Skip to main content
Log in

Giving and volunteering over a lifecycle

  • Published:
Review of Economics of the Household Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Charitable giving in the US is substantial, contributing 2% of the annual GDP. I develop a lifecycle model of warm-glow giving for consumers who derive utility from both acts of giving and volunteering, and explore the general equilibrium characteristics of an economy of these pro-social consumers. By separating the charitable deduction rate from the income tax rate as well as identifying non-separable utility not only between consumption and charitable giving, but also between giving and volunteering, the model unambiguously determines the direction of welfare from any particular change in a tax system, illuminating the role of policy in the private provision of public goods. Subject to mortality risks, the consumers are enabled to endogenously choose their retirement age, revealing salient features regarding lifecycle giving/volunteering on top of consumption/leisure behaviors in a calibrated OLG equilibrium. A simulation result shows that given an income tax rate, an increase in deduction rate increases not only giving but also output and consumption, due to greater labor supply. Reasonable parameterization of the model confers the highest level of welfare for the tax rate of about 23% given an equal rate for the income tax and charitable deduction.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13
Fig. 14
Fig. 15
Fig. 16
Fig. 17

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. DellaVigna et al. (2012), “Testing for Altruism and Social Pressure in Charitable Giving,” QJE 127.

  2. Andreoni (2006), “Philanthropy” in Handbook of Giving, Altruism, and Reciprocity. In 2014, the number is about 2.1% of GDP (Duquette, 2016).

  3. “Giving USA 2011: The Annual Report on Philanthropy for the Year 2010”

  4. “Giving USA 2020: The Annual Report on Philanthropy for the Year 2019”

  5. “Giving and Volunteering in the US,” 2001.

  6. In the US, the deduction for charitable giving is often a target for elimination.

  7. Unlike the recent CPS data, Menchik and Weisbrod’s result shows very little volunteer labor among older people, probably due to lack of data.

  8. Consumer Expenditure Survey.

  9. Fisman et al. (2007) estimate CES utility functions to demonstrate this.

  10. As well as education and family size in their model.

  11. They further compute a cross-price elasticity of time to the tax price of money of −2.11 for women and −1.12 for men.

  12. Freeman (1997) finds significant differences between these 90% of individuals that give money and time to charity, compared with 59% who donate money but do not volunteer.

  13. It ranges from around −2.45 to about −0.51.

  14. In case of CES utiliy, Eq. (2) may be replaced by \(c={[\theta {x}^{\rho }+(1-\theta ){g}^{\rho }]}^{1/\rho }\) with ρϵ(−, 1). Likewise, the total utility from hours not spent on employment is \(h={[\sigma {l}^{\varphi }+(1-\sigma ){v}^{\varphi }]}^{1/\varphi },\) with φϵ(−, 1). Although the CES functional form is more plausible to incorporate the possibility of elastic donations, i.e. a higher elasticity than one, as in Bakija and Heim (2011), I find that the form is not well tractable to derive a closed form solution in the constrained inter-temporal optimization. Numerically, I do not expect much difference in terms of macroeconomic aggregates.

  15. For an itemizer, when tg = 10%, the actual cost to the doner who makes $100 contribution will be $90 because 100(1 − 0.1) = 90. 

  16. Mt = xt + (1 − tg)gt + (1 − tw)wet[lt + vt], is the per period total resource allowance, explicit and implict, for consumption/giving and leisure/volunteering, like an annual expenditure schedule.

  17. If an individual firm endogenously chooses not only the labor and capital, but also the portion for charitable contribution according to a tax policy like a corporate income tax rate tc, then the maximization problem is Max(1 − π(1 − tc))F(K, N) − wN − (r + δ)K. 

  18. See the footnote 29 in Section 4.

  19. Author’s calculation using the annual percentage rate.

  20. By the data source, giving also varies significantly with educational attainment of the givers, although this fact is not reported here. Those with more education give more often, give more dollars, and generally give a higher fraction of income.

  21. According to this survey, although data is not shown here, it is also found that volunteering results display differences between employed and unemployed respondents. Employed respondents are more likely to have volunteered in the past year, compared to unemployed respondents (46.1% vs. 39.6%). Among past-year volunteers, however, employed respondents volunteer significantly fewer hours in the past month, compared to their unemployed counterparts (13.8 h vs. 18.2 h).

  22. Similarly, Gourinchas and Parker (2002) estimate 3.44% for the rate.

  23. The number comes from both the Individual giving 73% and the Foundations 14%.

  24. \(g=\mathop{\sum }\nolimits_{t = 0}^{T}{Q}_{t}{g}_{t}=0.87{{\Gamma }}\)

  25. Bullard and Feigenbaum (2007). This is the conditional productivity profile, measured conditional on working agents. It is assumed that the difference between the conditional and unconditional profiles is small.

  26. They are β, γ, η, θ, σ in the model.

  27. They are α, δ in the model.

  28. The value is 0.0857 if 2.94 is set for K/Y.

  29. For the derivation, consider the following: \(\frac{{C}^{after-tax}}{Y}+\frac{\delta K}{Y}+\frac{G}{Y}=1\), and \(G=\mathop{\sum }\nolimits_{t = 0}^{T}{Q}_{t}{t}_{w}w{e}_{t}[1-({l}_{t}+{v}_{t})]+\mathop{\sum }\nolimits_{t = 0}^{T}{Q}_{t}{t}_{r}r{b}_{t}-\mathop{\sum }\nolimits_{t = 0}^{T}{Q}_{t}{t}_{g}{g}_{t}.\) Define \(L=\mathop{\sum }\nolimits_{t = 0}^{T}{l}_{t},\) and \(V=\mathop{\sum }\nolimits_{t = 0}^{T}{v}_{t},\) and further \(\widehat{C}=C+we(L+V)\) and \(\widehat{Y}=Y+we(L+V).\) Then \(\widehat{C}=C+we(L+V)=\mathop{\sum }\nolimits_{t = 0}^{T}{Q}_{t}[(1-{t}_{g}){g}_{t}+{B}_{t}^{{{\Gamma }}}]+\pi +w\mathop{\sum }\nolimits_{t = 0}^{T}{e}_{t}({l}_{t}+{v}_{t})\) and \(\widehat{Y}=Y+we(L+V)=wN+(r+\delta )K+we(L+V)=w\mathop{\sum }\nolimits_{t = 0}^{T}{e}_{t}(1-({l}_{t}+{v}_{t}))+(r+\delta )K+w\mathop{\sum }\nolimits_{t = 0}^{T}{e}_{t}({l}_{t}+{v}_{t})=w\mathop{\sum }\nolimits_{t = 0}^{T}{e}_{t}+(r+\delta )K=wN+(r+\delta )\) Also, Y = KαN1−α is obtained from \(N=\mathop{\sum }\nolimits_{t = 0}^{T}{e}_{t}(1-({l}_{t}+{v}_{t})),\) while \(\widehat{Y}={K}^{\alpha }{\widehat{N}}^{1-\alpha }\) is obtained from \(\widehat{N}=\mathop{\sum }\nolimits_{t = 0}^{T}{e}_{t}\). Therefore, \(C/Y\approx \widehat{C}/\widehat{Y}\) when we(L + V) is small relative to Y.

  30. The peak age comes sooner, and the giving ratio measured for the amount at peak to the initial value is smaller than the data: this can be corrected by adding an element of social pressure or status into the model.

  31. Their estimation is obtained on PSID (1968–1996). Also see Bullard and Feigenbaum (2007).

  32. 28.9 percent and 28.0 percent, respectively.

  33. Or the deduction rate on taxable income.

  34. Their estimation is −1.26 (−0.40) for permanent (transitory) price elasticity and 0.87 (0.29) for permanent (transitory) income elasticity.

  35. Atkinson (2016) points out: “when aggregating people’s preferences, shall the warm glow or other individual motives be incorporated in the social welfare function, or is it double-counting, as argued by Diamond [2006]?”

  36. The intratemporal budget constraint of the model is: xt + (1 − tg)gt + (1 − tw)wet[lt + vt] + bt+1 = Mt

  37. It may be intuitive to think about the opposite case: what would happen to the variables if there is an increase in the income tax rate, while fixing the deduction rate. Following a similar argument as above, this will increase leisure and volunteering, but reduce labor supply and output.

References

  • Agranov, M., & Thomas, P. (2015). Equilibrium tax rates and income redistribution: a laboratory study. Journal of Public Economics, 130, 45–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J. (2006). Philanthropy. In S. C. Kolm & J. M. Ythier (Eds.), Handbook of the economics of giving, altruism and reciprocity, Vol. 2. Applications (pp. 1201–1269). Elsevier Science.

  • Andreoni, J. (1988). Privately provided public goods in a large economy: the limits of altruism. Journal of Public Economics, 35, 57–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J. (1990). Impure altruism and donations to public goods: a theory of warm glow giving. Economic Journal, 100, 464–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J., Gale, W. G., Scholz, J. K., & Straub, J. (1996). Charitable contributions of time and money. University of Wisconsin–Madison Working Paper.

  • Andreoni, J. (2006). Philanthropy. In S. C. Kolm & J. M. Ythier (Eds.), Handbook of the economics of giving, altruism and reciprocity, Vol. 2. Applications (pp 1201-1269). Elsevier Science.

  • Arias, E. (2004). United States life tables. National Center for Health Statistics, 58, 1–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ariely, D., Bracha, A., & Meier, S. (2009). Doing good or doing well? Image motivation and monetary incentives in behaving prosocially. American Economic Review, 99, 544–555.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson, A. (2016). Charitable Giving and Economics. In G. Fack & C. Landais (Eds.), Charitable Giving and Tax Policy: A Historical and Comparative Perspective (pp. 23–34). Oxford University Press.

  • Atkinson, A. B., Backus, P. G., & Micklewright, J. (2017). Charitable bequests and wealth at death. The Economic Journal, 127, F1–F23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Auten, G., Sieg, H., & Clotfelter, C. (2002). Charitable giving, income and taxes: an analysis of panel study. American Economic Review, 92, 371–382.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bakija, J., & Heim, B. (2011). How does charitable giving respond to incentives and income? New estimates from panel data. National Tax Journal, 64, 615–650.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bakija, J. M., Gale, W. G., & Slemrod, J. B. (2003). Charitable Bequests and Taxes on Inheritance and Estates: Aggregate Evidence from Across States and Time. American Economic Review, 93, 366–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J. (1974). Are government bonds net wealth? Journal of Political Economy, 82, 1095–1117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bauer, T., Bredtmann, J., & Schmidt, C. (2013). Time vs. money – The supply of voluntary labor and charitable donations across Europe. European Journal of Political Economy, 32, 80–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G., & Barro, R. (1988). A reformulation of the economic theory of fertility. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 103, 1–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrom, T., Blume, L., & Varian, H. (1986). On the private provision of public goods. Journal of Public Economics, 29, 25–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, A. L., Meer, J., & Williams, J. F. (2019). Why do people volunteer? An experimental analysis of preferences for time donations. Management Science, 65, 1455–1947.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, E., & Lankford, H. (1992). Gifts of money and gifts of time: estimating the effects of tax prices and available time. Journal of Public Economics, 47, 321–341.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, E., & Ferris, J. (2007). Social capital and philanthropy: an analysis of the impact of social capital on individual giving and volunteering. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 36, 85–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bullard, J., & Feigenbaum, J. (2007). A leisurely reading of the lifecycle consumption data. Journal of Monetary Economics, 54, 2305–2320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charness, G., & Rabin, M. (2002). Understanding social preferences with simple tests. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 817–869.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clotfelter, C. (1985). Federal tax policy and charitable giving. University of Chicago Press.

  • Carpenter, J., & Myers, C. (2010). Why volunteer? Evidence on the role of altruism, image, and incentives. Journal of Public Economics, 94, 911–920.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deaton, A. (1991). Saving and liquidity constraints. Econometrica, 59, 1221–1248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DellaVigna, S. (2009). Psychology and economics: evidence from the field. Journal of Economic Literature, 47, 315–372.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duncan, B. (1999). Modeling charitable contributions of time and money. Journal of Public Economics, 72, 213–242.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duquette, N. (2016). Do tax incentives affect charitable contributions? Evidence from public charities’ reported revenue. Journal of Public Economics, 137, 51–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dye, R. (1980). Contributions of volunteer time: some evidence on income tax effects. National Tax Journal, 33, 89–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ebeling, F., Feldhaus, C., & Fendrich, J. (2017). A field experiment on the impact of a prior donor’s social status on subsequent charitable giving. Journal of Economic Psychology, 61, 124–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eibich, P., Lorenti, A., & Mosca, I. (2020). Does retirement affect voluntary work provision? Evidence from England, Ireland, and the U.S. IZA Discussion Papers No. 13153.

  • Erlinghagen, M. (2010). Volunteering after retirement. European Society, 12, 603–625.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erosa, A., Fuster, L., & Kambourov, G. (2010). The Heterogeneity and Dynamics of Individual Labor Supply over the Life-Cycle: Facts and Theory. Working paper. https://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.650.8180&rep=rep1&type=pdf.

  • Fack, G., & Landais, C. (2010). Are tax incentives for charitable giving efficient? Evidence from France. American Economic Journal Economic Policy, 2, 117–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fack, G., & Landais, C. (2016). Philanthropy, Tax Policy and Tax Cheating: A Long Run Perspective on US data. In G. Fack & C. Landais (Eds.), Charitable Giving and Tax Policy: A Historical and Comparative Perspective (pp. 61−114). Oxford University Press.

  • Faravelli, M., & Stanca, L. (2014). Economic incentives and social preferences: causal evidence of non-separability. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 108, 273–289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Gächter, S. (2000). Fairness and retaliation: the economics of reciprocity. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14, 159–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehrler, S., & Przepiorka, W. (2016). Choosing a partner for social exchange: charitable giving as a signal of trustworthiness. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 129, 157–171.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feigenbaum, J. (2008). Information shocks and precautionary saving. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 32, 3917–3938.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldman, N. E. (2010). Time is money: choosing between charitable activities. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 2, 103–130.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein, M. (1995). The effect of marginal tax rates on taxable income: a panel study of the 1986 tax reform act. Journal of Political Economy, 103, 551–572.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein, M. (1976). Charitable bequests, estate taxation, and intergenerational wealth transfers. In R. E. Grieson (Ed.), Research Papers Sponsored by the Commission on Private Philanthropy and Public Needs. Lexington Books.

  • Fisman, R., Kariv, S., & Markovits, D. (2007). Individual preferences for giving. American Economic Review, 97, 1858–1876.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, R. B. (1997). Working for nothing: the supply of volunteer labor. Journal of Labor Economics, 15, 140–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B., & Meier, S. (2004). Pro-social behavior in a natural setting. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 54, 65–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gourinchas, P., & Parker, J. A. (2002). Consumption over the life cycle. Econometrica, 70, 47–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gruber, J. (2004). Pay or pray? The impact of charitable subsidies on religious attendance. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 2635–2655.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, G., & Imrohoroglu, S. (2006). Consumption over the life cycle: the role of annuities. NBER Working Paper 12341.

  • Heckman, J. (1974). Life cycle consumption and labor supply: an explanation of the relationship between income and consumption over the life cycle. American Economic Review, 64, 188–194.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kerr, W. (2014). Income inequality and social preferences for redistribution and compensation differentials. Journal of Monetary Economics, 66, 62–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landry, C., Lange, A., List, A., Price, M., & Rupp, N. G. (2006). Toward an understanding of the economics of charity: evidence from a field experiment. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121, 747–782.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • List, J., & Lucking-Reiley, D. (2002). The effects of seed money and refunds on charitable giving: experimental evidence from a University Capital Campaign. The Journal of Political Economy, 110, 215–233.

  • List, J. (2011). The market for charitable giving. Journal of Economic Perspective, 25, 157–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGrattan, E., & Prescott, E. (2000). Is the stock market overvalued? Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 24, 20–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • McClelland, R., & Brooks, A. C. (2004). What is the real relationship between income and charitable giving? Public Finance Review, 32, 483–497.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meer, J. (2014). Effects of the price of charitable giving: evidence from an online crowdfunding platform. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 103, 113–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Menchik, P. L., & Weisbrod, B. A. (1987). Volunteer labor supply. Journal of Public Economics, 32, 159–183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Musick, M., & Wilson, J. (2007). Volunteers: A Social Profile. Indiana University Press.

  • Ottoni-Wilhelm, M., Vesterlund, L., & Xie, H. (2017). Why do people give? Testing pure and impure altruism. American Economic Review, 107, 3617–3633.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Park, H., & Feigenbaum, J. (2018). Bounded rationality, lifecycle consumption and social security. Journal of Economic Behaviors and Organization, 146, 65–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peloza, J., & Steel, P. (2005). The price elasticities of charitable contributions: A meta-analysis. Journal of Public Policy & Marketing, 24, 260–272.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rios-Rull, J. (1996). Life-cycle economies and aggregate fluctuations. Review of Economic Studies, 63, 465–489.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sauer, R. (2015). Does it pay for women to volunteer? International Economic Review, 56, 537–564.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shang, J., & Croson, R. (2009). A field experiment in charitable contribution: the impact of social information on the voluntary provision of public goods. The Economic Journal, 119, 1422–1439.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steinberg, R. (1989). The Theory of Crowding Out: Donations, Local Government Spending, and the ‘New Federalism’. In R. Magat (Ed.), Philanthropic Giving: Studies in Varieties and Goals (pp. 143−156). Oxford University Press.

  • Wang, L., & Graddy, E. (2008). Social capital, volunteering, and charitable giving. International Journal of Voluntary and Nonprofit Organizations, 19, 23–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhu, R. (2021). Retirement and voluntary work provision: evidence from the Australian Age Pension reform. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 190, 674–690.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I thank John Duffy, James Feigenbaum, Lise Vesterlund, Daniele Coen-Pirani, and Marla Ripoll, as well as all the partipants at the conferences (Econometric Society, SABE, NTA, MMM, BEES), and the anonymous reviewers for their valuable comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hyeon Park.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The author declares no competing interests.

Additional information

Publisher’s note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

This appendix introduces a tractable version of the warm glow model so that a closed form solution can be obtained. Consider an agent who gets utility from the act of giving in the form of both goods and time as described in Section 2. The agent who is subject to mortality risk Qt may live up to T-period and each period he has one unit of time endowment, as well as a stream of productivity measured in efficiency units. The optimization problem of the agent at t = 0 is,

$$Ma{x}_{\{{x}_{t},{g}_{t},{l}_{t},{v}_{t}\}}\mathop{\sum }\limits_{t=0}^{T}{\beta }^{t}{Q}_{t}u({x}_{t},{g}_{t},{l}_{t},{v}_{t})$$

subject to

$${x}_{t}+(1-{t}_{g}){g}_{t}+{b}_{t+1}=(1-{t}_{w})[w{e}_{t}(1-{l}_{t}-{v}_{t})]+[1+(1-{t}_{r})r]{b}_{t}+{B}_{t}^{y}$$
(A1)
$$\begin{array}{l}{x}_{t},\,{g}_{t},\,{l}_{t},\,{v}_{t}\ge 0,1\ge {l}_{t}+{v}_{t}\ge 0\\ {b}_{0}=0,{b}_{T+1}=0\end{array}$$

where xt is consumption, gt is charitable giving, lt is leisure, and vt is volunteering. Rewrite the resource constraint to get

$${x}_{t}+(1-{t}_{g}){g}_{t}+(1-{t}_{w})w{e}_{t}[{l}_{t}+{v}_{t}]+{b}_{t+1}=(1-{t}_{w})w{e}_{t}+[1+(1-{t}_{r})r]{b}_{t}+{B}_{t}^{y}$$
(A2)

Let Mt ≡ xt + (1 − tg)gt + (1 − tw)wet[lt + vt]. Then the maximization problem is decomposed into two sub-problems:

(i) Intra-temporal optimization

$$V\left(M,we\right)=Ma{x}_{x,l,g,v}u\left(x,g,l,v\right)$$
(A3)

subject to

$$\begin{array}{l}x+(1-{t}_{g})g+(1-{t}_{w})we[l+v]=M\\ x,g,l,v\ge 0,\,1\ge l+v\ge 0\end{array}$$

(ii) Inter-temporal optimization

$$Ma{x}_{{M}_{t,}{b}_{t+1}{{\mbox{}}}}\mathop{\sum }\limits_{t=0}^{T}{\beta }^{t}{Q}_{t}V\left({M}_{t}{{\mbox{}}},w{e}_{t}\right)$$
(A4)

s u b j e c t t o

$$\begin{array}{l}{M}_{t}+{b}_{t+1}=(1-{t}_{w})w{e}_{t}+[1+(1-{t}_{r})r]{b}_{t}+{B}_{t}^{y}\\ {b}_{0}=0,{b}_{T+1}=0\end{array}$$

By solving the first problem, one gets an optimal consumption-giving and leisure-volunteering amount as a function of total resource level M committed to spend each time. Let us assume CRRA utility function that satisfies the Inada condition:

$$u(x,g,l,v)=\left\{\begin{array}{l}\frac{1}{1-\gamma }{[{c}^{\eta }{h}^{1-\eta }]}^{1-\gamma }\,{{\mbox{if}}}\,\gamma \,\ne\, 1\\ \\ \ln \,{{\mbox{}}}{c}^{\eta }{h}^{1-\eta }\;{{\mbox{if}}}\,\gamma =1\end{array}\right\}$$
(A5)

where c = xθg1−θ represents the total consumption of goods, and the total hours not spent on labor is h = lσv1−σ, with ηϵ(0, 1), θϵ(0, 1), σϵ(0, 1) and γ > 0. From the first order condition, it is satisfied that

$$\frac{x}{(1-{t}_{g})\theta }=\frac{g}{(1-\theta )}$$
(A6)
$$\frac{l}{\sigma }=\frac{v}{(1-\sigma )}$$
(A7)

These conditions dictate the relative importance of the two arguments in each utility component of goods and hours: c = xθg1−θ and h = lσv1−σ. Giving (g) and volunteering (v) can be written in terms of consumption (x) and leisure (l), or vice versa. Rewriting the agent’s intra-temporal problem in terms of (x, l) for

$$Ma{x}_{x,l}\frac{D}{1-\gamma }{\left({x}^{\eta }{l}^{1-\eta }\right)}^{1-\gamma }$$
(A8)

subject to

$$\begin{array}{l}\left[1+\frac{1-\theta }{\theta }\right]x+(1-{t}_{w})we\left[1+\frac{1-\sigma }{\sigma }\right]l=M\\ \sigma \ge l\ge 0\end{array}$$

for a constant \(D={({A}^{{}^{\eta }}{B}^{1-\eta })}^{1-\gamma }\), where \(A={\left(\frac{1-\theta }{(1-{t}_{g})\theta }\right)}^{1-\theta }\) and \(B={\left(\frac{1-\sigma }{\sigma }\right)}^{1-\sigma }.\) Notice that the leisure is constrained by a fixed variable σ. Once again, the resource constraint can be reduced to a simpler form of \(\,\frac{1}{\theta }x+(1-{t}_{w})we(\frac{1}{\sigma })l=M.\) With this preliminary work, the model is analyzed via intra-temporal and inter-temporal optimization.

A. Solving the Intra-temporal optimization

$$V\left(M,we\right)=Ma{x}_{x,l}\frac{D}{1-\gamma }{\left({x}^{\eta }{l}^{1-\eta }\right)}^{1-\gamma }$$
(A9)

subject to

$$\begin{array}{l}\frac{1}{\theta }x+(1-{t}_{w})we(\frac{1}{\sigma })l=M\\ x\ge 0,\sigma \ge l\ge 0\end{array}$$

Using the resource constraint, \(\frac{1}{\theta }x+(1-{t}_{w})we(\frac{1}{\sigma })l=M,\) the optimal consumption and leisure levels are derived for any specific resource level and wage rate. Because it is satisfied that (1 − tw)we < (1 − η)M when leisure binds, the solution is determined by the threshold level \({M}^{* }\equiv \frac{(1-{t}_{w})we}{1-\eta }.\) Given we, depending on whether the leisure is binding or not, the optimal choice is:

$$x\left(M,we\right)=\left\{\begin{array}{l}\theta \eta M\,\,if\,\,M\le {M}^{* }\\ \theta [M-(1-{t}_{w})we]\,\,if\,\,M \,>\, {M}^{* }\end{array}\right\}$$
(A10)
$$l\,\left(M,we\right)=\left\{\begin{array}{l}\sigma \left(1-\eta \right)\frac{M}{(1-{t}_{w})we}\,\,if\,M\le {M}^{* }\\ \sigma \,\,if\,\,M \,>\, {M}^{* }\end{array}\right\}$$
(A11)

Because \(g=\frac{(1-\theta )}{(1-{t}_{g})\theta }x\) and \(v=\frac{(1-\sigma )}{\sigma }l,\) it is also true that

$$g\left(M,we\right)=\left\{\begin{array}{l}(1-\theta )\eta \frac{M}{(1-{t}_{g})}\,\,if\,\,M\le {M}^{* }\\ \frac{1-\theta }{1-{t}_{g}}[M-(1-{t}_{w})we]\,\,if\,\,M \,>\, {M}^{* }\end{array}\right\}$$
(A12)
$$v\left(M,we\right)=\left\{\begin{array}{l}(1-\sigma )\left(1-\eta \right)\frac{M}{(1-{t}_{w})we}\,\,if\,\,M\le {M}^{* }\\ {{\mbox{}}}1-\sigma \,\,if\,\,M \,>\, {M}^{* }\end{array}\right\}$$
(A13)

The indirect utility function of the optimization is given by

$$V\left(M,we\right)=$$
$$\left\{\begin{array}{c}{{\mbox{}}}\frac{D}{1-\gamma }{\left[{\left(\theta \eta \right)}^{\eta }{\left(\frac{\sigma \left(1-\eta \right)}{(1-{t}_{w})we}\right)}^{1-\eta }M\right]}^{1-\gamma }\,if\,M\le {M}^{* }\\ \frac{D}{1-\gamma }{\left[{\theta }^{\eta }{[M-(1-{t}_{w})we]}^{\eta }{\sigma }^{1-\eta }\right]}^{1-\gamma }\,if\,M \,>\, {M}^{* }\end{array}\right\}$$
(A14)

B. Solving the Inter-temporal optimization

Let the time-indexed resource level be \({M}_{t}=\frac{1}{\theta }{x}_{t}+\left(\frac{(1-{t}_{w})w{e}_{t}}{\sigma }\right){l}_{t}\) and let \(V\left({M}_{t},w{e}_{t}\right)\) be the indirect utility function obtained from the analysis in section A. Then the maximization problem for the agent over time is

$$Ma{x}_{{M}_{t,}{b}_{t+1}{{\mbox{}}}}\mathop{\sum }\limits_{t=0}^{T}{\beta }^{t}{Q}_{t}V\left({M}_{t},w{e}_{t}\right)$$
(A15)

s u b j e c t t o

\({M}_{t}+{b}_{t+1}=(1-{t}_{w})w{e}_{t}+[1+(1-{t}_{r})r]{b}_{t}+{B}_{t}^{y}\)

b0 = 0, bT+1 = 0

The first order condition is

$${V}_{M}\left({M}_{t},w{e}_{t}\right)=\frac{{\lambda }_{0}}{{Q}_{t}{[\beta \left(1+(1-{t}_{r})r\right)]}^{t}}$$
(A16)

where λ0 is the Lagrange multiplier of the optimization at time 0 and \({V}_{M}=\frac{\partial V}{\partial M}.\) Given a value of wet, because the derivative of the value function \({V}_{M}\left({M}_{t},w{e}_{t}\right)\) is strictly decreasing in Mt, there exists an inverse function over the domain. Let \({{\Psi }}={V}_{M}^{-1}\left({M}_{t},w{e}_{t}\right)\) be the inverse function. From the first order condition above, it is true that

$${M}_{t}={V}_{M}^{-1}\left(\frac{{\lambda }_{0}}{{Q}_{t}{[\beta \left(1\right.+(1-{t}_{r})r]}^{t}},w{e}_{t}\right)={{\Psi }}\left(\frac{{\lambda }_{0}}{{Q}_{t}{[\beta \left(1+(1-{t}_{r})r\right)]}^{t}},w{e}_{t}\right)$$
(A17)

Plugging Mt back into the constraint to get

$$\mathop{\sum }\limits_{t=0}^{T}\frac{{{\Psi }}\left(\frac{{\lambda }_{0}}{{{Q}_{t}[\beta \left(1\right.+(1-{t}_{r})r]}^{t}},w{e}_{t}\right)}{{[1+(1-{t}_{r})r]}^{t}}=\mathop{\sum }\limits_{t=0}^{T}\frac{(1-{t}_{w})w{e}_{t}+{B}_{t}^{y}}{{[1+(1-{t}_{r})r]}^{t}}$$
(A18)

By solving for λ0, the optimal Mt is obtained: \({M}_{t}={{\Psi }}\left(\frac{{\lambda }_{0}^{* }}{{Q}_{t}{[\beta \left(1\right.+(1-{t}_{r})r]}^{t}},w{e}_{t}\right),\) where \({\lambda }_{0}^{* }\) is the value solved from the constraint equation.

Next, regarding the choice of working hours related to retirement, notice that the agent freely chooses his optimal working hours, and thus optimal leisure/volunteer hours each period. The paper explores the conditions under which the agent chooses either to retire early or postpone entering into the labor market. Revisiting the equation (A16), \({V}_{M}\left({M}_{t},w{e}_{t}\right)=\frac{{\lambda }_{0}}{{Q}_{t}{[\beta \left(1+(1-{t}_{r})r\right)]}^{t}},\) the condition can be rewritten into

$$D{\left[{\left(\theta \eta \right)}^{\eta }{\left(\frac{\sigma \left(1-\eta \right)}{(1-{t}_{w})w{e}_{t}}{{\mbox{}}}\right)}^{1-\eta }\right]}^{1-\gamma }{M}_{t}^{-\gamma }=\frac{{\lambda }_{0}}{{Q}_{t}{[\beta \left(1+(1-{t}_{r})r\right)]}^{t}}$$
(A19)

or

$${M}_{t}={\left(\frac{{\lambda }_{0}}{{\kappa }_{t}{Q}_{t}{[\beta \left(1+(1-{t}_{r})r\right)]}^{t}}\right)}^{-\frac{1}{\gamma }}$$
(A20)

where \({\kappa }_{t}=D{\left[{\left(\theta \eta \right)}^{\eta }{\left(\frac{\sigma \left(1-\eta \right)}{(1-{t}_{w}){we}_{t}}\right)}^{1-\eta }\right]}^{1-\gamma }\). Combining this with the constraint gives the solution for λ0, which is

$${\lambda }_{0}^{* }={\left(\frac{\mathop{\sum }\nolimits_{t = 0}^{T}\frac{(1-{t}_{w})w{e}_{t}+{B}_{t}^{y}}{{[1+(1-{t}_{r})r]}^{t}}}{\mathop{\sum }\nolimits_{t = 0}^{T}{\kappa }_{t}^{\frac{1}{\gamma }}{Q}_{t}^{\frac{1}{\gamma }}{\left[\frac{{\left[\beta \left(1+(1-{t}_{r})r\right)\right]}^{1/\gamma }}{1+(1-{t}_{r})r}\right]}^{t}}\right)}^{-\gamma }={\left(\frac{\mathop{\sum }\nolimits_{t = 0}^{T}\frac{(1-{t}_{w})w{e}_{t}+{B}_{t}^{y}}{{[1+(1-{t}_{r})r]}^{t}}}{\mathop{\sum }\nolimits_{t = 0}^{T}{\kappa }_{t}^{\frac{1}{\gamma }}{Q}_{t}^{\frac{1}{\gamma }}{\left[\frac{1}{{\phi }^{* }}\right]}^{t}}\right)}^{-\gamma }$$
(A21)

where \(\frac{1}{{\phi }^{* }}=\frac{{\left[\beta \left(1+(1-{t}_{r})r\right)\right]}^{1/\gamma }}{1+(1-{t}_{r})r}.\) Therefore, the optimal resource commitment schedule for work and partial leisure/volunteer, {σ > l > 0, 1 − σ > v > 0}, or no work and full leisure/volunteer, {σ = l > 0, 1 − σ = v > 0} is:

$${M}_{t}^{{{\mbox{}}}}=\left\{\begin{array}{l}{{\mbox{}}}{\left(\frac{{\lambda }_{0}^{* }}{{\kappa }_{t}{Q}_{t}{[\beta \left(1+(1-{t}_{r})r\right)]}^{t}}\right)}^{-\frac{1}{\gamma }}{{\mbox{}}}if\,\,{M}_{t}\le {M}_{t}^{* }{{\mbox{}}}\ \iff \ \frac{{\lambda }_{0}^{* }}{{Q}_{t}{[\beta \left(1+(1-{t}_{r})r\right)]}^{t}}{{\mbox{}}}\ge {q}_{t}^{* }\\ {\left(\frac{{\lambda }_{0}^{* }}{{\overline{\kappa }}_{t}{Q}_{t}{[\beta \left(1+(1-{t}_{r})r\right)]}^{t}}\right)}^{-\frac{1}{\overline{\gamma }}}+(1-{t}_{w})w{e}_{t}{{\mbox{}}}\;if\,\,{M}_{t} \,>\, {M}_{t}^{* }\ \iff \ \frac{{\lambda }_{0}^{* }}{{Q}_{t}{[\beta \left(1+(1-{t}_{r})r\right)]}^{t}} \,<\, {q}_{t}^{* }\end{array}\right\}$$
(A22)

where \({q}_{t}^{* }={\kappa }_{t}{\left(\frac{(1-{t}_{w}){we}_{t}}{1-\eta }\right)}^{-\gamma }=\overline{\kappa }{\left(\frac{(1-{t}_{w}){we}_{t}}{1-\eta }\right)}^{-\overline{\gamma }}\) with \(\overline{\kappa }=D\eta {\theta }^{\eta (1-\gamma )}{\sigma }^{{}^{(1-\eta )(1-\gamma )}}\) and \(\overline{\gamma }=1-\eta \left(1-\gamma \right).\)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Park, H. Giving and volunteering over a lifecycle. Rev Econ Household 21, 335–369 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-022-09602-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-022-09602-0

Keywords

Navigation