 4545–4552).

  • McMillan, J., & Woodruff, C. (2002). The central role of entrepreneurs in transition economies. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 16(3), 153–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merz, J. (2004). Reichtum in Deutschland: Mikroanalytische Ergebnisse der Einkommensteuerstatistik für Selbständige und abhängig Beschäftigte. Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik, 5(2), 105–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moskowitz, T. J., & Vissing-Jorgensen, A. (2002). The returns to entrepreneurial investment: A private equity premium puzzle? American Economic Review, 92, 745–778.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, K. M., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1991). The allocation of talent: Implications for growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 503–530.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (1992). OECD employment outlook, Ch. 4: Recent trends in self-employment. Paris: Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parker, S. C. (2003). What is entrepreneurship? A proposal for a data-based methodology. Academy of Entrepreneurship Journal, 9(2), 45–66.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parker, S. C. (2004). The economics of self-employment and entrepreneurship. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poutvaara, P., & Tuomala, J. (2004). What is left to residual claimants? The empirics of income reported by entrepreneurs and workers. IZA Working Paper No. 1178.

  • Puri, M., & Robinson, D. (2005). Optimism and economic choice. NBER Working Paper No. 11361.

  • Rosen, S. (1981). The economics of superstars. American Economic Review, 71, 845–858.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schuetze, H. J., & Bruce, D. (2004). The relationship between tax policy and entrepreneurship. Swedish Economic Policy Review, 11, 235–265.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1934). The theory of economic development. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stern, S. (2004). Do scientists pay to be scientists? Management Science, 50, 835–853.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Throsby, D. (1996). Disaggregated earnings functions for artists. In V. A. Ginsburgh & P.-M. Menger (Eds.), Economics of the arts: Selected essays (pp. 331–346).

  • Towse, R. (2000). Creativity, incentive and reward. An economic analysis of copyright and culture in the information age. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tucker, I. B. (1988). Entrepreneurs and public sector employees: The role of achievement motivation and risk in occupational choice. Journal of Economic Education, 19, 259–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Praag, M. (1999). Some classic views on entrepreneurship. De Economist, 147, 311–335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Praag, M., & Cramer, J. S. (2001). The roots of entrepreneurship and labor demand: Individual ability and low risk aversion. Economica, 68(269), 45–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vivarelli, M. (1991). The birth of new enterprises. Small Business Economics, 3, 215–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vivarelli, M. (2004). Are all the potential entrepreneurs so good? Small Business Economics, 23, 41–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, J. (2003). Testing Lazear’s jack-of-all-trades view of entrepreneurship with German micro data. Applied Economics Letters, 10, 687–689.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wassall, G. H., & Alper, N. O. (1992). Toward a unified theory of the determinants of the earnings of artists. In R. Towse & A. Khakee (Eds.), Cultural economics. Berlin Heidelberg New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wasserman, N. (2004). Executive compensation in entrepreneurial teams: The founder gap, board membership, and pay for milestones. Best Paper Proceedings, Academy of Management 2004 Annual Meeting.

Download references

Acknowledgement

I would like to thank Thomas Astebro, William Baumol, Gary Becker, Raquel Bernal, Patrick Bolton, Robert D. Cooter, Bruno S. Frey, Gerald Hosp, Paul DiMaggio, Henry Hansmann, Amir Licht, Raymond Miles, Ebba Norsted, Alois Stutzer, Tom Tyler, Burton Weisbrod, Oliver Williamson, several anonymous referees and seminar participants at UC Berkeley, Northwestern University, Harvard Business School and the University of Zurich for helpful comments and discussions. The paper was written while I was a visiting research fellow at the Boalt School of Law, University of California at Berkeley, whose hospitality I gratefully acknowledge, as well as financial support by the Swiss National Science Foundation.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Matthias Benz.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Benz, M. Entrepreneurship as a non-profit-seeking activity. Int Entrep Manag J 5, 23–44 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11365-006-0031-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11365-006-0031-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation