Skip to main content
Log in

Technology Licensing under Successive Monopoly

  • Published:
Review of Industrial Organization Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Assume that there is an outside innovator who owns a cost-reducing innovation and the market structure of the industry in question is that of successive monopoly. It is found that, an innovation that is aimed at an upstream firm will tend to be accompanied by a fixed fee license, while an innovation that is aimed at a downstream firm will tend to be accompanied by a per-unit royalty license. But the former is reversed if the market structure of the final goods becomes duopolistic: The optimal licensing contract could never be that of fixed fee when licensing occurs at the upmost production stage. Moreover, the industry profit, consumer surplus and social welfare are all maximized when the licensing occurs at the upmost production stage.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. From 1996 to 2020, the technology licenses have increased by about 400% in the U.S., please refer to https://autm.net/AUTM/media/SurveyReportsPDF/FY20-US-Licensing-Survey-FNL.pdf.

  2. In addition to pure royalty, pure fixed-fee, and two-part tariff licensing contracts, Hegde (2014) reveals that three- and four-part payments including milestone payments and minimum royalty payments are common in licenses of biomedical inventions in the U.S.; a total of 57% of the licenses in the empirical sample are either milestone payments or minimum royalty payments besides fixed fees and royalty rates. Savva and Taneri (2015) show that in the presence of asymmetric information, it is more effective for a patent holder such as a university to use equity-royalty rather than fixed-fee-royalty contracts as a screening mechanism.

  3. Linnemer (2022) considers an n-level vertical structure with a general demand function but does not deal with technology licensing. In our paper, the equilibrium licensing contract for a general demand function is derivable when n = 1; we will discuss this in detail in the Appendix.

  4. Unlike other producers, this upmost stage producer is assumed to be a raw material supplier that incurs no input cost.

  5. Following the literature on licensing, we assume that the outside licensor has full bargaining power. Accordingly, the optimal fixed-fee is the profit difference of firm k between accepting and rejecting the licensing offer.

  6. Furthermore, the second-order condition for profit maximization is satisfied as \(\frac{{d^{2} \Omega_{k} (r_{k} )}}{{dr_{k}^{2} }} = \frac{ - 2}{{2^{n + 1} }} + \frac{2}{{2^{2n + 2 - k} }} < 0\).

  7. Please refer to the Appendix for the proof.

  8. Several studies in the technology licensing literature relate to the issue of welfare implication, such as Chang et al. (2013), Kuo et al. (2016) and Lin et al. (2022).

  9. We assume that the licensor licenses its technology to both firms, regardless of the production stage at which the innovation is aimed.

  10. If the two final goods producers compete in Bertrand fashion, our main results remain robust. The intuition goes as follows. Under Bertrand competition, the outside licensor always has an incentive to charge a positive per-unit royalty rate to soften the price competition so as to increase the industry profit. Therefore, a positive royalty rate is imposed regardless of the production stage at which the innovation is aimed.

References

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yan-Shu Lin.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

We are indebted to the editor, Lawrence J. White, and the two anonymous referees for their suggestions that have significantly improved the paper. The usual disclaimer applies.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file1 (PDF 190 KB)

Appendix A

Appendix A

We use n = 1 as an example to check if the results that we derived with the linear demand curve and constant marginal costs are still robust with more general demand and marginal cost functions. It is found that the main results still hold if the demand function is not too convex.

The proof is as follows:

Assume n = 1: There are only two production stages. When the innovation is aimed at firms at the final production stage–k = 0–the non-input cost of the final good producer before licensing is assumed to be \(c(q_{0} )\), where \(c(q_{0} )\) is the general marginal cost function with the properties \(c^{\prime}(q_{0} ) > 0\) and \(c^{\prime\prime}(q_{0} ) > 0\). It changes from \(c(q_{0} )\) to \(c(q_{0} ) + r_{0} q_{0} - \varepsilon q_{0}\) after licensing. Moreover, the inverse final demand function is assumed to be \(p_{0} (q_{0} )\) with \(p_{0}^{\prime } (q_{0} ) < 0\). The profit function of the final good producer–firm 0–is therefore specified as follows:

$$\pi_{0} (q_{0} ) = [p_{0} (q_{0} ) - p_{1} ]q_{0} - c(q_{0} ) - r_{0} q_{0} + \varepsilon q_{0}$$
(A1)

The first-order condition for profit maximization of the above objective function is derivable as follows:

$$\frac{{d\pi_{0} }}{{dq_{0} }} = p^{\prime}_{0} q_{0} + p_{0} - c^{\prime}(q_{0} ) - r_{0} + \varepsilon - p_{1} = 0$$
(A2)

and the second-order condition requires: \(\frac{{d^{2} \pi_{0} }}{{dq_{0}^{2} }} = 2p^{\prime}_{0} + p_{0}^{\prime \prime } q_{0} - c^{\prime\prime}(q_{0} ) < 0\). We can also derive the following comparative statics: \(\frac{{dq_{0} }}{{dp_{1} }} = \frac{{dq_{0} }}{{dr_{0} }} = \frac{1}{{2p^{\prime}_{0} + p_{0}^{\prime \prime } q_{0} - c^{\prime\prime}(q_{0} )}} < 0\), the value of which depends on the concavity of the demand and the cost curves.

In the second stage of the game, firm 1–the upmost-stage producer–has the following profit function:

$$\pi_{1} (p_{1} ) = p_{1} q_{1} (p_{1} ) - c(q_{1} (p_{1} )).$$

where \(c(q_{1} )\) is the marginal cost function with \(c^{\prime}(q_{1} ) > 0\) and \(c^{\prime\prime}(q_{1} ) > 0\). The first-order condition for profit maximization of the above objective function is derivable as follows:

$$\frac{{d\pi_{1} }}{{dp_{1} }} = q_{1} + (p_{1} - c^{\prime})\frac{{dq_{1} }}{{dp_{1} }} = 0.$$

Note that \(q_{1} = q_{0} = q\) because we assume that the production technology exhibits a one-to-one relationship. The comparative statics effect becomes: \(\frac{{dp_{1} }}{{dr_{0} }} = \frac{{ - ({{d^{2} \pi_{1} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{d^{2} \pi_{1} } {dp_{1} dr_{0} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {dp_{1} dr_{0} }})}}{{{{d^{2} \pi_{1} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{d^{2} \pi_{1} } {dp_{1}^{2} }}} \right. \kern-0pt} {dp_{1}^{2} }}}}\), where \(\frac{{d^{2} \pi_{1} }}{{dp_{1} dr_{0} }} = \frac{dq}{{dp_{1} }}(1 + 3qp^{\prime\prime}_{0} \frac{dq}{{dp_{1} }} - c^{\prime\prime}\frac{dq}{{dr_{0} }})\) and \(\frac{{d^{2} \pi_{1} }}{{dp_{1}^{2} }} < 0\) by the second-order condition. It is found that if the demand function is not too convex, \(\frac{{d^{2} \pi_{1} }}{{dp_{1} dr_{0} }}\) and \(\frac{{dp_{1} }}{{dr_{0} }}\) are negative.

At the downstream stage, the objective function of the licensor kk = 0–is the same as Eq. (6). The first-order condition of the licensor k is as follows:

$$\frac{{d\Omega_{0} (r_{0} )}}{{dr_{0} }} = q + \mathop {r_{0} \frac{dq}{{dr_{0} }}}\limits_{{}} + \mathop {\frac{{\partial \pi_{0}^{{}} }}{{\partial p_{1} }}\frac{{\partial p_{1} }}{{\partial r_{0} }}}\limits_{{}} - q = 0$$
(A3)

From (A3), we find that with a non-linear demand and a non-constant marginal cost, our results still generally hold, and the optimal licensing contract is generally a pure per-unit royalty or a two-part tariff if the innovation is aimed at the downstream firm. This is because the input price effect is generally negative, which is the same as Eq. (7). However, the input price effect becomes ambiguous if the demand function is too convex. From the above discussions, we conclude that if the innovation is aimed at firms at the final goods production stage, the licensor still charges a positive royalty rate as long as the demand is not too convex.

Now consider the case that the innovation is aimed at firms at the upmost production stage:\(k=1\). The non-input cost of the upstream producer is \(c(q_{1} )\). After licensing, it changes to \(c(q_{1} ) + r_{1} q_{1} - \varepsilon q_{1}\). The last stage is the same as in the previous paragraph. In the second stage of the game, the profit function of the upmost stage producer–firm 1–is as follows:

$$\pi_{1} (p_{1} ) = p_{1} q_{1} (p_{1} ) - c(q_{1} (p_{1} )) - r_{1} q_{1} + \varepsilon q_{1}$$
(A4)

In the first stage, the objective function of the licensor k, k = 1, is the same as that in Eq. (6). The first-order condition for profit maximization of the licensor k is as follows:

$$\frac{{d\Omega_{1} (r_{1} )}}{{dr_{1} }} = q + r_{1} \frac{dq}{{dr_{1} }} + 0 - q = 0$$
(A5)

From (A5), we find that with a non-linear demand and non-linear marginal cost, the equilibrium \(r_{1}\) set by the outside licensor is still 0 when the innovation is aimed at the upmost stage producer: Regardless of whether the demand and cost curves are linear or non-linear, an innovation that is aimed at an upstream firm will be accompanied by a fixed-fee license because there is no input price effect.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Shih, PC., Chou, TH., Hwang, H. et al. Technology Licensing under Successive Monopoly. Rev Ind Organ (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-024-09951-3

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-024-09951-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation