Skip to main content
Log in

Government ideology and fiscal consolidation: Where and when do government parties adjust public spending?

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Recent studies indicate that the ideological stances of government parties no are longer associated with differences in total government spending. At the same time, we observe that political polarization over spending policies has deepened. This paper addresses that puzzle by analyzing government spending behavior for ten expenditure categories during both ‘normal’ times and periods of fiscal consolidation between 1995 and 2015 for 16 OECD countries. Our results indicate that partisan motives prevail in ‘normal’ times: right-wing cabinets spend more on defense and less on education and environmental protection than left-wing governments. On the other hand, in periods of fiscal adjustment, differences between left- and right-wing government expenditures can be observed mostly in different budget categories. For instance, during fiscal consolidations, right-wing governments reduce spending more than their left-wing counterparts on those categories featuring large shares of public employee compensation (i.e., public consumption spending) and small capital-expenditure shares. Hence, a central message of this paper helping to resolve the aforementioned puzzle is that ideological differences remain important after taking a comprehensive look at individual spending categories and distinguishing between periods with and without adjustments.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See also Alesina et al. (2017), who study a sample of 16 OECD countries during the 1978–2015 period, finding that government spending and transfer cuts are less detrimental to future GDP growth than tax increases. While tax adjustments typically complement spending cuts during periods of fiscal consolidation, their magnitude is on average smaller than spending cuts by a factor of almost four.

  2. Examples of the recent electoral successes of far-left and -right parties are Die Linke and the Alternative für Deutschland in Germany, the United Kingdom Independence Party in the UK, the Lega Nord in Italy, the Rassemblement National/Front National in France, the Freiheitliche Partei Österreichs in Austria and Podemos and VOX in Spain.

  3. The narrative method identifies consolidation policies by reference to budget documents indicating that the primary policy objective was not to stabilize the economic cycle. Consequently, the fiscal adjustments identified by that approach prove to be uncorrelated with the business cycle (Alesina et al. 2018). Moreover, it has been argued that such narratives do not suffer from weak identification nor reverse causality biases (Guajardo et al. 2014).

  4. For an extensive review of the literature on external and internal adjustments, see Walter (2003).

  5. The composition of the sample is explained by the availability of data from distinct sources. Observations on fiscal adjustments are available for the 1980–2014 period. Data on total and disaggregated public spending are available for the 1995–2015 period. See also Tables 1 and 2 for details on measurement, data sources and descriptive statistics.

  6. For example, 2011’s target was reducing budget deficits to 4.8% of GDP for the central government and 1.3% of GDP for the state governments (`Comunidades Autónomas´), thereby demanding a much larger effort from the latter, as the expenditure shares of central and state governments over GDP were almost identical beforehand.

  7. The histogram for a pooled sample of total expenditure growth rates can be found in the Supplementary material to this paper. For the case of Ireland, available data indicate a 34.26% growth of total public expenditures in 2010, followed by a subsequent 30.26% reduction in 2011. Those sharp expenditure changes are explained by strong (upward and downward) shifts (of + 135.35% and − 117.54%, respectively) in the Economic affairs category. To guard against the influence of such outliers on our empirical estimates, we have removed the 2010 and 2011 observations for Ireland from the sample.

  8. If one party holds the majorty in Parliament, ideo is the ideology of that party. In the United States, ideo is the ideology of the President’s party.

  9. Since elec is a weighted variable and election dates are almost uniformly throughout the calendar year, the mean of elec is 0.247. On average, regular elections took place every fifth year. The number of elections in our sample is 89. Among them, the number of irregular elections is 27. In the robustness section of our results, we also use the measurement of the electoral cycle proposed by Schuknecht (2000).

  10. We also have considered estimating random-effect (RE) regression models. However, noticing significant differences among parameter estimates for a few spending categories, we consider FE estimation as more suitable owing to its robustness to eventual correlations between unobservable heterogeneity and our explanatory variables. In qualitative terms, RE and FE models return almost identical regression results (see also the descriptive statistics in Table 2 on the prevalence of sizable within variation). Summary results for Hausman tests comparing FE and RE estimates are given in the notes to those tables that report outcomes for the general regression model in (1).

  11. All empirical conclusions largely remain unaffected by the inclusion or exclusion of first-order dynamics.

  12. The five categories with the largest shares of employee salaries are: Public order and safety ≈ 70%, Education ≈ 60%, Defense ≈ 50%, Recreation, culture and religion and Health ≈ 30%. Apart from Social protection, capital spending is lowest in Health (≈ 4%), Public order and safety (≈ 5%) and Education (≈ 7%). For details, see Eurostat (2019).

  13. All tables reporting the results of the robustness checks are contained in the online supplementary material to this paper.

References

  • Alesina, A. (1987). Macroeconomic policy in a two-party system as a repeated game. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102, 651–678.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Ardagna, S., & Trebbi, F. (2006). Who adjusts and when? The political economy of reforms. IMF Staff Papers, 53(Special Issue), 1–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Azzalini, G., Barbiero, O., Favero, C. A., Giavazzi, F., Karamysheva, M., Miano, A., & Paradis, M. (2018). Fiscal adjustment plans. Dataset. Retrieved November 20, from, 2018. http://www.igier.unibocconi.it/folder.php?idfolder=306&vedi=306&tbn=albero.

  • Alesina, A., Baqir, R., & Easterly, W. (1999). Public goods and ethnic divisions. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 1214–1284.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Barbiero, O., Favero, C., Giavazzi, F., & Paradisi, M. (2017). The effects of fiscal consolidations: Theory and evidence, NBER working paper no. 23385.

  • Alesina, A., Favero, C., & Giavazzi, F. (2015). The output effect of fiscal consolidation plans. Journal of International Economics, 96, S19–S42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Roberto, P., & Tavares, J. (1998). The political economy of fiscal adjustments. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 29, 197–266.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Roubini, N., & Cohen, G. D. (1997). Political cycles and the macroeconomy. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bakker, R., de Vries, C., Edwards, E., Hooghe, L., Jolly, S., Marks, G., et al. (2015). Measuring party positions in Europe: The Chapel Hill expert survey trend file, 1999–2010. Party Politics, 21, 143–152.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benoit, K., & Laver, M. (2006). Party policy in modern democracies. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brender, A., & Drazen, A. (2005). Political budget cycles in new versus established democracies. Journal of Monetary Economics, 52, 1271–1295.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brender, A., & Drazen, A. (2013). Elections, leaders, and the composition of government spending. Journal of Public Economics, 97, 18–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cameron, D. R. (1978). The expansion of the public economy: A comparative analysis. The American Political Science Review, 72, 1243–1261.

    Google Scholar 

  • CHESDATA. (2018). Datasets on party positions across Europe. http://chesdata.eu

  • Cusack, T. R. (1997). Partisan politics and public finance: Changes in public spending in the industrialized democracies, 1955–1989. Public Choice, 91, 375–395.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cusack, T. R., & Beramendi, P. (2006). Taxing Work. European Journal of Political Research, 45, 43–73.

    Google Scholar 

  • Devries, P., Guajardo, J., Leigh, D., & Pescatori, A. (2011). A new action-based dataset of fiscal consolidation. IMF Working Papers, 11/128, 1–90.

    Google Scholar 

  • Döring, H. & Manow, P. (2018). Parliaments and governments database (ParlGov): Information on parties, elections and cabinets in modern democracies. Retrieved November 5, from, 2018. http://parlgov.org.

  • Drazen, A., & Easterly, W. (2001). Do crises induce reform? Simple empirical tests of conventional wisdom. Economics and Politics, 13, 129–158.

    Google Scholar 

  • Drazen, A., & Eslava, M. (2010). Electoral manipulation via voter-friendly spending: Theory and evidence. Journal of Development Economics, 92, 39–52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterly, W. (2006). The white man’s burden: Why the West’s efforts to aid the rest have done so much ill and so little good. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eurostat. (2019). Government expenditure by function—COFOG. https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statistics-explained/pdfscache/10912.pdf.

  • Franzese, R. J. (2000). Electoral and partisan manipulation of public debt in developed democracies. In R. R. Strauch & J. von Hagen (Eds.), Institutions, politics and fiscal policy (Vol. 2, pp. 1956–1990)., ZEI studies in european economics and law Boston, MA: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garrett, G., & Mitchell, D. (2001). Globalization, government spending and taxation in the OECD. European Journal of Political Research, 39, 145–177.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guajardo, J., Leigh, D., & Pescatori, A. (2014). Expansionary austerity? International evidence. Journal of the European Economic Association, 12, 949–968.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herwartz, H., & Theilen, B. (2014a). Partisan influence on social spending under market integration, fiscal pressure and institutional change. European Journal of Political Economy, 34, 409–424.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herwartz, H., & Theilen, B. (2014b). Health care and ideology: A reconsideration of political determinants of public healthcare funding in the OECD. Health Economics, 23, 225–240.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herwartz, H., & Theilen, B. (2017). Ideology and redistribution through public spending. European Journal of Political Economy, 46, 74–90.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs, D. A., Jr. (1977). Political parties and macroeconomic policy. The American Political Science Review, 71, 1467–1487.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs, D. A., Jr. (1987). The political economy of industrial democracies. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iversen, T. (2001). The dynamics of the welfare state expansion: Trade openness, de- industrialization, and partisan politics. In P. Piersson (Ed.), The new politics of the welfare state (pp. 45–79). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, C. (2011). Capitalist systems, de-industrialization, and the politics of public education. Comparative Political Studies, 44, 412–435.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katsimi, M., & Sarantidis, V. (2012). Do elections affect the composition of fiscal policy in developed, established democracies? Public Choice, 151, 325–362.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kayser, M. A. (2009). Partisan waves: International business cycles and electoral choice. American Journal of Political Science, 53, 950–970.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kittel, B., & Obinger, H. (2003). Political parties, institutions, and the dynamics of social expenditure in times of austerity. Journal of European Public Policy, 10, 20–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer, A. H., & Richard, S. F. (1981). A rational theory of the size of government. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 914–927.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer, A. H., & Richard, S. F. (1983). Tests of a rational theory of the size of government. Public Choice, 41, 403–418.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mulas-Granados, C. (2003). The political and economic determinants of budgetary consolidation in Europe. European Political Economy Review, 1, 15–39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W. D. (1975). The political business cycle. Review of Economic Studies, 42, 169–190.

    Google Scholar 

  • Norris, P. (2005). The Radical Right: Voters and parties in the electoral market. New York and Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2011). Divided we stand: Why inequality keeps rising. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2018). Government at a glance2017 edition. Retrieved November 20, from, 2018. https://stats.oecd.org/.

  • Perroti, R., & Kontopoulos, Y. (2002). Fragmented fiscal policy. Journal of Public Economics, 86, 191–222.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., Roland, G., & Tabellini, G. (2007). Electoral rules and government spending in parliamentary democracies. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 2, 155–188.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (1994). Is inequality harmful for growth? The American Economic Review, 84, 600–621.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2000). Political economics. Explaining economic policy. Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Potrafke, N. (2009). Did globalization restrict partisan politics? An empirical evaluation of social expenditure in a panel of OECD countries. Public Choice, 140, 105–124.

    Google Scholar 

  • Potrafke, N. (2010). The growth of public health expenditure in OECD countries: Do government ideology and electoral motives matter? Journal of Health Economics, 29, 797–810.

    Google Scholar 

  • Potrafke, N. (2011). Does government ideology influence budget composition? Empirical evidence from OECD countries. Economics of Governance, 12, 101–134.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff, K. (1990). Equilibrium political budget cycles. The American Economic Review, 80, 21–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff, K., & Sibert, A. (1988). Elections and macroeconomic policy cycles. The Review of Economic Studies, 55, 1–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, C. D., & Romer, D. H. (2010). The macroeconomic effects of tax changes: Estimates based on a new measure of fiscal shocks. The American Economic Review, 100, 763–801.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schuknecht, L. (2000). Fiscal policy cycles and public expenditure in developing countries. Public Choice, 102, 113–128.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shelton, C. A. (2007). The size and composition of government expenditure. Journal of Public Economics, 91, 2230–2260.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tepe, M., & Vanhuysse, P. (2009). Are ageing OECD welfare states on the path to gerontocracy? Evidence from 18 democracies, 1980–2002. Journal of Public Policy, 29, 1–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G. (1995). Decision making in political systems: Veto players in presidentialism, parliamentarism, multicamerialism and multipartyism. British Journal of Political Science, 25, 289–325.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G., & Chang, E. C. C. (2004). Veto players and the structure of the budget in advanced industrialized countries. European Journal of Political Research, 43, 449–476.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walter, S. (2003). Financial crises and the politics of macroeconomic adjustments. New York: Cambride University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Whitten, G. D., & Williams, L. K. (2011). Buttery guns and welfare hawks: The politics of defense spending in advanced industrial democracies. American Journal of Political Science, 55, 117–134.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We cordially acknowledge helpful suggestions from four anonymous referees, the editor in chief, William F. Shughart II, and the participants of the International Conference on Public Economic Theory (PET 2019) in Strasbourg. The second author acknowledges financial support from the Spanish Ministerio de Economía, Industria y Competitividad and the European Union under project ECO2016-75410-P (AEI/FEDER, UE) and Universitat Rovira i Virgili and Generalitat de Catalunya under projects 2017PRF-URVB2-B3 and 2017GR770. We thank Dr. Viet T. Tuan for computational assistance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Bernd Theilen.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (PDF 51 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Herwartz, H., Theilen, B. Government ideology and fiscal consolidation: Where and when do government parties adjust public spending?. Public Choice 187, 375–401 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-020-00785-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-020-00785-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation