Introduction

The past decade has witnessed the surge of online business worldwide, especially in the online retail sector.Footnote 1 The literature highlights several major advantages of online business, such as lower transaction costs (Alba et al., 1997; Childers et al., 2001; Gallino & Moreno, 2014), lower price-adjustment costs, and lower price dispersions on the seller side (Brynjolfsson & Smith, 2000), and higher quality and efficiency of decision-making on the buyer side (Häubl & Trifts, 2000). The real estate market is well known for high search and transaction costs for both buyers and sellers (Wheaton, 1990; Genesove & Han, 2012), which, in theory, implies a great potential for online real estate market platforms. In practice, the online real estate market’s development still lags behind most other major markets. To our knowledge, no purely online-based property marketplace exists in China or other major economies besides the online judicial housing auction market analyzed in this paper.

Despite the proliferation of online property portals, most real estate transactions are still conducted with a combination of an online listing, offline visits, and bargaining. In this paper, we provide insights on the feasibility of an online-only real estate market, using the empirical evidence from China’s online judicial housing sector as an example. We focus on whether and to what extent the information disclosure on the online platform can help mitigate the information-asymmetry problem in the real estate market and facilitate online transactions.

The real estate asset market is one of the few sectors where the share of online transactions is still tiny. An increasing number of online real estate platforms have developed in major economies, such as Zillow and Redfin in the US and Lianjia and Anjuke in China. However, these online platforms only serve to circulate listing units’ information and attract potential buyers with initial interests. In most cases, an interested buyer still needs to contact the agent or seller to arrange onsite inspections of the property and have intense face-to-face negotiations with the agent/seller, instead of completing the whole transaction process online. One essential challenge in the development of a direct online real estate transaction platform comes from the substantial information-asymmetry problem in the real estate market (Cramton, 1984; Garmaise & Moskowitz, 2003; Wit & Klaauw, 2013; Kurlat & Stroebel, 2015). Due to the high heterogeneity of real estate properties, relying solely on online information to get an adequate understanding of the property and judging how the property meets her preferences is difficult for a buyer. The combination of the high value of a real estate property and the complexity of property-rights issues further exaggerates the information-asymmetry problem, making the online transaction of real estate properties less feasible.

The leading online real estate platforms worldwide have made considerable efforts to overcome the information-asymmetry problem and promote the feasibility of online real estate transactions. Several new technologies have been adopted to provide more comprehensive property-related information on online platforms, such as 3D scanning, virtual and augmented realities (VR and AR), and drones (Ullah et al., 2018). The recent COVID-19 epidemic led to a new round of attempts to promote online real estate transactions in the industry. Due to the public health requirements of home isolation and social distancing during the epidemic, arranging onsite inspections or face-to-face discussions has been less feasible for buyers, which makes online real estate transactions more attractive. For instance, Zillow introduced pre-recorded video tours, 3D home tours, and live video walkthrough services. Redfin also launched video-chat tours in which a local agent visits the house in person and tours live with the client. One can expect that these efforts would also exist after the epidemic or even trigger the emergence of the online real estate market. However, from an academic perspective, few studies have been conducted to identify the challenges and/or directions of future efforts in developing online real estate transactions, mainly due to the lack of related data.

This study uses online judicial housing auctions in China to investigate how online information disclosure can help facilitate online real estate transactions. The online judicial auction sector started to develop in China in 2012. Since January 2017, all the judicial auctions in mainland China must be implemented on the designated online platforms, with over 40% of the execution properties as dwelling units. Due to the constraints associated with execution properties, in most cases, potential buyers cannot make an onsite inspection of the unit. Additionally, an interested buyer will not directly negotiate or bargain with the seller (i.e., the court); by contrast, all interest buyers compete via an online English auction. Thus, such online judicial housing auctions can be perceived as a representative type of online real estate transaction. During the sample period of 2017–2019, 215,559 dwelling units were listed on the “Taobao online judicial auction” platform, the largest designated online judicial auction platform in China. Over 65% of the listed units were sold, making it the world’s largest online real estate platform.

We manually collect information on the first auctions of the 215,559 dwelling units listed on the Taobao platform. Most importantly, for each auction, we identify whether the court provides each of the 14 information items on the webpage: one video, one package of photos, three attached files, and nine text information items on physical attributes and property rights. Meanwhile, we collect the number of buyers setting reminders, which serves as the proxy for buyers attracted with initial interests, and the number of registered bidders, which serves as the proxy of actual participants. We can also observe whether the auction resulted in a successful transaction and, if so, the transaction prices. Thus, we can empirically investigate whether and how online information disclosure helps attract buyers to participate in online real estate auctions and the final impacts on auction outcomes. One potential endogeneity concern is that information may be released selectively: the court officers may intentionally release more information associated with attractive attributes and, by contrast, hide some less attractive attributes. To rule out this effect, we only use the units handled by officers who always release exactly the same information for each case they handle. In our sample, the information disclosure pattern is therefore exogenously determined by the court officers’ (consistent) personal styles and independent of property characteristics. We also construct an index to quantitatively measure each unit’s information-disclosure quality and provide a preliminary analysis of the major factors affecting the online-information-disclosure quality during the sample period.

The paper offers three major findings: First, disclosing more and higher-quality information online can significantly help attract more potential buyers. In particular, the effect of online information disclosure is substantially larger in attracting actual participants of the online transactions (i.e., registered bidders) than in attracting initial interest (i.e., potential buyers setting reminders). The results also reveal that buyers focus on different information items in various stages: the eye-catching and less time-consuming information items such as photos can help attract initial interest; but when buyers need to make a more serious purchase decision, they will rely more on more comprehensive information sources such as videos or professional appraisal reports. We also provide evidence that the positive effect in attracting buyers can be finally converted to a higher success probability and a lower discount rate of the auction. Second, we discover a higher probability of online real estate transactions in some specific situations. The online platform could be more effective when combined with offline services, in a more mature online market, or for lower-value properties. Finally, we find evidence that the sellers (i.e., court officers) have realized the importance of online information disclosure. The information quality tends to increase when the court officer has more experience in handling online judicial housing auctions, consistent with the pattern of “learning by doing.”

This study speaks directly to the growing literature on the efficiency of online markets (Alba et al., 1997; Degeratu et al., 2000; Ansari & Mela, 2003; Zhang & Krishnamurthi, 2004; Robinson et al., 2007; Zhang & Wedel, 2009; Wang et al., 2014; Aguirre et al., 2015; Li & Lo, 2015; Lin et al., 2016). Most of the existing literature focuses on the well-developed online retail sector. To the best of our knowledge, we provide the first empirical analysis in the context of the online real estate market. Our empirical results reveal the effect of online information disclosure on attracting potential buyers in the housing sector. We also highlight some guidelines for the future development of the online real estate sector.

We also contribute to the rich literature on the impact of information on transaction participants (Tellis & Weiss, 1995; Chandy et al., 2001; Terui et al., 2010; Bertrand et al., 2010; Bertrand & Morse, 2011). The following three contributions are especially noteworthy. First, whereas most studies on this topic mainly rely on lab or field experiments, we provide empirical evidence based on field data. Second, we provide some of the first empirical evidence in the real estate market. Finally, we highlight that information’s role changes with the stage of market participants’ decision-making.

The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 describes the institutional background of China’s online judicial housing auction sector. Section 3 introduces the data and the empirical strategy. Section 4 presents the main empirical results on the effect of information disclosure on judicial auction outcomes. Section 5 provides a preliminary analysis of the macro-level pattern and micro-level factors affecting information disclosure quality. Section 6 concludes the paper.

Online Judicial Auctions in China

Similar to most other countries, the judicial auction in China is the work that the court publicly deal with the debtor’s property according to the compulsory execution procedure in civil cases, so as to pay off the creditor’s debts. The foreclosed collateral of bank loans contributes to a large portion of the execution properties,Footnote 2 with the remainder from condemned properties of criminal cases. Table 9 in the Appendix provides a breakdown of the execution properties by asset type, using the online judicial auctions on the Taobao platform as an example. The real estate properties account for 84.2% of all execution properties, with over half from the housing sector. By law, all individuals and institutes, both in China and abroad, are qualified to bid for the execution properties. Similar to the foreclosure housing market in the US (Clauretie & Daneshvary, 2009; Mian et al., 2015), we can reasonably expect that both homebuyers for living purposes and investors are active in the market. Nevertheless, no official information is available on the buyer side of the judicial housing sector in China.

One unique feature of the judicial auctions in China, including the judicial housing sector, is the prevalence of online auctions. As a critical measure to improve judicial auctions’ transparency and efficiency, the Chinese government has implemented a series of policies to promote online judicial auctions during the past decade. In February 2012, the Supreme People’s Court, China’s highest court, established the official website of judicial auction information disclosure,Footnote 3 which provides the first signal of introducing the online service to the judicial auction sector. All local courts are required to release the announcement of each judicial auction (either online or offline) on this website, including the information about the execution property. Then, two local courts in Zhejiang province jointly implemented the first online judicial auction on Taobao, the leading e-commercial platform in China, in July 2012. On August 31, 2012, the Amendment of the Civil Procedure Law became effective, which legally permits courts to implement online judicial auctions, and triggered the emergence of this new sector around the country. As a milestone in the development of the online judicial auction sector, the Supreme People’s Court issued the “Provisions on Several Issues Concerning the Online Judicial Auction by People’s Courts” (Judicial Interpretation No. 2016-18; “Provisions on Online Auction” for short hereafter) on August 2, 2016.Footnote 4 As an essential part of the document, since January 2017, all the judicial auctions in mainland China should be conducted online only based on the officially authorized online platforms. The document also includes detailed requirements on the online platforms and the procedures of online auctions. Since then, the online judicial auction market has been rapidly developing around China. We thus adopt January 2017 as the starting point of the sample period in the empirical analysis.

Figure 1 depicts the standard procedures of an online judicial auction. At most three attempts are made to auction off a property (or a pack of multiple properties). The first auction of the property follows the procedures of a conventional English auction. As the auctioneer, the court will first set a starting price open to all the bidders. If more than one bidder accepts the starting price, they will compete by bidding higher prices online within a designated period (24 h in most cases). A delaying mechanism is embedded in the bidding process. When a new bid is placed within five minutes before the designated ending time, the ending time will be automatically extended by five minutes after the last bid. In other words, the bidding process will only stop if no new bids are made within five minutes before the ending time. Such a delaying mechanism can help avoid the potential impacts of so-called snipers (a bidder who submits a bid in the closing moment of an auction hoping to win at the minimal cost added). The highest bidder wins the competition and has to purchase the property at the final bidding price. If no bidder accepts the starting price, the first auction fails, and the court will implement a second auction for the same property within 30 days. The second auction follows the same procedure as the first auction, the only difference being that the starting price is typically 20% lower than in the first. If the second auction fails as well, a last sell-off attempt is made.Footnote 5 The court will re-list the property on the online platform for 60 days, using the starting price of the second auction again. The first buyer accepting this price will get the property. If the sell-off attempt also fails, no further attempts are made.

Fig. 1
figure 1

The typical online judicial auction process. This figure visualizes a typical process of online judicial auctions in China during the sample period

This study mainly focuses on the information-disclosure arrangements associated with the above procedures and their outcomes. Here, we adopt the first auction as an example, whereas the arrangements are similar for the second auction and the sell-off attempt. For a specific execution property, the court will randomly appoint one of its officers to handle this online judicial auctionFootnote 6. The officer will collect the information on the property herself via, for example, onsite visits and due diligenceFootnote 7. As required by the Supreme People’s Court, she also needs to appoint a professional third-party appraiser to provide an appraisal price for the property. The appraisal price is expected to reflect the property’s market value and serve as the benchmark for the starting price. After all the preparations, the court will issue an official announcement for the auction on both the online auction platform and the Supreme People’s Court’s official judicial auction information-disclosure website. The auction announcement includes the name and a brief description of the execution property, the designated online platform for the auction, the starting (which is typically about 30 days after the announcement) and ending times of the auction, the starting price and appraisal price, and a series of auction rules. More detailed information on the execution property will also be simultaneously listed on the online auction platform.

Figure 2 provides an example of a representative listing webpage for an online judicial auction of a dwelling unit, including almost all the information that a potential buyer can access on the execution property and the online auction. Besides the brief description in the announcement, buyers can visually observe the house through a video and a few photos. Moreover, the related files, the detailed physical attributes, and property-rights information are also provided in the property description. The online information is all free and open to the public; in other words, no one can access more online information from the webpage by paying extra money or owning the purchasing priority.

Fig. 2
figure 2

An example of the listing webpage for an online judicial auction. This figure shows a representative example of a dwelling unit’s online judicial auction listing webpage (sf-item.taobao.com/sf_item/587646539573.htm). The core information parts that we focus on are all displayed and marked

Three arrangements are noteworthy here. First, the Supreme People’s Court only puts forward some online-information-disclosure principles in the “Provisions on Online Auction”, instead of detailed stipulations of information contents or formats. Thus, the information provided on the website is largely determined by the officer, which provides considerable variations for us to investigate the effect of information disclosure on auction outcomes. Second, the courts will not arrange onsite inspections for potential buyers. For each unit, its detailed address, including both the community’s name and the room number, is released publicly on the website. However, interested buyers typically will find it difficult to inspect the dwelling units themselves due to the potential seal-up conditions or tenants still occupying the units. Moreover, if the unit is part of a gated community (which is prevalent in China), the buyers cannot enter the community either. The buyers could turn to professional agents for offline services, but the agents face the same difficulties when attempting onsite inspections. In sum, it is typically infeasible for potential buyers to collect valuable offline information. In other words, the online platform is the dominant, if not only, channel for interested buyers to collect property-related information. Third, with emerging online judicial auctions, in some cities, professional agents provide related offline services, which mainly help solve the post-transaction property transfer problemsFootnote 8. The online auction platform (instead of the court) will automatically match available local offline services with the online judicial auction and provide the service links on the webpage. We also collect information on the availability of such offline services for each online judicial auction and investigate their effects in the empirical analysis.

During the listing period (i.e., the period between the announcement and the start of the auction, usually more than 30 days), all individual and institutional buyers can visit the webpage and contact the officer for inquiries. The information provided by officers in response to inquiries is, in most cases, identical to data already offered on the webpageFootnote 9. The listing webpage also records and publicly reports a few indicators of the potential buyers’ behaviors, and we mainly focus on two indicators in the following analysis. First, if a potential buyer is interested in the property, she can sign up for an automatic reminder when the auction is ready to start. No cost is involved in setting this reminder, so we expect that most potential buyers with an initial interest in the property will use it. Therefore, in the following empirical analysis, we adopt the number of potential buyers setting reminders as the proxy for the outcome in attracting initial interest. Second, a buyer needs to register if she plans to bid in the auction formally. For the registration, she needs to complete a detailed form and, more importantly, transfer a substantial deposit to the court, which typically amounts to 5–20% of the starting price.Footnote 10 Accordingly, we can reasonably expect that a potential buyer would only register when she has a real intention to participate in the bidding process. We thus adopt the number of registered buyers to reflect the achievement in attracting actual participation.

Data and Empirical Strategy

Data

We manually collect the data from the housing sector of the website of “Taobao online judicial auction” (sf.taobao.com), which is the first and currently largest online judicial auction platform in China.Footnote 11 Between January 2017 and October 2019, the platform had 215,599 dwelling units listed from all the 293 cities across the country. We then cleaned the raw data via the following procedures. First, we excluded properties with priority buyers.Footnote 12 Second, we also excluded dwelling units included in multiple-property packs. These procedures resulted in the exclusion of 15,196 units. The full sample includes 200,403 dwelling units for our analysis.

Figure 3 shows the units’ monthly distribution according to the ending time of their first auctions. The market witnessed a continuous and rapid development during the sample period, from an average monthly volume of 3,958 units in 2017 to an average monthly volume of 7,074 units in the first ten months of 2019. A significant seasonality also exists. The courts would typically list more units in the last months of a year. One possible explanation is that courts need to meet some specific annual targets in dealing with the execution properties, and thus have a higher incentive at the end of a year to reduce the number of unsold or unlisted execution properties. Figure 4 depicts the province-level distribution of the aggregated number of units during the sample period. Zhejiang province has 23,323 units, which account for the largest fraction of 11.9%, followed by Jiangsu and Henan provinces. Generally, provinces with more auction units are concentrated in the eastern region.

Fig. 3
figure 3

The monthly distribution of online judicial auction units. This figure visualizes the monthly distribution of the online judicial dwelling units from January 2017 to October 2019, according to the ending time of their first auctions

Fig. 4
figure 4

The province distribution of online judicial auction units. This figure visualizes the provincial distribution of online judicial dwelling units from January 2017 to October 2019

As shown in Table 1, because all the dwelling units in the sample were listed in a first auction, the data include information on 200,403 first auctions, with 88,133 successful transactions. Most of the properties that were not sold in the first auctions entered the subsequent stagesFootnote 13: 92,842 properties were listed in their second auctions, with 42.3% (39,255 properties) being successfully sold; 21,285 properties were listed in the sell-off stage, with 38.3% (8,150 properties) being successfully sold. In this study, we mainly focus on information disclosure and its effects on the first auctions for two reasons. First, there could be quality bias with the samples in the following two stages. Second, in 99.7% of all the cases, the court will duplicate the information of the first auction for the second auction and sell-off attempt. In the remaining 0.3% cases, only minor information changes are made. In other words, the latter two stages provide very little additional information.

Table 1 Breakdown of the execution properties by stages

For each dwelling unit and its first auction, we collect information on its basic auction characteristics, information disclosure, and outcomes from the webpage (Fig. 2 as an example). The auction-related characteristics include the listing time, starting time, and ending time of the first auction. We then calculate the length of the listing-period variable, exposure time, as the number of days between the listing time and the starting time of the auction. We also collect the appraisal value (appraisal price) as the proxy for the market price. Additionally, we identify the name of the court and the officer who handles the auction.

The information-disclosure condition is our primary interest in the empirical analysis. The information variables can be classified into visual information, file information, and text information. The visual information consists of the video and photo. The platform requires a minimum number of one photo and a maximum number of five. Video is not compulsory, and one video at most can be included. We record whether a video is available as the video dummy variable video and whether the number of photos reaches five as the photo dummy variable 5photo (i.e., the counterfactual of the photo dummy is that the website only provides one to four photos).

The file information refers to the official documents attached to the webpage. We measure the degree of file-information disclosure by the variable file num, which indicates the number of file types. The file types include the appraisal report, legal document, and property-rights certificate. We identify the existence of each type according to the file title.

The text version of the property description on the webpage contains physical attributes and property-rights information. These two categories’ disclosure degrees are measured by the information item numbers, phy num and right num, respectively. Physical attributes refer to the physical characteristics, including the area, age, floor, type, and decoration of the house. Property-rights information reflects the unit’s property-rights conditions, which consist of the right-limit condition (mortgage, seal up, and co-owner condition), with or without a key, the right source of the house, and the kind of certificate. We develop a text-analysis method for each category to determine whether the description contains a designated item.Footnote 14

The outcome of the listing process is measured from two perspectives. The first perspective reflects the direct effect of online information disclosure in attracting potential buyers, including the number of reminders and of registered bidders, which are explicitly presented on the webpage as Fig. 2 shows. We adopt the natural log of the number of reminders (ln(reminder)) as the proxy of potential buyers’ initial interest in the unit, and the natural log of the number of registered bidders (ln(registration)) as the indicator of actual transaction participationFootnote 15. The information disclosure can be perceived as achieving a better outcome if it attracts more potential buyers, especially more actual participants. As for the second perspective, we have two variables on the auction outcomes. The dummy if success indicates whether the auction is a success or a failure. The variable discount rate quantitatively measures the ratio of the transaction price to the appraisal price (i.e., discount rate = 1 – transaction price / appraisal price) for successful auctions. The information disclosure can be perceived as achieving a better outcome if the auction is successful, especially with a lower discount rate (i.e., a higher transaction price).

The definition and summary statistics of the major variables are listed in Table 11 in the Appendix. In the full sample, nearly 20% of properties provide a video, and nearly 80% of properties have five uploaded photos. The average file-type number is 0.56. On average, the property description provides information on 2.19 items on physical attributes and 2.20 items on property rights. On average, the number of reminders is 2.95 in the natural log (19.14 in the absolute number), and the number of registrations is 0.78 in the natural log (2.17 in the absolute number). The probability of success in the first auctions is 44.0%, and the successfully transacted properties have an average discount rate of 0.9%.

Empirical Strategy

In this study, we mainly focus on how information disclosure on the online platform helps attract potential buyers and its effect on the auction outcomes. For this purpose, we introduce the micro-level data of the first auctions of the dwelling units, and the main specifications are as follows:

$${y}_{i}=\beta \times {information}_{i}+\gamma \times {control}_{i}+{\alpha }_{j,t}+{\varepsilon }_{i}$$
(1)
$$P\left({if \ success}_{i}=1 | {information}_{i}, {control}_{i}\right)=\Phi (\beta \times {information}_{i}+\gamma \times {control}_{i})$$
(2)

where Eq. (1) adopts the OLS model and Eq. (2) adopts the binary probit model; \(\varPhi \left(\cdot \right)\) is the cumulative distribution function of standard normal distribution. \({y}_{i}\) refers to the outcome variable for dwelling unit i, which is located in district j and transacted in period t. The outcome variables include the number of reminders, the number of registered buyers, and the discount rate for successful auctions. \({ifsuccess}_{i}\) refers to the dummy indicating whether the auction is a success or a failure. \({information}_{i}\) refers to the vector of information disclosure variables. \({control}_{i}\) refers to a series of control variablesFootnote 16 that depict other transaction features of the property. The county-year-month fixed effects, \({\alpha }_{j,t}\), control for the district-specific time trend at year-month t of district j. \({\epsilon }_{i}\) is the error term that is two-way clustered at the district and year-month levels (Cameron & Miller, 2015).

One potential problem in Eqs. (1) and (2) is that the information disclosure might be endogenously determined. For instance, the officer may be willing to release more information on the listing webpage for a more desirable dwelling unit. By contrast, she may intentionally hide some less attractive attributes of a unit. Such behaviors, if they exist, will lead to an overestimate of the effect of the information disclosure on the number of buyers attracted or the auction outcome. We use the officers’ personal styles of information releasing to mitigate such a potential endogenous problem. More specifically, we first select the officers who provide information in a consistent format within all the online judicial auctions she handled during the sample period. Therefore, the information disclosure is purely determined by the officer’s own custom instead of any property-level characteristics; in other words, the officer will stick to the same list of information items when collecting and releasing information, no matter how valuable or desirable the property is. Following this strategy, we only include first auctions which are: (1) it is handled by an officer with such a time-invariant personal information-providing style; and (2) the county-year-month has more than one such officer in the working sample of the empirical analysis. The summary statistics of the working sample are reported in Table 11 in the Appendix. Not surprisingly, the sample volume shrinks dramatically due to such a strict criterion - the working sample only accounts for about 8% of the full sample. Nevertheless, we still have 15,723 observations in the working sampleFootnote 17. We also use the full sample to replicate the main results in the robustness checks.

Next, we provide suggestive evidence of the effectiveness of the “consistent personal style” strategy. As discussed in Section 3.2, the major concern is that the court officers intentionally release more desirable information but less undesirable information. Therefore, if our “consistent personal style” strategy can at least partially mitigate this endogeneity, we would observe less desirable information and more undesirable information in our working sample, compared with the sample excluded from the analysis due to the “consistent personal style” criterion. It is difficult to distinguish whether the content is desirable for most information items because potential buyers may have different preferences. Here we adopt the information item of key availability (in the category of “property right”) as the example, which is easy for us to evaluate the content: for part of the execution properties, the courts already have the door keys, which would facilitate the post-transaction delivery process; but for the other properties, the courts do not have the door keys (typically due to the existence of tenants). As listed in Table 12 in the Appendix, in the working sample with 15,723 observations, 27.8% of the units release information on key availability, with 13.8% reporting “with keys” (i.e., desirable information) and the other 14.0% reporting “without keys” (i.e., undesirable information). Meanwhile, in the 184,680 observations which are excluded due to the “consistent personal style” criterion, there are 16.7% reporting “with keys” and the other 11.9% reporting “without keys.” This pattern is consistent with our expectation, which can serve as a piece of indirect evidence of the effectiveness of the “consistent personal style” in mitigating the potential endogeneity.

In the working sample, the released information is only determined by officers’ (consistent) personal styles, which may result from officers’ personal working habits or working templates. To show the differences in such personal styles across officers, we calculate the sum of information variables (including video, 5photo, file num, phy num, and right num as shown in Table 11 in the Appendix) for each officer in the working sample. The histogram distribution of the sum is displayed in Fig. 9 in the Appendix with a mean of 5.8 and a standard deviation of 2.6 showing that the differences are significant between officers.

Empirical Results

Main Results

We start with the effect of information disclosure on attracting potential buyers. As discussed before, we mainly focus on the number of potential buyers who have set reminders, which serves as the proxy for initial interests in the property, and the number of registered buyers, which serves as the actual participation indicator. Following Eq. (1), for each specification, besides the information-disclosure variables, we also include the control variables and the county-year-month fixed effects. The results are listed in Table 2. Besides the estimated coefficients of each information variable, we also calculate the relative effect of information disclosure for each information category, which measures the change in the outcome variable by standard deviations when the corresponding information variable increases by one standard deviation. The overall relative effect measures the impact when all five variables increase by one standard deviation. Therefore, the results not only reflect whether and to what extent information disclosure helps attract potential buyers but also help identify the key information categories.

Table 2 Baseline results: The effects on category level

Regarding the number of reminders (column 1), the effect of information disclosure is relatively limited in attracting buyers’ initial interests. In all five information categories, only two categories, photo and physical attributes, are statistically significant. After controlling for other variables, the relative effect is 0.049 standard deviations for photos and 0.039 standard deviations for the number of physical-attribute items. The overall relative effect of all five information categories is about 0.082 standard deviations in attracting buyers’ initial interests. In other words, the number of reminder settings can increase from 9.2 (the average level of the working sample) to 10.6 if all five information variables simultaneously increase by one standard deviation.

Then, we turn to the number of registered buyers (column 2), for whom the information effect becomes relatively larger. The video and attached files show statistically significant positive effects, for which the relative effects are 0.064 and 0.043 standard deviations, respectively. The variables of 5photo and right num are also positive and marginally significant. The overall relative effect reaches 0.216 standard deviations. That is, whereas an online judicial action in the sample period attracts 1.7 registered bidders on average, the number can increase to 2 if all five information variables increase by one standard deviation simultaneously.

In Table 3, we further decompose the variables of file num, phy num, and right num to the dummies of specific information items to reflect the potential difference in their relative importance. The effects of video and photos are similar to the effects shown in Table 2. For the effects on reminders, we only witness a significant effect associated with the variables of certificate file (an item in the attached file category) and area (an item in the physical attribute category). For the effects on registration, more information items become significant. If the court can provide the appraisal report (in the attached-file category), certificate file, house type (in the physical-attribute category), or name of the property-rights certificate (in the property-rights category) on the webpage, it can attract significantly more registered bidders. Only one information item has a significantly negative effect—the impact of a legal document on the number of registered buyers. In most cases, the legal document refers to the court verdict that explains why the property should be executed in a judicial auction. Thus, one possible reason for the negative effect is that the legal document’s existence may implicitly enhance the so-called stigma effect associated with the execution properties, which has been proven to negatively affect the demand for foreclosure properties in the US (Clauretie and Daneshvary, 2009).

Table 3 The effects on item level

The above results reveal important differences in information’s role in various stages of online real estate transactions. A potential buyer’s initial interest mainly comes from her preliminary cognition of the dwelling unit, which can be expected to be less rational. Thus, it is not surprising to see that the role of information is limited at this stage, and the eye-catching and less time-consuming information is more likely to be effective, such as photos and verbal descriptions of physical attributes. By contrast, when a buyer needs to make a more serious decision on whether she will bid for the unit (and her reservation price), she would prefer a more comprehensive and more complete source of information, even if it will take her more time to absorb. For instance, compared with just a few photos, she would prefer a video. Similarly, compared with a brief verbal description on the webpage, she will rely more on the completed version of a professional appraisal report.

In Table 13 in the Appendix, we replicate Table 2 for the second auctions and the sell-off attempts, respectively. Compared with the results associated with the first auctions, the contribution of information disclosure is much smaller in these two alternative groups. This finding is consistent with the fact that, in most cases, no additional information is provided during these two stages.

We conduct a series of robustness checks. In Table 14 in the Appendix, we further control for the natural log of starting price and the ratio of starting price to appraisal price in the baseline model. The results generally remain consistent. In Table 15 in the Appendix, we replicate the baseline model with the full sample of first auctions. The pattern remains qualitatively unchanged, whereas the magnitudes of the effects associated with the information variables are generally larger than in Table 2. This finding is consistent with the concern that the potential endogeneity of courts’ information-disclosure behaviors might lead to an overestimate of the information effect. In Table 16 in the Appendix, we further differentiate the effect of photos among different numbers from one to fiveFootnote 18 by adding the variables 2photo, 3photo, and 4photo (similar to the definition of variable 5photo) into the baseline model and the results remain consistent.

Note that the strategy of using officers’ consistent personal styles to construct the working sample may arouse another potential endogenous problem - the information disclosure style may result from the court officers’ capability, which might affect the auction performance via other channels. For example, a more capable officer may process all the cases more carefully and patiently, and release more information simultaneously. The buyers may be more willing to focus on or buy the property due to the officer’s patient attitude instead of the more information she released. To rule out this endogeneity, here we test the effect of each information disclosure variable one by one while controlling for the fixed effects of all the other information disclosure variables. Taking the test of the video dummy variable as an example, the model writes as follows:

$${y}_{i}=\beta \times {video}_{i}+\gamma \times {control}_{i}+{\alpha }_{j,t}+{5photo}_{i}\times {file num}_{i}\times {phy num}_{i}\times {right \ num}_{i}+{\varepsilon }_{i}$$
(3)

In this analysis, we mainly focus on the coefficient of \({video}_{i}\) while controlling for the photo-file-physical-right fixed effects (by multiplying \({5photo}_{i}\), \({file \ num}_{i}\), \({phy \ num}_{i}\), and \({right \ num}_{i}\) together). Officers who provide the same numbers of photos, files, physical information, and property right information may be very close in capability. Thus, the coefficient of the video dummy variable compares the outcomes with and without a video conditional on officers with very similar capabilities. Similar tests are also done for the photo dummy variable, file number variable, physical attributes number variable, and property rights number variable. The results are listed in Table 17 in the Appendix, consistent with the main results in Table 2. Therefore, it is reasonable to argue that our key findings are not driven by the new potential endogeneity of officers’ capability.

Heterogeneity Analysis

First, we focus on the interaction between online information disclosure and the availability of offline services. As introduced in Section 2, potential buyers can access offline services from local professionals in some cities, which can assist in the post-transaction property transfer process. Once a buyer succeeds in bidding for a dwelling unit, she needs to contact the court and the local housing authority to complete the property transfer process, which can only be implemented offline in current China. The transfer process is typically complicated for an execution property due to the potential property-rights problems. We expect that when the difficulty in post-transaction property transfer, which is another bottleneck of online real estate transactions, can be better solved via offline services, the online transactions could become more feasible, and the online information’s role could be enhanced. Note that there is no variation for offline services within a city during our sample period. Therefore, we provide a preliminary analysis of the offline service by distinguishing cities with offline services and cities without available offline services. The results are listed in Table 4. The overall effect of information disclosure is substantially larger in cities with offline services. For attracting initial interests, the overall effect is about 0.097 standard deviations in cities with offline service, but only 0.029 standard deviations in cities without offline service. Similarly, the overall effect in attracting registered bidders reaches 0.231 standard deviations in cities with offline service, whereas the corresponding number is 0.114 in cities without offline service. The results provide evidence of the importance of the “offline-online combination” in the online real estate sector’s future development. When the bottleneck of property transfer is solved, the effect of online information gets strengthened.

Table 4 Heterogeneous effect: By offline service

Second, we focus on the heterogeneity associated with the market scale or market maturity. In cities with a more active or mature online judicial housing auction sector, potential buyers are more likely to get used to this innovative transaction platform and trust the information released. For this purpose, in Table 5, we divide the cities into two groups according to the annual amount of online judicial housing auctions. As expected, the overall effect of information disclosure is higher in cities with a larger (above median) market scale of online judicial housing auctions. For the number of reminders, the overall effect is 0.13 standard deviations in cities with a larger market scale, compared with 0.051 standard deviations in the other group. For the number of registered bidders, the overall effects are 0.28 and 0.169 standard deviations, respectively.

Table 5 Heterogeneous effect: By market scale of online judicial housing auction

Finally, the role of online information may vary with the property value. A higher property value to pay means higher risk exposure for the buyer, especially in the judicial housing market. Under the risk aversion assumption in decision-making with uncertainty (Deck & Schlesinger, 2010), we can reasonably expect that a potential buyer would show more prudence in purchasing a higher-value dwelling unit. In this case, she may take the due diligence before the transaction more seriously and would be less satisfied with the online information but seek to collect offline information (even with a very high cost). In other words, we could expect that online information disclosure plays a less critical role for more valuable properties. The results in Table 6 echo such an expectation. Within each city, we divide the properties into the higher- or lower-value group, with the city’s median appraisal price as the threshold. The results show a larger effect of information disclosure in the lower-value group. For the number of reminders, the overall effect is only 0.041 standard deviations in the higher-value group but reaches 0.15 standard deviations in the lower-value group. Similarly, the overall effect for the number of registered bidders is 0.186 standard deviations in the higher-value group and 0.227 standard deviations in the lower-value group. Therefore, the online housing market is more likely to develop first in the lower-end market but would face more challenges in the luxury end.

Table 6 Heterogeneous effect: By property value

Effects on Auction Results

The above analysis indicates better online information disclosure can help attract more buyers to participate in the auction. The question that follows is whether such an effect can be finally converted to a higher success probability and/or a higher transaction price of the auction.

We first explore the impacts of information disclosure on the auction’s success probability based on Eq. (2). The results are listed in Table 7, column (1). All five information variables are positive and statistically significant. We then calculate the relative effects based on the marginal effects at the means. The overall relative effect is 0.367 standard deviations. On average, the success probability of a first auction in the working sample is 29.1% points. If all five information variables simultaneously increase by one standard deviation at their means, the success probability would be 16.7% points higher. This result indicates that better online information disclosure can promote the success of real estate transactions.

Table 7 The effects of information on the auction results

We then examine the impact on the discount rates of successful auctions based on Eq. (1).Footnote 19 As shown in column (2), only two types of visual-related information can help significantly decrease the discount rate of transaction price from appraisal price. If a video is uploaded, the discount rate will drop by 9% points. For properties with five photos, its discount rate will be 9.1% points lower than the counterfactual cases (properties with 1 to 4 photos) on average. Considering that the current average discount rate is 2.5% points in the sample as shown in Table 11 in the Appendix, such an alleviation effect of information is economically important. For example, if the property does not have a video, the discount rate will increase from 2.5% points to 11.5% points. As for the overall effect, a simultaneous increase of all five information variables by one standard deviation can reduce the discount rate by 0.162 standard deviations, or 3.8% points. These results suggest that better online information disclosure can help alleviate the price discount and thus reduce the distortion degree of the property price.

Improvement of Online Information Disclosure

The empirical results above suggest that better information disclosure can help attract more interested buyers and actual participants for an online judicial housing auction, which can be finally converted to a higher success probability or/and a higher transaction price. The next question is whether the courts have realized the importance of online information disclosure and improved its quality. Did the overall information-disclosure quality improve over time? Did some types of courts tend to perform better? And, most importantly, were the courts or officers becoming more and more experienced?

To answer these questions, we first construct an index of information-disclosure quality. As described in Section 3, for an online judicial housing auction, we have considered the effect of 14 information items provided on the webpage: one video, one package of photos, three attached files, five information items on physical attributes, and four information items on property rights. The information-disclosure-quality index is constructed based on these 14 information items as follows:

$${index}_{i}=\frac{\sum _{h=1}^{14}{\beta }_{h}\times {info \ item}_{i,h}}{\sum _{h=1}^{14}{\beta }_{h}}$$
(4)

where \({index}_{i}\) refers to the information-disclosure-quality index for dwelling unit i; \({info \ item}_{i,h}\) refers to the dummy which equals 1 if the court provides information item h for dwelling unit i and 0 otherwise, the same as the independent variables in Table 3; \({\beta }_{h}\) refers to the corresponding coefficients of the dummies in Table 3, column (2), which reflect each item’s relative importance in attracting registered bidders. In other words, for dwelling unit i, the information-disclosure-quality index \({index}_{i}\) is calculated as the average of \({info \ item}_{i,h}\) weighted by \({\beta }_{h}\). A higher value of the index implies a higher quality of online information disclosure, especially in attracting actual participants.

We apply Eq. (4) to the first auctions in our sample. As discussed in Section 3.2, for the 15,723 units in the working sample, we believe their information-disclosure quality is purely determined by officers’ time-invariant personal styles. We thus do not include them in the following analysis. In other words, the following analysis covers 184,680 units (200,403 − 15,723) from 293 cities between January 2017 and October 2019, for which the handling officers have time-variant information-disclosure behaviors.

We start with the overall trend of the information-disclosure-quality index. Figure 5 depicts the national- and regional-level aggregated indices, which are calculated as the simple average of the unit-level indices on a monthly basis. During our sample period, the overall quality of online information disclosure remained relatively stable at the national level, with the monthly average index fluctuating around 0.28. The average indices of the east and central regions share similar patterns, although the average index of the east region was always above the national-level average, whereas the average index of the central region was well below the average. A noteworthy change is a considerable improvement in the information quality of the western cities in the first half of 2017, increasing from about 0.2 to about 0.3, a level comparable to the east region.

Fig. 5
figure 5

The trend of online-information-disclosure quality. This figure visualizes the overall trend of the online-information-disclosure quality at both the national and regional levels. Each aggregated index is calculated as the simple average of all the unit-level indices included

Figure 6 provides a snapshot of the spatial distribution of the quality index, with the average index in the first ten months of 2019 as an example. Not surprisingly, the information quality was high in almost all the cities in Zhejiang province, where the online business is most developed. As described in Section 2, online judicial auctions also started from this province. Several other coastal provinces, such as Fujian, Jiangsu, and Liaoning, also had relatively high information quality. Meanwhile, the information quality was also high in a few western provinces, including Chongqing, Sichuan, and Yunnan, which is consistent with the pattern revealed in Fig. 5.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Spatial distribution of information-quality index. This figure visualizes the distribution of online-information-disclosure quality by prefecture-level cities. For each city, we calculate the average of the information index of all the dwelling units from this city in 2019

We then turn to the effect of the micro-level factors from three aspects: court levels, if the unit locates in a different city than the courts, and the previous experience. We investigate their effects based on the following specification:

$${index}_{i}=\eta \times {micro \ factor}_{i}+{\lambda }_{i}+{\nu }_{t}+{\varepsilon }_{i}$$
(5)

where \({index}_{i}\) refers to the information-disclosure-quality index for dwelling unit i; \({micro \ factor}_{i}\) refers to the micro-level factor variables for dwelling unit i; \({\lambda }_{i}\) refers to the specific micro-level fixed effects for each \({micro \ factor}_{i}\) variable, including city fixed effects, court fixed effects, and officer fixed effects; \({\nu }_{t}\) refers to the year-month fixed effects; \({\epsilon }_{i}\) is the error term.

The results are listed in Table 8. First, we investigate the effect of court levels in column (1). The variable high level equals 1 if the court is a High People’s Court or an Intermediate People’s Court, and 0 if it is a Primary People’s Court.Footnote 20 The result shows the Primary People’s Courts perform better than the higher-level courts. Controlling for the city fixed effects (according to the courts’ location) and year-month fixed effects, the information index of an online judicial auction implemented by a primary court is 1.9% points higher. One possible explanation is that the primary courts take over many more judicial auctions (about 90.4% in the sample) than the higher-level courts (about 9.6%), and thus have more information-disclosure experience.

Table 8 The performance of information-disclosure work

Second, for 10.8% of online auctions in the sample, the execution dwelling units were located in different cities than the courts. Collecting and releasing the information would be more difficult and costly for these courts. The result in column (2) confirms the existence of such an information barrier. Controlling for the court fixed effects and year-month fixed effects, the information-quality index is about 1.5% points lower if the unit locates in another city. The courts should exert more effort to overcome such an information barrier to improve information-disclosure quality.

Another important question is whether the pattern of learning by doing applies to courts and officers, that is, whether the information quality can improve when a court or an officer has more previous experience in implementing online judicial housing auctions. In column (3), after controlling for the officer fixed effects and time fixed effects, we introduce the cumulative number of dwelling units that the officer had previously handled on the Taobao platform. As expected, the variable of officer exp is statistically significant and positive in the model, which suggests officers can accumulate experience from previous cases and convert the experience into a significant improvement in the following online information disclosure. A similar pattern also applies at the court level. In column (4), we introduce the variable of court exp, which measures the cumulative number of dwelling units that the court had handled on the Taobao platform before. It is also significantly positive in the model after controlling for the court fixed effects and time fixed effects. These results provide an encouraging signal that we could expect a continuous improvement in information disclosure around the country, with the further development of the online judicial housing auctions.

Based on the above results, there are two main factors that determine court officers’ information-releasing behaviors. The first factor is court officers’ knowledge/ability on information releasing. If the officers have more experience in online judicial housing auctions, they will know more about which information is important and can release more valuable information. The second factor is information cost. If the cost of obtaining the information is higher (for example, the unit locates in a different city), the information is less likely to be disclosed.

Conclusion

In this study, we use the online judicial housing auction platform in China as an example to investigate how information disclosure helps facilitate online real estate transactions. The empirical results show that a higher quality of online information disclosure can help attract more buyers to participate in the bidding process, which can finally be converted to a higher success probability and a higher transaction price. In particular, although intuitive information sources such as photos can effectively attract buyers’ initial interests, the buyers will mainly rely on more comprehensive information sources such as videos or professional appraisal reports when they decide whether to participate in the bidding. We also show rich heterogeneity associated with the above results. Based on the above results, we calculate the information-quality index for the online judicial dwelling units. The empirical results suggest the information quality tends to increase when the officer or the court has more experience in handling online housing auctions.

Admittedly, compared with the conventional offline real estate market, the judicial housing auction is a special and small sector. However, the empirical results of this study can help figure out what information is important in online real estate transactions, thus helping us explore the possible effective forms of future online real estate transactions and providing valuable enlightenment to the future development of online real estate market. Most importantly, the results provide preliminary evidence of the feasibility of online real estate transactions, though the challenges associated with transactions of execution properties might not be totally consistent with conventional real estate properties. Moreover, this study also provides some specific guidelines. Online platforms can consider adopting different information-disclosure strategies at various stages. Especially, if the online platforms aim at converting buyers’ initial interests to actual online real estate transactions, they need to provide more comprehensive information such as videos, 3D scanning, VRs, and ARs, and more professional information such as appraisal reports.