Skip to main content
Log in

The Anatomy of Public and Private Real Estate Return Premia

  • Published:
The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Market-wide, stock market specific, and real estate market specific risk – what kind of risk and to which extent drives the returns of listed real estate? Based on a structural asset pricing model calibrated to the empirical data in the U.S., we show that at least two thirds of the risk premium of listed real estate are driven by the same factors as direct real estate. Our results shed new light on the risk-characteristics of listed real estate returns and are of high interest for academics, regulators, and portfolio managers alike.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. By using U.K. data from January 1979 to December 1982, Brown (1997) shows that an investor has to hold 100 properties to explain about 90% of the variation in portfolio returns. However, the market average of institutional investors with about 30 properties can only explain about 75%.

  2. See http://www.reit.com/DataAndResearch/IndexData.aspx for the data and http://www.ftse.com/products/downloads/FTSE_NAREIT_US_Real_Estate_Index_Series.pdffor a detailed description of the index classification system.

  3. See http://www.econ.yale.edu/~shiller/data.htm.

  4. See http://www.russell.com for a detailed description of the index.

  5. Koijen et al. (2017) characterize the relationship between business cycle risk, the bond risk premium, and the value premium of common stocks.

  6. The real estate returns are reported to NCREIF on an unlevered basis. For a detailed description of the methodology for producing the transactions-based index (TBI) using the NCREIF database, see Fisher et al. (2007).

  7. For this approximation, we use the data of total debt and equity of Equity REITs between 1990 and 2010 obtained from SNL Financial. The precise ratio rounded to three decimal places is 1.995.

  8. They calibrate the state variable according to the Cochrane and Piazzesi (2005) factor.

  9. Computational details are provided in the ??.

  10. The slightly larger business cycle risk of listed real estate compared to that of stocks is consistent with the fact that these companies are value and small / mid cap stocks (see Koijen et al. (2017)).

  11. Notice that this transaction lag is distinct from the smoothing lag induced by the appraisal-based estimation process.

  12. The sample is based on 177 transactions between 1995 and 2002 of three institutional investors.

References

  • Anderson, R., Clayton, J., MacKinnon, G., & Sharma, R. (2005). REIT Returns and pricing: the small cap value stock factor. Journal of Property Research, 22(4), 267–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ang, A., Nabar, N., & Wald, S.J. (2013). Searching for a common factor in public and private real estate returns. Journal of Portfolio Management, 39(5), 120–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barkham, R., & Geltner, D. (1995). Price discovery in American and British property markets. Real Estate Economics, 23(1), 21–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bond, S.A., Hwang, S., Lin, Z., & Vandell, K.D. (2007). Marketing period risk in a portfolio context: comment and extension. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 38(2), 447–461.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boudry, W.I., Coulson, N.E., Kallberg, J.G., & Liu, C.H. (2012). On the hybrid nature of REITs. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 44(1-2), 230–249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, G.R. (1997). Reducing the dispersion of returns in U.K. real estate portfolios. Journal of Real Estate Portfolio Management, 3(2), 1–12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Byrne, P., & Lee, S. (1995). Is there a place for property in the multi-asset portfolio?. Journal of Property Finance, 6(3), 60–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Byrne, P., & Lee, S. (2005). The impact of real estate on the terminal wealth of U.K. mixed-asset portfolios: 1972-2001. Journal of Real Estate Portfolio Management, 11(2), 133–145.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, J.Y., Lo, A.W., & MacKinlay, A.C. (1997). The econometrics of financial markets, 2nd edn. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chua, A. (1999). The role of international real estate in global mixed-asset investment portfolios. Journal of Real Estate Portfolio Management, 5(2), 129–137.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clayton, J., & MacKinnon, G. (2001). The time-varying nature of the link between REIT, real estate and financial asset returns. Journal of Real Estate Portfolio Management, 7(1), 43–54.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clayton, J., & MacKinnon, G. (2003). The relative importance of stock, bond and real estate factors in explaining REIT returns. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 27(1), 39–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane, J.H., & Piazzesi, M. (2005). Bond risk premia. American Economic Review, 95(1), 138–160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crosby, N., & McAllister, P. (2004). Deconstructing the transaction process: an analysis of fund transaction data. In Lizieri, C. (Ed.) Liquidity in commercial property: Research findings. London: Investment Property Forum.

  • Eichholtz, P.M. (1996). Does international diversification work better for real estate than for stocks and bonds?. Financial Analysts Journal, 52(1), 56–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichholtz, P.M., & Hartzell, D.J. (1996). Property shares and the stock market: an international perspective. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 12(2), 163–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Firstenberg, P.M., Ross, S.A., & Zisler, R.C. (1988). Real estate: the whole story. Journal of Portfolio Management, 14(3), 22–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, J., Gatzlaff, D., Geltner, D., & Haurin, D. (2004). An analysis of the determinants of transaction frequency of institutional commercial real estate investment property. Real Estate Economics, 32(2), 239–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, J., Geltner, D., & Pollakowski, H. (2007). A quarterly transactions-based index of institutional real estate investment performance and movements in supply and demand. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 34(1), 5–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geltner, D. (1993). Estimating market values from appraised values without assuming an efficient market. Journal of Real Estate Research, 8(3), 325–345.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghysels, E., Plazzi, A., Valkanov, R., & Torous, W. (2013). Forecasting real estate prices. In Elliott, G., & Timmermann, A. (Eds.) Handbook of Economic Forecasting, Vol. 2A. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

  • Giliberto, S.M. (1990). Equity real estate investment trusts and real estate returns. Journal of Real Estate Research, 5(2), 259–263.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goetzmann, W.N., & Ibbotson, R.G. (1990). The performance of real estate as an asset class. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 3(1), 65–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoesli, M., & Oikarinen, E. (2012). Are REITs real estate? Evidence from international sector level data. Journal of International Money and Finance, 31(7), 1823–1850.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoesli, M., Lekander, J., & Witkiewicz, W. (2004). International evidence on real estate as a portfolio diversifier. Journal of Real Estate Research, 26(2), 161–206.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koijen, R.S., Lustig, H., & Nieuwerburgh, S.V. (2017). The cross-section and time series of stock and bond returns. Journal of Monetary Economics, 88, 50–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kroencke, T.A., & Schindler, F. (2012). International diversification with securitized real estate and the veiling glare from currency risk. Journal of International Money and Finance, 31(7), 1851– 1866.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, Y., & Wang, K. (1995). The predictability of reit returns and market segmentation. Journal of Real Estate Research, 10(4), 471–482.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ling, D.C., & Naranjo, A. (2015). Returns and information transmission dynamics in public and private real estate markets. Real Estate Economics, 43(1), 163–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ling, D.C., Naranjo, A., & Ryngaert, M.D. (2000). The predictability of equity REIT returns: time variation and economic significance. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 20(2), 117–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, C.H., & Mei, J. (1992). The predictability of returns on equity reits and their co-movement with other assets. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 5(4), 401–418.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, C.H., Hartzell, D.J., Greig, W., & Grissom, T.V. (1990). The integration of the real estate market and the stock market: some preliminary evidence. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 3(3), 261–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MacGregor, B.D., & Nanthakumaran, N. (1992). The allocation to property in the multi-asset portfolio: the evidence and theory reconsidered. Journal of Property Research, 9(1), 5–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mei, J., & Lee, A. (1994). Is there a real estate factor premium?. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 9(2), 113–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morawski, J., Rehkugler, H., & Füss, R. (2008). The nature of listed real estate companies: property or equity market?. Financial Markets and Portfolio Management, 22(2), 101–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newell, G., & Worzala, E. (1995). The role of international property in investment portfolios. Journal of Property Finance, 6(1), 55–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oikarinen, E., Hoesli, M., & Serrano, C. (2011). The long-run dynamics between direct and securitized real estate. Journal of Real Estate Research, 33(1), 73–103.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pagliari, J.J.L., Scherer, K.A., & Monopoli, R.T. (2005). Public versus private real estate equities: a more refined, long-term comparison. Real Estate Economics, 33 (1), 147–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plazzi, A., Torous, W., & Valkanov, R. (2011). Exploiting property characteristics in commercial real estate portfolio allocation. Journal of Portfolio Management, 35(5), 39–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ross, S.A., & Zisler, R.C. (1991). Risk and return in real estate. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 4(2), 175–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seiler, M.J., Webb, J.R., & Myer, F.C.N. (1999). Are EREITs real estate? Journal of Real Estate Portfolio Management, 5(2), 171–181.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stevenson, S. (2000). International real estate diversification: empirical tests using hedged indices. Journal of Real Estate Research, 19(1), 105–131.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yunus, N., Hansz, J.A., & Kennedy, P.J. (2012). Dynamic interactions between private and public real estate markets: some international evidence. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 45(4), 1021–1040.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ziobrowski, J.A., & Curcio, R.J. (1991). Diversification benefits of U.S. real estate to foreign investors. Journal of Real Estate Research, 6(2), 119–142.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors are grateful for comments by Seow Eng Ong, Maurice K.S. Tse, Roland Füss, David C. Ling, and other participants at the ReCapNet Conference 2013, the ARES Annual Meeting 2014, the AREUEA 2014 International Conference, the 2014 Asia Pacific Real Estate Research Symposium, and the Eastern Finance Association Annual Meeting 2015.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Bertram I. Steininger.

Additional information

We would like to thank the European Public Real Estate Association (EPRA) for its grant in support of this work and for their thoughtful comments.

Appendix: Details of the Model

Appendix: Details of the Model

In this section, we outline the details of our structural model of listed and direct real estate. The model is a variant of Koijen et al. (2017). The derivations below closely follow their discussion.

Economy

Macroeconomic activity, st+ 1, is the central state variable of the structural model. It captures business cycle activity, i.e. the state of the economy, through an autoregressive process and can be described by the following process:

$$s_{t + 1}=\rho_{s}s_{t}+\sigma_{s}\epsilon_{t + 1}^{s}. $$

High values of st+ 1 correspond to strong economic activity. The parameter ρ s implies that business cycle activity is to some degree persistent. The innovation term, \(\epsilon _{t + 1}^{s}\), is the first priced source of risk in the model.

We model the returns of three assets. The first is the aggregate stock market (M), the second is listed real estate (L), and the third is direct real estate (D), so that the real dividend growth of asset i = {M, L, D} is described by:

$$\triangle d_{t + 1}^{i}=\gamma_{0i}+\gamma_{1i}s_{t}+\sigma_{mi}\epsilon_{t + 1}^{m}+\sigma_{di}\epsilon_{t + 1}^{d},\:\forall i=\left\{ M,\:L,\:D\right\} . $$

Shock \(\epsilon _{t + 1}^{m}\) is an aggregate stock market dividend shock, the second source of risk for the structural model. Shock 𝜖t+ 1d is an aggregate direct real estate rent shock and the third source of risk. The parameter γ1i is the sensitivity of dividend growth to business cycle activity. Listed real estate is leveraged; thus, we set γ1L = 2 × γ1D and σ d L = 2 × σ d D to capture a leverage of two against direct real estate. Furthermore, listed real estate vehicles are value stocks. In line with this observation, we impose γ1L > γ1M, since Koijen et al. (2017) show that value stocks are more sensitive to recession risk than growth stocks. The coefficient σ m i represents stock market risk and is zero for direct real estate (σ m D = 0). We can utilize this coefficient to model stock-market spillovers in listed real estate by σ m L > 0.

Investors’ preferences are captured by a stochastic discount factor (SDF) following the log process:

$$-m_{t + 1}=y+\Lambda^{\prime}\epsilon_{t + 1}, $$

where the vector \(\epsilon _{t + 1}=\left (\epsilon _{t + 1}^{m},\epsilon _{t + 1}^{d},\epsilon _{t + 1}^{s}\right )^{\prime }\)captures the shocks, and \(\tilde {y}=y-\frac {1}{2}\Lambda ^{\prime }\Lambda \) is the real interest rate. This model has three positively priced sources of risk: aggregate stock market dividend risk (Λ m > 0), aggregate direct real estate rent risk (Λ d > 0), and business cycle risk (Λ s > 0), which are summarized via the vector:

$$\Lambda=\left( \begin{array}{c} \Lambda_{m}\\ \Lambda_{d}\\ \Lambda_{s} \end{array}\right). $$

Asset Prices

The log return of asset i follows:

$$r_{t + 1}^{i}=\kappa_{0i}+\kappa_{1i}pd_{t + 1}^{i}+\triangle d_{t + 1}^{i}-pd_{t}, $$

where \(pd_{t + 1}^{i}\) is the log price-dividend ratio, and κ0i, κ1i are constants (see below). The log-price-dividend ratio is linear in the state of the economy:

$$pd_{t + 1}^{i}=A_{i}+B_{i}s_{t + 1}, $$

where

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} B_{i}&=&\frac{\gamma_{1i}}{1-\kappa_{1i}\rho_{s}},\\ A_{i}\!&=&\!\frac{-y+\gamma_{0i}+\kappa_{0i}+\frac{1}{2}\sigma_{mi}^{2}+\frac{1}{2}\sigma_{di}^{2}+\frac{1}{2}\kappa_{1i}^{2}B_{i}{\sigma_{s}^{2}}-\Lambda_{m}\sigma_{mi}\,-\,\Lambda_{d}\sigma_{di}\,-\,\Lambda_{s}\kappa_{1i}B_{i}\sigma_{s}}{1-\kappa_{1i}}. \end{array} $$

Decomposition of Risk Premia

The risk premium for our three assets can be computed by the covariance to the SDF:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} E_{t}\left( r_{t + 1}^{i}-y\right)+\frac{1}{2}V_{t}\left( r_{t + 1}^{i}\right)&=&Cov_{t}\left( -m_{t + 1},r_{t + 1}^{i}\right)\\ &=&Cov_{t}\left( {\Lambda}^{\prime}\epsilon_{t + 1},\kappa_{1i}B_{i}\epsilon_{t + 1}^{s}+\sigma_{mi}\epsilon_{t + 1}^{m}+\sigma_{di}\epsilon_{t + 1}^{d}\right)\\ &=&{\Lambda}_{m}\sigma_{mi}+{\Lambda}_{d}\sigma_{di}+{\Lambda}_{s}\kappa_{1i}B_{i}. \end{array} $$

The first component of the constant risk premium compensates investors for aggregate stock market dividend risk (Λ m σ m i ). For direct real estate σ m D = 0; thus, this term is zero. The second component of the constant risk premium compensates investors for aggregate real estate rent risk (Λ d σ d i ). For the aggregate stock market σ d M = 0; thus, this term is zero. The third constant risk premium term compensates for business cycle risk (Λ s κ1iB i σ s ).

Proof

The logreturn for any asset i can be approximated by e.g. Campbell et al. (1997):

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} r_{t + 1}&=&\kappa_{0}+\kappa_{1}pd_{t + 1}+\triangle d_{t + 1}-pd_{t},\\ \kappa_{0}&=&ln\left( exp\left( \bar{pd}\right)+ 1\right)-\kappa_{1}\bar{pd},\\ \kappa_{1}&=&\frac{exp\left( \bar{pd}\right)}{exp\left( \bar{pd}\right)+ 1}, \end{array} $$

where we drop the subscripts i for convenience. The log price-dividend ratio is assumed to be linear in the state of the economy:

$$pd_{t + 1}=A+Bs_{t + 1}. $$

The coefficients A and B are found by solving the asset pricing equation:

$$E_{t}\left( M_{t + 1}R_{t + 1}\right)= 1, $$
$$1=E_{t}\left( exp\left( m_{t + 1}+r_{t + 1}\right)\right), $$
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} 0&=&E_{t}\left( m_{t + 1}\right)+\frac{1}{2}V_{t}\left( m_{t + 1}\right)+E_{t}\left( r_{t + 1}\right)+\frac{1}{2}V_{t}\left( r_{t + 1}\right)+Cov_{t}\left( m_{t + 1},r_{t + 1}\right),\\ &=&-y+\kappa_{0}+\gamma_{0}+\gamma_{1}s_{t}+\left( \kappa_{1}-1\right)A+\left( \kappa_{1}\rho_{s}-1\right)Bs_{t}+\frac{1}{2}{\sigma_{m}^{2}}+\frac{1}{2}{\sigma_{d}^{2}}\\ &&\;\;+\frac{1}{2}{\kappa_{1}^{2}}B^{2}{\sigma_{s}^{2}}-\Lambda_{m}\sigma_{m}-\Lambda_{d}\sigma_{d}-\Lambda_{s}\kappa_{1}B\sigma_{s}. \end{array} $$

Collecting all s t terms and all others results in the following system of two equations:

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} 0 \!&=&\!\gamma_{1}s_{t}\,+\,\left( \kappa_{1}\rho_{s}\,-\,1\right)Bs_{t},\\ 0&=&\,-\,y\,+\,\kappa_{0}\,+\,\gamma_{0}\,+\,\left( \kappa_{1}\,-\,1\right)A\,+\,\frac{1}{2}{\sigma_{m}^{2}}\,+\,\frac{1}{2}{\sigma_{d}^{2}}\,+\,\frac{1}{2}{\kappa_{1}^{2}}B^{2}{\sigma_{s}^{2}}\,-\,\Lambda_{m}\sigma_{m}\,-\,\Lambda_{d}\sigma_{d}\,-\,\Lambda_{s}\kappa_{1}B\sigma_{s}, \end{array} $$

which can be solved as:

$$B=\frac{\gamma_{1}}{1-\kappa_{1}\rho_{s}}, $$
$$A=\frac{-y+\gamma_{0}+\kappa_{0}+\frac{1}{2}{\sigma_{m}^{2}}+\frac{1}{2}{\sigma_{d}^{2}}+\frac{1}{2}{\kappa_{1}^{2}}B^{2}{\sigma_{s}^{2}}-\Lambda_{m}\sigma_{m}-\Lambda_{d}\sigma_{d}-\Lambda_{s}\kappa_{1}B\sigma_{s}}{1-\kappa_{1}}. $$

Parameter Values

This section provides details on how we calibrate our structural model. We simulate the model using a monthly time interval 10,000 times and afterwards, we convert the data to an annual time interval with a sample length of 27 years. The persistence parameter for the state of the economy (ρ s = 0.936) is taken from Koijen et al. (2017). On an annual basis, this is equal to a modest persistence of 0.45. The volatility parameter (σ s = 0.01) is an arbitrary normalization.

The stock market dividend volatility parameter (σ m M = 0.04) and the direct real estate rent volatility parameter (σ d D = 0.02) closely match the empirical annual dividend volatilities of 13.2% and 5.3%. The respective volatilities implied by our calibration are 13.9% (\(= 4\%\times \sqrt {12}\)) and 6.9% (\(= 2\%\times \sqrt {12}\)). The listed real estate dividend and rent volatility parameters depend on our model assumptions, i.e. (i) σ m L will be one half of the value of σ m M if there are stock market spillovers and (ii) zero if there are no stock market spillovers. The parameter σ d L is two times σ d D to reflect leverage of listed real estate.

We impose two restrictions on the recession risk sensitivity parameters, (i) γ1L = 2 × γ1D to reflect leverage of listed real estate and (ii) γ1L > γ1M, since listed real estate are value stocks and should be more exposed to recession risk than common stocks. The parameter values γ1D = 0.10, γ1L = 0.20, and γ1M = 0.14 satisfy these criteria.

After defining the parameters for the business cycle state variable, dividend growth and rent growth, we choose in a final step SDF risk prices, i.e. the parameter vector Λ, to generate risk premia which are as close as possible to the observed average returns of common stocks, listed real estate, and direct real estate. Since we measure returns in excess of the risk-free rate, the real interest rate (\(\tilde {y}\)) does not affect our results on risk premia and is set to 2% p.a. in all simulations.

Table 5 Parameter values

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kroencke, T.A., Schindler, F. & Steininger, B.I. The Anatomy of Public and Private Real Estate Return Premia. J Real Estate Finan Econ 56, 500–523 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-017-9646-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-017-9646-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation