Skip to main content
Log in

Monetary equilibrium and price stickiness reconsidered: A reply to Bagus and Howden

  • Published:
The Review of Austrian Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Bagus and Howden (Review of Austrian Economics 24(4): 383–402, 2011) argue that price stickiness is a poor justification for advocating a flexible money supply through the issuing of fiduciary media under central or free banking. They view the contraction in output following an exogenous increase in money demand as an optimal response, worry about redistribution effects from the issuance of fiduciary media, and claim a changing money supply complicates economic calculation. Accepting their view that the contraction in output is an optimal response to an exogenous change in money demand, we still find a potentially beneficial role for monetary policy (under central banking) or fractional reserve note issue (under free banking). We show that even if all prices were perfectly flexible, changes in the money supply to offset changes in money demand might still be desirable. We point out several errors and mischaracterizations in their article, justify our decision to disregard wealth transfers, and discuss how a flexible money supply might facilitate economic calculation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The authors define “money proper” as high-powered money. Given their opposition to fiduciary media, we suppose they have 100%-backed commodity monies in mind. They claim that, in a free market, the supply of money proper would be governed by the “general profit rate prevailing in the economy” (Bagus and Howden 2011, p. 398). Unfortunately, they give no further indication as to how they believe the supply of money would expand and contract in response to various shocks. In our view, White (1999, pp. 28–37) offers an excellent explanation of the mechanism governing the supply of commodity monies.

  2. Although it is not a necessary implication of viewing the observed fluctuation in output as the optimal response path to an exogenous shock, the authors make the stronger claim that there is no better alternative to the sluggish correction of monetary disequilibrium (Bagus and Howden 2011, p. 399). In other words, the sluggish adjustment of prices and output is not only narrowly optimal, but also optimal in a broader sense that takes into account alternative sets of institutions.

  3. The authors repeat this mischaracterization elsewhere in the text (pp. 395, 396).

  4. To put it somewhat differently, there are two ways to reach a long run equilibrium in response to an increase in money demand: allow prices to adjust downward (as Bagus and Howden propose) or maintain prices at their pre-shock level through monetary expansion (as monetary equilibrium theorists propose).

  5. Contrary to their claim (p. 386, footnote 5), “stating that one price level is more optimal [sic] than another” is not equivalent to deeming “stable output as preferable to stable prices.” In the absence of productivity gains, monetary equilibrium theorist typically prefer stable output (at the natural level) and a stable price level (so as not to incur unnecessary adjustment costs), whereas Bagus and Howden would seem to prefer neither stable output (accepting short run deviations) nor a stable price level (allowing the price level to change in response to monetary shocks).

  6. Selgin (1997) makes a similar argument in the context of productivity growth.

  7. We say “potentially greater” since sticky prices might be indicative of significant adjustment costs (i.e., prices are sticky because it is more costly to change prices than under the flexible regime), but also might arise from some other source.

  8. If the money supply adjusted with a lag, flexible prices would adjust in the short run and then readjust back to reflect the changing money supply. Sticky prices, by definition, are not changed in this regime.

References

  • Bagus, P., & Howden, D. (2010). Fractional reserve free banking: Some quibbles. Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, 13(4), 29–55.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bagus, P., & Howden, D. (2011). Monetary equilibrium and price stickiness: Causes, consequences, and remedies. Review of Austrian Economics, 24(4), 383–402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E. (1972). Expectations and the neutrality of money. Journal of Economic Theory, 4(2), 103–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw, N. G. (1985). Small menu costs and large business cycles: A macroeconomic model of monopoly. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100(2), 529–537.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw, N. G., & Reis, R. (2002). Sticky information versus sticky prices: A proposal to replace the New Keynesian Phillips Curve. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4), 1295–1328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Selgin, G. A. (1997). Less than zero: The case for a falling price level in a growing economy. London: Institute of Economic Affairs.

    Google Scholar 

  • Selgin, G. A. (2012). Mere quibbles: Bagus and Howden’s critique of the theory of free banking. Review of Austrian Economics, 25(2), 131–148.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, L. H. (1999). The theory of monetary institutions. Oxford: Wiley-Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alexander W. Salter.

Additional information

The authors wish to thank the Mercatus Center at George Mason University for its generous support.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Luther, W.J., Salter, A.W. Monetary equilibrium and price stickiness reconsidered: A reply to Bagus and Howden. Rev Austrian Econ 25, 263–269 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-012-0184-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-012-0184-6

Keywords

JEL classifications

Navigation